152 P.2d 542 | Utah | 1944
Lead Opinion
Certiorari to review an order of the Public Service Commission of Utah. The order directed a reduction in the rates charged by the Utah Power Light Company to its customers in Utah for electrical energy.
The petitioner, hereinafter called Company, is a corporation duly organized and existing under and by virtue of the *161 laws of the State of Maine and duly authorized to do business in the State of Utah. It is an "electrical corporation" and a "public utility" as those terms are defined in Title 76, U.C.A. 1943. It furnishes electrical energy to customers in southeastern Idaho, northern and central Utah, and a small part of southwestern Wyoming. For the purposes of this case the Commission accepted the Company's separation or allocation of plant which it considered was used and useful in the rendering of electrical service in the state of Utah. On the basis of this separation 90.6% of the total plant cost was allocated to Utah operations.
On August 15, 1942, the Public Service Commission of Utah, hereinafter referred to as the Commission, upon its own motion initiated this proceeding to inquire into the reasonableness of rates charged for electrical energy by the Utah Power Light Company. An amended complaint was filed by the Commission on September 15, 1942. This complaint alleged in substance that the Company was at present and had been earning in excess of a reasonable return on a "just and proper rate base." It further alleged that the rates charged by the Company were unjust, unreasonable, and otherwise in violation of Title 76 of 1933 Revised Statutes of Utah, as amended. The complaint ordered that a public hearing and investigation be had to determine a just and proper rate base; to ascertain a fair and reasonable rate of return on said rate base, and to inquire into the reasonableness of the Company's existing rates.
The Company by answer denied that it had been making more than a reasonable rate of return or that its rates were unjust, unreasonable or unlawful. It further alleged that it was entitled to earn a reasonable return upon the value of its property used and useful in rendering electrical services to customers in Utah.
After a lengthy hearing the Commission found against the Company on all material issues and ordered that "the rates and charges made and demanded and received by the Utah Power Light Company from its customers in the state of Utah for electric energy shall be decreased to reflect a reduction *162 in rates which, when applied to the 1941 volume of sales, will amount to not less than $1,504,644 annually." It further ordered the Company to file with the Commission new schedules of rates that would "(a) reflect the rate reduction ordered * * * and (b) be non-discriminatory, just and reasonable * * *." The company thereupon filed an application for rehearing setting forth in detail the grounds therefor. This application was denied and the Commission brought the record before this court for review.
While numerous grounds are urged as a basis for reversal of the Commission's order, there is one fundamental contention, upon the determination of which many of the other specifications of error hinge. In its original brief the Company posed this issue by its contention that it had a right, granted by statute and insured by the Constitution, to have its rates established by the Commission at a level which would permit the Company to earn a reasonable return on the "fair value" of its property used and useful in serving its Utah customers.
The Company does not contend that the Commission was required to adopt any single formula or any particular group of formulae as a measuring rod for ascertaining value. Its contention is simply that the Commission is required to adopt some formula reasonably calculated to find the "present fair value" of the property; that the Commission cannot ignore evidence of value and determine a rate base founded upon the "cost" of the property devoted to public service. This argument recognizes the essential difference between what might have been paid for property many years ago and what the property is now worth. When various properties were acquired they may have been of the best known most modern design and of great value, and a short time thereafter may have been rendered practically worthless because outmoded by later technical advances in the art of producing electrical energy. Conversely, the property may have been acquired when land values were low and few markets were available at a relatively low cost and now because of the growth of the area — *163 increase in available demand for the product and increased demand for land — be of greater value. In its original brief, the Company contended that it had both a constitutional and astatutory right to have its rate base established in relation to value as distinguished from cost; that it was entitled to a rate which would permit it to earn a reasonable return on the present fair value of its property.
Between the time the Company filed its original brief and the time it filed its reply brief, the United States Supreme Court decided the case of Federal Power Commission v. Hope NaturalGas Company, 1944,
The Commission adopted a directly contrary position. It held that the just and proper rate base for the Company is the amount actually and "prudently invested" in the property used and useful in rendering Utah service. The Company offered to prove the value of its property by evidence of the reproduction cost new and reproduction cost new less depreciation as of July 1, 1941. Considerable evidence along this line was admitted. In its report the Commission stated that:
"After listening to such testimony for about a day and a half the Commission asked the Company to state what additional witnesses it proposed to call in connection with the reproduction cost new less depreciation of its properties in Utah and, briefly, what their testimony would be. Counsel for the Company prepared a statement as to what additional testimony it proposed to offer in this connection and read the same into the record. After considering the testimony which had been received and the statement of what additional evidence on reproduction cost the Company proposed to offer, the Commission sustained an objection to the introduction of further evidence on this subject and granted a motion to strike the evidence in that regard which had been read into the record. *164 The objections made by counsel for the Commission to such evidence were that it is unreliable, fallacious, immaterial, irrelevant, incompetent, and of no probative value in such a case as this."
Toward the close of the hearing the question of the admissibility of this evidence relating to reproduction costs, etc., was again raised. The Commission ruled that "however offered or submitted, the Commission would not receive in evidence proof of reproduction cost new and proof of reproduction cost new less depreciation." In so ruling, the Commission indicated that it was cognizant of the role of reproduction cost data in ascertaining the present fair value of utility property for it stated that "Under the `fair value' rule reproduction cost new less depreciation is frequently the controlling element."
From the entire record it becomes unmistakably clear that the Commission rejected "fair value" as a measuring rod for the determination of a proper rate base. In lieu of "fair value" the Commission purported to ascertain the dollars "prudently invested" in the acquisition of Company's property and the expense of integrating that property into a co-ordinated system. This prudent investment cost was adopted as the rate base upon which the Company was to be permitted to earn a reasonable return. We, therefore, are squarely confronted with the question of whether a utility in the state of Utah has the right to have rates established by the regulatory body which will permit the utility to earn a reasonable return on the "fair value" of its property which it has devoted to rendering public service in Utah. If it has, this court must set aside the order of the Commission which established a rate base which excludes value and purports only to reflect the amount "prudently invested" in acquiring the property and integrating it into single system.
The problems implicit in resolving this contention dictate that we discuss the development of substantive constitutional law regarding rate legislation before determining whether or not Utah statutes require the Commission to use a value rate base in establishing rates. *165
A logical starting point for an analysis of the development of constitutional limitations on the power of legislatures to regulate the rates charged for the use of privately owned property is the case of Munn v. Illinois,
The court there pointed out that prior to the adoption of the Fourteenth Amendment "it was not supposed that statutes regulating the use, or even the price of the use, of private property necessarily deprived an owner of his property without due process of law. * * *" Page 125 of
"It is insisted, however, that the owner of property is entitled to a reasonable compensation for its use, even though it be clothed with a public interest, and that what is reasonable is a judicial and not a legislative question.
"As has already been shown, the practice has been otherwise. In countries where the common law prevails, it has been customary from time immemorial for the legislature to declare what shall be a reasonable compensation under such circumstances, or, perhaps more properly speaking, to fix a maximum beyond which any charge made would be unreasonable. * * *
"We know that this is a power which may be abused; but that is no argument against its existence. For protection against abuses from legislatures the people must resort to the polls, not to the courts."
This declaration regarding the power of the legislatures to fix rates of businesses affected with a public interest *166
was clear and all inclusive. The doctrine that the people must resort to the polls, not to the courts, for redress against abuses of legislative power was re-affirmed on the same day in a group of cases known as the Granger cases, Chicago, Burlington Quincy Railroad Co. v. Iowa,
Mr. Justice Field, at this early date, was well aware of the fact that the legislature could not possibly deny to any owner of property the power to make as much money from his property as he had anticipated without destroying some portion of the value of that property. Since he thought that the value of private property must be protected at all costs, he dissented. "If it be admitted," he said, "that the legislature has any control over the compensation, * * *. the amount fixed will operate as a partial destruction of the value of the property, if it fall below the amount which the owner would obtain by contract * * *." He for this reason denied that the legislature had any right whatever to regulate the prices charged by the grain elevator owners.
The statement adhered to by the majority of the court to the effect that the courts would not interfere even though the legislature abused its power was not destined to stand. Seven years later in Spring Valley Water-Works v. Schottler,
In Dow v. Beidelman, 1887,
In 1894 in the case of Reagan v. Farmers' Loan TrustCo.,
During this early formative period rates were usually established by direct legislative enactment. It was untenable to hold that a legislative enactment per se lacked the elements of due process. Courts groped for a constitutional means by which the power to regulate could be checked. Since the process for setting rates — an act of the legislature — could not be deemed violative of due process, the courts looked to the result of the rate itself. If it was unreasonably low so that the court on the evidence could determine that it would not yield an adequate return, it was held unconstitutional by drawing an analogy with the familiar eminent domain cases. See Brewer's opinion in Ames v. Union Pac. Ry., C.C. 1894, 64 F. 165.
It was upon the stage thus set that the court in the now famous case of Smyth v. Ames,
At the time of Smyth v. Ames, because of existing price levels, the figure reached by applying the reproduction cost less depreciation formula would be considerably less than the actual amount of historical cost. Hence during this period the utilities were desirous of having rates based on historical cost. But inSan Diego Land Town Co. v. National City, 1899,
Next followed a decision in which the Court considered the rate of return (see Willcox v. Consolidated Gas Company,
The next major development occurred in 1913 with the decision in the Minnesota Rate Cases, Simpson v. Shepard,
Immediately following the end of the first World War, courts and commissions were urged to make allowances for the inflationary price levels then existing. The effect of abnormal prices and the recognition of a new price "plateau" upon the determination of present fair value was discussed at length by the court in Galveston Elec. Co. v. Galveston, 1922,
"But in determining present value, consideration must be given to prices and wages prevailing at the time of the investigation; and, in the light of all the circumstances, there must be an honest and intelligent forecast as to the probable price and wage levels during a reasonable period in the immediate future. In every confiscation case, the future as well as the present must be regarded. * * *" page 408 of 272 U.S., page 147 of 47 S.Ct.,
From 1923 until 1929 there were three other cases in addition to those last cited which are considered to be leading cases; namely, Georgia Railway Power Company v. RailroadCommission,
It was in the Southwestern Bell Telephone Company case that Justice Brandeis rendered his now famous concurring opinion in which he concurred in the result, but he dissented from the "fair value" doctrine of Smyth v. Ames and urged the court to adopt as the standard for measuring the reasonableness of rates the so-called "prudent investment" rule. According to Bauer and Gold, Public Utility Valuation, p. 88, "the minority opinion of Judge Brandeis, whatever one may think of it conclusions in support of `prudent investment,' is generally recognized as the ablest presentation *172 of the basic economic issues involved in valuation for rate making that has ever been delivered from the bench." Yet it failed to detour the majority of the court from its rigid adherence to the "fair value" rule.2
Another landmark case in the development of a standard for testing the reasonableness of utility rates is the case of LosAngeles Gas Electric Co. v. Railroad Commission ofCalifornia, 1933,
This case was followed in 1934 by the case of Lindheimer v.Illinois Bell Telephone Company,
"* * * this actual experience of the company is more convincing than tabulations of estimates. In the face of that experience, we are unable to conclude that the company has been operating under confiscatory intrastate rates. * * * The glaring incongruity between the effect of the findings below as to the amounts of return that must be available in order to avoid confiscation and the actual results of the company's business makes it impossible to accept those findings as a basis of decision." Page 163 of 292 U.S., page 663 of 54 S.Ct.,
The case of Dayton Power Light Co. v. Public UtilitiesCommission of Ohio,
Two other cases are worthy of note in the development of the law in this regard. They are Denver Union Stock Yard Co. v.United States, 1938,
This brings us to the case of Federal Power Commission v.Natural Gas Pipeline Co.,
After a detailed analysis, Hale concluded that in spite of the statement by Black, Douglas, and Murphy that "We think this is an appropriate occasion to lay the ghost of Smyth v. Ames,
At this point it may be noted that a majority of the members of the Supreme Court as constituted in 1942 had at one time or another expressed views contrary to those adhered to in the cases applying the fair value rule of Smyth v. Ames. See Mr. Justice (now Chief Justice) Stone's dissent in West v.Chesapeake Potomac Tele. of Baltimore,
The Hope case involved a petition by the Hope Natural Gas Company to review an order of the Federal Power Commission under the various provisions of the Natural Gas Act of 1938, 52 Stat. 821,
Sec. 6(a) provided that the same "Commission may investigate and ascertain the actual legitimate cost of the property of every natural-gas company, the depreciation therein, and, when found necessary for rate-making purposes, other facts which bear on the determination of such cost or depreciation and the fair value of such property."
The Federal Power Commission arrived at a rate base predicated upon the amount found by it to be "prudently invested" in the property devoted to public service. It found that Hope's estimates of reproduction cost and trended original cost were without probative value and ignored them. No consideration was given to the change in price levels occurring since the construction or acquisition of the properties. Upon the rate base so determined the Commission allowed a return of 6 1/2%. The Circuit Court of Appeals in an opinion reported in 4 Cir.,
At page 296 of 134 F.2d the Circuit Court of Appeals said that "It must not be forgotten that it is the property owned by the utility, and not the cash invested by stockholders in its stock, that is devoted to public use; that this property is worn out in furnishing the service which the public receives and which the utility is bound to render; and that, unless the utility receives a rate sufficient to make necessary replacements at current prices with a fair return upon the present fair value of its investment, its property is being taken from it and given to its customers." It went on at page 298 of 134 F.2d, to hold that "original investment cost cannot be taken alone as a measure of the present fair value of the property * * *." Many of the "present fair value" cases were discussed.
Certiorari was granted by the United States Supreme Court. In an opinion reported in
The foregoing discussion regarding constitutional limitations is of necessity not complete. For more detailed analysis see Bauer and Gold, "Public Utility Valuation," 1934, pages 25 to 111, inclusive; Barnes, "The Economics of Public Utility Regulation," 1942, p. 370-403; Bondright, "Valuation of Property," 1937, pp. 1078-1110; Beutel, Valuation As A Requirement of Due Process, 43 Harvard Law Review 1249; Hale, "Does the Ghost of Smyth v. Ames Still Walk?," 55 Harvard Law Review 1116.
We need not here consider the economic merits of either the "prudent investment" or the "fair value" concept of rate making. In this regard see Barnes, Economics of Utility *179 Regulation, p. 545. The arguments for "prudent investment" as against "fair value" have been set forth by various members of the Supreme Court upon several occasions.5
From the foregoing it becomes clear that the Supreme Court is now committed to the view that there is no constitutional requirement that utilities be permitted to earn a "fair return" on the "fair value" of the property devoted to the public use. The Hope case stands squarely for the 1, 2 doctrine that it is the final impact of the rate order which is controlling insofar as Federal constitutional limitations are concerned. So long as the rate set does not confiscate the property devoted to public service, the rate order will not be held to violate substantive constitutional principles. The legislature is free to determine its own economic policy in regard to the fixing of rates. Its power to set rates is, however, still circumscribed by two constitutional limitations: (1) substantive constitutional law requires that the rates finally set shall not be confiscatory; and (2) the requirements or procedural due process must still be followed.
The petitioner in its reply brief concedes that it has no claim for relief under the substantive constitutional law of the Federal Constitution. We have included the history and development of the Federal doctrine as a background for *180 what we shall hereafter say and as especially applicable in our consideration of the Company's contention that the Utah law requires the Commission to take value as the base and further in our consideration of the term "just and reasonable rates."
Our holding, and the Company's concession, that the legislature itself, under substantive constitutional law, would have had the power to ignore value and adopt in lieu thereof prudent investment in establishing a rate base, brings us to the Company's contention that even though the legislature itself does have such power, it did not delegate that power to the Public Service Commission. It contends that the doctrine of "fair value" as developed in Smyth v. Ames is embedded in the Utah statutes and that such statutes, aside from any constitutional limitations, require the Commission to bottom utility rates upon a "fair value" rate base.
If it were determined that the legislature of Utah had by the Utilities Act directed the Commission to use "value" as the rate base in arriving at just and reasonable rates, the fact the the Supreme Court of the United States has now departed from its earlier holding of Smyth v. Ames would make no 3 difference. A change in substantive constitutional law which now permits as constitutional the use of "prudent investment" as a rate base cannot eradicate from the statutes of this state a legislative mandate that rates be based on "value" if such mandate in fact exists in our statutes. In this regard see the holding and reasoning of Peoples Natural Gas Co. v.Pennsylvania Pub. Utility Commission,
The particular Utah statutes relied upon by the Company in support of this contention are sections 76-4-21 and 76-6-19, U.C.A. 1943. Section 76-4-21 provides:
"The commission shall have power to ascertain the value of the property of every public utility in this state and every fact which in its judgment may or does have any bearing on such value. The commission shall have power to make revaluations from time to time and to ascertain the value of new construction, extensions, and *181 additions to the property of every public utility; provided, that the valuation of the property of all public utilities doing business within this state located in Utah as recorded in accordance with section 76-4-21 of this chapter shall be considered the actual value of the properties of said public utilities in Utah unless otherwise changed after hearings by order of the commission. In case the commission changes the valuation of the properties of any public utility said new valuations found by the commission shall be the valuations of said public utility for all purposes provided in this chapter."6
The company contends that this section should be construed as a mandate to the Commission to find the value of public utilities and to use that value as a base for determining just and reasonable rates. Section 76-6-19 implements 76-4-21 and provides the procedure to be followed by the 4 Commission in ascertaining value thereunder. Reliance is placed particularly on the following portion of Section 76-6-19:
"For the purpose of ascertaining the matters and things specified in section 76-4-21 the commission may cause hearings to be held at such times and places as the commission may designate. * * * All public utilities affected shall be entitled to be heard and to introduce evidence as such hearings. * * * The commission shall make and file its findings of fact * * *. The findings of the commission so made and filed * * * shall be admissible in evidence in any action, proceeding or hearing before the commission or any court in which the commission, the state or any officer, department or institution thereof, or any county, municipality or other body politic and the public utility affected may be interested, whether arising under the provisions of this title or otherwise, and such findings, when so introduced, shall be conclusive evidence of the facts therein stated, as of the date therein stated * * *. The commission may from time to time cause further hearings and investigations to be had for the purpose of making revaluations or ascertaining the value of any betterments, improvements * * * subsequent to any prior hearing or investigation * * *." *182
The Company contends that this language shows a legislative intent to have rates based upon value and argues that if "cost" were to be taken in place of "value" there would be no necessity for or meaning to the language requiring revaluations from time to time.
We believe that these two statutes, even when lifted from the Act and considered by themselves, show that the legislature contemplated that there would be situations under which various departments of the state would find it necessary to know or to prove the value of a public utility. This is evidenced by the provision that the findings of value, when properly made, would be admissible in evidence in the various named proceedings in which the departments of the state or various bodies politic might be interested. This language indicates that these section (76-4-21 and 76-6-19) were not designed to require the Commission to find value for rate making purposes. Since the valuation findings were by statute made admissible in evidence in various types of proceedings and were to be conclusive in absence of a showing of changed conditions, etc., it is only logical that the statute would provide a procedure for revaluations from time to time to keep the valuation abreast of changing conditions.
There is nothing in Section 76-4-21 which requires that it be construed as a mandate to the Commission to base rates on value rate base. The provision that the "commission shall have power to ascertain the value" is not the equivalent of a provision that the "commission shall ascertain value." Nor is the provision that when the Commission finds new valuations "said new valuations * * * shall be the valuations * * * for all purposes" the equivalent of a provision that "value is to be used for all purposes." If this section stood by itself it might be susceptible of such an interpretation, when, however, it is considered in relation to other sections of the same chapter, it becomes fairly clear that it should not be so construed.
Section 76-4-1 gives the Commission general jurisdiction over every public utility in the state of Utah. The Commission *183 is there given power "to supervise and regulate every public utility in this state, and to supervise all of the business of every such public utility in this state, and to do all things, whether herein specifically designated or in addition thereto, which are necessary or convenient in the exercise of such power and jurisdiction."
Section 76-4-2 authorizes the Commission to proceed upon its own motion to investigate any schedule of rates and charges. It is directed to fix a time and place for hearing and notify the utility concerning which such investigation is being made. Upon hearing it "shall make such findings and orders as shall be just and reasonable with respect to any such matter." Section 76-4-3 deals with rates of carriers. Section 76-4-4 provides that:
"Whenever the commission shall find * * * that the rates * * * are unjust, unreasonable, discriminatory or preferential, or in anywise in violation of any provision of law, or that such rates * * * are insufficient, the commission shall determine the just, reasonable or sufficient rates * * * and shall fix the same by order as hereinafter provided."
These sections give the Commission general jurisdiction over utility rates. They empower the Commission to do all things necessary to supervise and regulate every utility in this state. They provide that rates are to be just and reasonable and direct the Commission to fix just and reasonable rates by order after hearing. These sections are broad and sweeping in scope. The limitations placed on the exercise of full legislative powers by said sections are: first, that the Commission proceed by notice and hearing; and second, that the rates established conform to the standard of "just and reasonable." These sections contain no mandate that rates be based on a fair value rate base. We so stated in State ex rel. Pub. Service Comm. v. Southern PacificCo.,
"Prior to the enactment of the challenged amendments [Chap. 87 and 100, Laws of Utah, 1937], the Public Service Commission had plenary power to regulate utilities and to fix rates which should *184 be fair and reasonable. There was no legislative requirement that the utility rates be based on the fair value of the property but only that they be fair and reasonable."
It may be, as contended by the Company, that this quoted matter was not strictly necessary to a decision in the Southern Pacific case, but it was a part of the rationale of the holding of the court. We think that it correctly stated the law.
The Company cites Peoples Natural Gas Co. v. PennsylvaniaPublic Utility Commission,
"commission may, after reasonable notice and hearing, ascertain and fix fair value of the whole or any part of the property of any public utility * * * and ascertain the fair value of all new construction, * * * When any public utility furnishes more than one of the different types of utility service * * * the commission shall segregate the property used and useful in furnishing each type of such service and shall not consider the property of such public utility as a unit in determining the value of the property of such public utility for the purpose offixing rates." (Italics added.)
The location of the Pennsylvania valuation section under an article with a title relating only to rates; the fact that all other sections under said article deal directly with rates; and the reference in the valuation section to fixing rates furnish considerable support for the Pennsylvania Court's *185 holding that the statutes required the Commission to base utility rates on a value rate base. It is upon these factors that we think the two statutes differ.
The Company has advanced various other arguments in support of its contention that the Utah valuation section (76-4-21) must be construed as a mandate to the Commission to bottom rates upon a value rate base.
First, the Company contends that the Utah Act was copied from the Public Utility Act of Idaho and that the Supreme Court of Idaho in Murray v. Public Utilities Commission,
While the Idaho court in Murray v. Public ServiceCommission [
The Company's second argument designed to have us construe the Utah Act as a directive to the Commission to fix rates in relation to fair value is that the Utah Commission has consistently so construed the statutes and that such administrative interpretations are entitled to great 7 weight. The proposition of law implicit in this argument is well settled. Consistent administrative *187
interpretations over the years by the officers charged with the duty of applying the statute and making each part work efficiently and smoothly are entitled to great weight by the courts. United States v. American Trucking Ass'n,
Closely allied to this argument is the third argument in which the Company seeks to invoke the principle of law that when the legislature re-adopts a statute or act without change after uniform and notorious construction by officers required to administer it the presumption is that the 8 legislature knew of such construction and adopted it in re-enacting the statute. This doctrine has been criticized (see 54 Harvard Law Review p. 1311, Article by A.H. Feller) but it nevertheless is supported by considerable authority. State Boardof Land Commissioners v. Ririe, supra,
The Commission contends that these principles have no application because it contends the Utah Act has not been uniformly construed as a mandate from the legislature to fix utility rates on a fair value rate base. The Company takes the position that "from the beginning of 1917 down to and including the filing of its original complaint in the case now under review, [the commission has] adhered consistently to the rule that the value of property devoted to the public service must be ascertained as a rate base." The Company cites 23 cases decided by the Utah Commission in which the fixing of rates was involved and it contends that in every one of these cases the Commission adhered to a fair value rate base. *188
We have examined each of the 23 cases cited. From them it appears that the Commission has in the past consistently adhered to the fair value rule of Smyth v. Ames. Statements similar to the following taken from In the Matter of the Application of the Utah Gas and Coke Company, case No. 233, 3 R.P.U.C. 75 are found throughout the discussions in many of these cases:
"The Commission takes occasion to say that it is in full harmony with the well established and economically correct rule that public service corporations should be permitted to earn `a fair return upon the reasonable value of the property at the time it is being used for the public.'"
Yet not one of these cases construed the Public Utilities Act of Utah as a mandate to the Commission to fix utility rates on a fair value rate base. In fact in case number 6; In Re Application of the Utah Light Traction Company, the Commission concluded that "when the Legislature enacted the Public Utilities Commission Law, its intention was to delegate all its power in respect to rate regulation to such Commission. That was one of the chief reasons for the creation of the Public Utilities Commission." It is apparent that the Commission thought the limitation placed upon the rate making power of the Commission, which limitation required the Commission to fix rates upon a fair value rate base, was a restriction upon legislative power by principles of substantive constitutional law. So that while the Commission throughout its various opinions adhered to the fair value rule of Smyth v. Ames, it indicated that it did so because it understood that it was required to do so by the court decisions applying constitutional law. The cases cannot be construed as holding that the Public Utilities Act contained a mandate to the Commission to fix rates on a fair value rate base.
In case number 87, 2 R.P.U.C. 27, In re Application of the Utah Gas Coke Company, the Commission did discuss the language (Sec. 76-4-21) relied upon by the Company. *189 However, the Commission did not say that this language required the Commission to find value and fix rates upon a fair value rate base. What the Commission did say was that: "In determining just and reasonable rates, the basis of calculation is the fair value of the property used and useful for the convenience of the public. The authority granted to the Commission to ascertain the value of public utilities is contained in Sec. 18 of Article 4, Chapter 47, Compiled Laws of Utah, 1917 (quoting it)." (This section was identical with 76-4-21 relied upon by the Company.) The Company would have us construe this language to say that "The Commission is required by this section to find value and fix rates upon a fair value rate base." We think it apparent from the whole of this case that the Commission believed that the mandate to fix rates on value came from the court decisions which followed Smyth v. Ames and that the statute was but the authorization, the delegation of power, to the Commission empowering it to undertake procedure to ascertain value; that the mandate came not from the legislature, but from the courts.
The situation in respect to the Commission cases is this: The Commission has consistently approved the fair value rule ofSmyth v. Ames. Its former opinions indicated that it did so because it interpreted the various federal and state court decisions as requiring it. In one case the Commission interpreted the Public Utilities Act as an attempt by legislature to delegate all its rate making power to the Commission. None of these cases construed the act as a mandate to fix rates on a value rate base. When the substantive constitutional limitation imposed by the United States Supreme Court in Smyth v. Ames was removed, the Commission, insofar as its past decisions were concerned, could consistently and logically hold that it was no longer required to fix utility rates in accordance with the rule ofSmyth v. Ames.
The Company next points out that when the Utah Public Utilities Act was enacted in 1917, constitutional substantive *190 law required adherence to the fair value principle of rate making. It contends that it must therefore be held that the Utah Act was enacted in reference to and 9 incorporated the constitutional restriction of the fair value rule of Smyth v. Ames. If the legislature by statute had expressly restricted the powers of the Commission to conform with the prevailing rule of constitutional law, this last mentioned factor would be a logical explanation of such restriction. But the fact that such constitutional restrictions existed at the time of the enactment is hardly justification for construing the Act narrowly. It is equally logical to hold that the legislature intended to delegate all the powers of rate making to the Commission that it could constitutionally delegate subject only to express statutory restrictions. The removal of the constitutional barrier erected by Smyth v. Ames unleashed the power of the Commission and permitted it to expand into fields previously restricted by earlier court decisions.
The statute cannot be construed as requiring the Commission to fix utility rates on a value rate base. The legislature gave full rate making power to the Commission subject only to the limitations of procedural due process and the requirement that rate established be just and 10 reasonable. This standard "just and reasonable" has been held to be the same as the constitional standard. FederalPower Commission v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., supra,
The Company next contends that even though it be determined that the Commission had the authority to discard the "fair value" theory and to substitute therefor "prudent investment" in ascertaining the proper base for fixing utility rates, the Commission nevertheless erred in excluding from the 11 "prudent investment" base certain items of cost. The specification of error has been divided by counsel into four parts for the purpose of discussion. Exception is first taken to the exclusion from the rate base of certain fees (hereinafter referred to as "Phoenix Fees") paid by the Company to affiliate companies for construction of electric plant.
Under the terms of these cost-plus contracts, the Company paid to the Phoenix Companies all the costs of construction plus additional fees averaging about 3 1/4% of total cost. The Commission found that the fees so paid by the Company to the Phoenix Companies constituted inter-company profits and concluded that these amounts paid as profits to affiliate companies could not be properly included in the rate base. The amount paid to the Phoenix Companies and thus excluded from the rate base was $997,472.27.
There is no evidence to show that the fees thus paid to the Phoenix Companies were exorbitant. The work was properly and skillfully done. There is nothing to indicate that the work could have been done more cheaply or efficiently had the work been let to nonaffiliated construction concerns under competitive bidding. The Company at the time when the work was done did not have the facilities to do the work for itself. Had the work been let to other nonaffiliate concerns, similar costs would have been incurred. It thus appears that the sole ground for the exclusion from the rate base of the Phoenix fees was that said fees represented profits to affiliates and as such were not properly includable.
The Commission urges that in this regard the corporate entities of these various affiliate corporations must be disregarded and that these payments to Phoenix Companies should be in substance considered as payments by the Company to itself. It would appear self-evident that had the Company had its own construction department which had done this construction work, it could not have paid itself a profit nor had profits included in the rate base. This would be true regardless of how cheaply or efficiently the work was done. The Company could not pyramid its rate base by including therein profits paid by it to itself.
The situation would be little changed by placing a corporate veil between the Company and its construction department. If the incorporated construction department were still fully owned and controlled by the Company, *193 it would essentially still be a case where the parent would be doing the construction work for itself. This would be especially true if the subsidiary corporation had no separate substantial assets or capital of its own. The amount of capital devoted to the public service would remain unchanged. There would be no justification to add anything to the rate base over and above the actual cost of construction. We need not consider the situation under which the subsidiary corporation has substantial separate assets of its own, for as will be subsequently noted, the Phoenix Companies had no assets. In the case of a "dummy" corporation organized without substantial assets of its own to do construction work for the parent corporation there is no reasonable basis as far as rate making is concerned upon which it could be paid anything more than actual costs. Any profits paid to it would redound to the benefit of the parent corporation with the result that the profits would in effect be returned to the parent corporation. If this expenditure by the parent to pay the subsidiary a profit were also written into the rate base so that it could be recouped from the public the parent corporation would in effect have its cake and eat it too. Such fictitious "write-ups" should not be permitted.
The underlying principle is not changed by the addition to the picture of a holding company (Electric Bond Share) which owns both the construction corporation and the 12 operating utility. Alabama Power Co. v. Federal PowerCommission, 5 Cir.,
It was admitted on behalf of the Company by counsel that the Phoenix Companies were in effect the construction department of Electric Bond Share Company; that Electric Bond Share functioned through the Phoenix Companies. The Phoenix Companies were organized primarily for the purpose of enabling the parent company (Electric Bond Share) to in effect qualify to do business under the laws of the various states and to provide a method of segregating the accounts for construction work from its other business. No attempt was made to hold the Phoenix Companies apart *194 as distinct entities from Electric Bond Share. The payments of these profits (Phoenix Fees) to the Phoenix Companies was in effect a payment direct to Electric Bond Share.
The Commission held and the evidence discloses that the Phoenix Companies had no assets of their own. The Phoenix Utility Company, successor to other Phoenix Companies, had only nominal capitalization and substantially no direct overhead costs or administrative organization distinct from that of Electric Bond Share Company. With this nominal capitalization (only 20 shares of outstanding stock valued at $100 per share) the Phoenix Companies completed nearly $37,000,000 in construction for its associate, the Utah Power Light Company. In view of the evidence showing that every service rendered by Electric Bond Share Company was billed as an item of cost; that all employees were compensated by the Company; that part of the overhead expense of New York offices was allocated to the Utah construction; and the further fact that there were no assets or employees of Electric Bond Share that were shown to have been devoted to or employed in connection with construction for the Company which were not paid for by the Company, we cannot hold that the Commission was arbitrary in refusing to include in the rate base an aditional amount representing additional payments to Electric Bond Share Company in connection with this construction.
The Phoenix Companies operated in the field with the assets of the operating utility for which the work was being done. Thus while the $37,000,000 in construction was being done for the Company, it was in reality done with the company's assets. It was as though the Electric Bond Share Company had loaned its construction department to the Company in the same way as it might loan a skilled employee. The salaries of all employees of the Phoenix Companies who were connected with the construction for the Company were paid by the Company, as were all other labor costs. A proportionate share of overhead and office *195 expenses was allocated to the cost of the jobs being done for the Company. Phoenix purchased materials in the Company's name and for its account. There is no evidence which would even raise an inference that any assets of the Electric Bond Share Company or any other affiliate were used without compensation in construction of Utah plant.
The position taken by the Company regarding the failure of the Commission to include these Phoenix fees in the rate base is not new to the courts. A similiar contention was made inPennsylvania Power Light Co. v. Federal Power Comm., 3 Cir.,
"The facts of the present case justify the Commission's conclusion that a close relationship existed in the Electric Bond and Share holding company system among the licensee (Pennsylvania Power Light), Phoenix and Electric Bond and Share. Since the incorporation of Phoenix in 1906 as a construction company Electric Bond and Share has owned its total outstanding stock of 20 shares having a par value of $100 each. Aside from its name Phoenix has no genuine corporate existence. It operates with no funds of its own, has no construction equipment, no officers or employees of its own but only such as are supplied by Electric Bond and Share or by the operating companies, and pays none of their salaries. It operates only within the Electric Bond and Share system and obtains none of its contracts as a result of competitive bidding.
Certiorari was denied by the United States Supreme Court in
From the record it appears that the Commission did allow approximately $47,000 for organization expenses. This fact was acknowledged by witness Richard H. Jones who testified for the Company. There is no satisfactory evidence from which this court could conclude that the *197 Commission was arbitrary or that this was an insufficient allowance. Counsel for the Company admitted that the $350,000 estimate claimed by the Company could not be supported by documentary evidence. On the bill to the Company there was a $310,000 item identified only as "Promotion Services, Electric Bond and Share Company." This item is also referred to as an "award" to Electric Bond Share Company. In a letter by L.B. Weigers, secretary and treasurer of Electric Bond Share Company, it is reported that said Company could not give a more detailed explanation of the amounts "awarded" to it. Under this state of the record we are not prepared to hold that the Commission was arbitrary in not allowing more.
Various other amounts expended in the sale of preferred stock and excluded from the rate base fall in a different class. At least a portion of these other amounts was properly expended. They undoubtedly represent legitimate expense of financing the Company. The Commission did not hold to the contrary. It excluded these items on the theory that they were expenditures that added nothing to the property of the corporation; that they should be considered as items of expense to be recovered from revenues, and that they should not be included in plant account. It took the view that since these items of expenditure did not represent tangible plant assets they should be recovered by the utility out of the return earned on its property. We are thus confronted with the question of law: Has the utility a right to have the cost of the issuance and sale of its preferred stock included as a plant asset in the rate base upon which it will be permitted to earn a fair return?
The Commission quoted from the report by the National Association of Railroad Utility Commissioners (1936, 48th Annual Convention) in connection with the adoption of the present Uniform System of Accounts as a basis for refusing to include this preferred stock expense in the rate base. This quotation follows:
"`Commissions and expenses on the issuance and sale of preferred stock do not give rise to property and should not be included in the utility plant accounts of the utility. Such items represent a cost of money and should be recovered by the utility out of the return earned on its property. There is essentially no difference between commissions and expenses on capital stock issues and discount and expense on bond issues. Both represent a cost of money to the utility. The amortization of bond discount and expense has been rightfully considered a part of the interest cost of the issue and as such has been considered recoverable out of the return earned on the property. Commissions and expenses on capital stock should be treated in the same manner.'"
Two witnesses (Gadsby and Jones) for the Company testified that they did not believe that this expense of issuing and selling preferred stock should be included as *199 a factor both in establishing the rate of return and in the rate base — that it should only be included in one of these two places.
Gadsby referred to the cost of selling preferred stock as one of the arguments for a higher rate of return. On the other hand, witness Thain for the Commission testified that this preferred stock expense would have been properly included in plant account in 1934 when a different system of accounting was used and that its present removal from the plant account was because of a change in accounting systems.
As we view this problem it appears that the expenses of issuing and selling preferred stock cannot be included in the rate base and also be taken into account in fixing the rate of return. Further, that if they be once recouped from the public, they should no longer be included in either 15 place. But until once recouped from the public and if legitimate items of expense, and some of these were, it would appear that the Company should be allowed to include these expenses as a part of the rate base or in the alternative to recover said expenses out of the return earned on its property. No cases have been cited by either the Commission staff or by the Company which deal with this problem. However, since the expenses do not represent property nor tangible assets in the Company, we are of the opinion that the Commission should not be required to include such items in the rate base. This is essentially a problem in accounting and as such should be left to the discretion of the Commission.
The Company entered into a lease agreement with the Traction Company under which the Company leased the electric properties thus acquired. The problem arose as to how these leased properties were to be represented in the rate base of the Company. In the case of all other properties acquired by the Company system cost (the cost of acquisition paid by the first company in the Electric Bond Share group) was recommended by the Commission's staff and adopted by the Commission as the correct rate base. For this reason the Company contends that the Commission should have included this leased property at the actual cost paid by the Traction Company for the property when it was purchased from the Oregon Short Line Railroad Company group. This, the company contends, would have been the equivalent of allowing system cost. The Commission refused to adopt this view and in lieu thereof allowed only the original cost of constructing said properties. By allowing original cost rather than system cost, all intangibles such as good will, going concern value, etc., were eliminated. Only the actual original cost of constructing the physical properties was allowed. There was a difference of $1,800,000 between the Company's claimed system cost and the original cost figure allowed by the Commission. It is this $1,800,000 item which the Company contends was improperly excluded from the rate base.
The argument that this $1,800,000 should have been included in the rate base is predicated upon the proposition that system cost of these electric properties exceeded the original cost of said properties by that amount. At the *201 outset the Commission challenged the correctness of this proposition. The electric properties were acquired as a part of a transaction involving the sale of four separate groups of properties — to wit: the electric properties, the railway system, the artificial gas and the steam heating properties. At the time of acquisition no attempt was made to segregate the amount of the total purchase price to be allotted to any particular property. It is referred to as a "basket transaction" under which a "basket" of properties was sold for a total, unsegregated purchase price. The Company freely admitted that there was no documentary evidence by which it could now be told how much of said total price should have been allocated to the electric properties. The Company's evidence, designed to show that 58.9% of the total purchase price should be allocated to the electric properties, was found by the Commission to be not convincing. It amounted to little more than a rough estimate based on a segregation of the earnings of these various properties.
Further there is some disagreement concerning the amount actually paid by the Traction Company as the total purchase price. The Company contends that a total of $16,260,905.34 was paid for all the properties. This figure was apparently arrived at by adding the cost of capital stock issued ($1,024,215.39) to the amount of funded debt assumed ($15,476,000) and subtracting therefrom net sundry assets in the amount of $239,310.05. The Commission questioned the correctness of this figure by noting that the Company had failed to consider plant accounts, the reserve for depreciation and surplus in its computation. In view of the indefinite nature of this evidence as to the amount of the total purchase price which should have been allocated to the electric properties and in view of the question regarding the total purchase price paid, we cannot say that the Commission was arbitrary in not accepting the Company's estimate and in using in lieu thereof the Company's own book figures regarding the original cost of these electric properties. *202
We do not understand that the Company seriously contends that this $1,800,000 was absolutely correct and that this is the exact figure which should have been adopted. Rather it complains because the Commission refused even to attempt to estimate the system cost of the electric properties. It contends that the evidence was sufficiently clear to enable the Commission to make an estimate concerning the amount that should have been allocated to the electric properties and that every inference from the evidence is that the system cost (the amount actually paid by the Traction Company) was higher than original cost (the amount it originally cost to construct).
It should be noted that in regard to all other property which was represented in the rate base by including the system cost of said property, the Company actually owned the property. But in regard to this property all the Company had was a lease — it did not acquire the property. We are not prepared to hold that the Commission was required to include in the rate base the price which the Traction Company paid for this property. The Traction Company still owns it — it is not unreasonable or arbitrary to hold that the Traction Company should absorb the cost of the intangible assets, such as good will and going concern value (if any such intangible values in fact existed) which were incident to the purchase of this property from the Oregon Short Line Railroad Company group. When this last mentioned factor is taken together with the fact that the evidence designed to show that the system cost which should be allocated to the electric properties, which cost was considerably higher than original cost, is nothing more than a rough estimate, it appears that we should not hold that the Commission was unreasonable and arbitrary in excluding this estimated figure of $1,800,000 and accepting in lieu thereof the Company's original cost figures.
"The Company's purpose in introducing such testimony was to present evidence of value which would be helpful to the Commission in reaching a just conclusion as to the fair value of the property of the Company used and useful in rendering service to its customers in the State of Utah. * * *"
In view of this avowed purpose, it would seem that our holding that the Commission was not required to find the "present fair value" of the Company's property, and our holding that the Commission was not required to give effect to evidence regarding "value," should completely dispose of this contention. If the Commission was not required to find value nor to give effect to evidence regarding value, it could not be held to have been arbitrary had it completely disregarded this evidence which was adduced solely for the purpose of showing value.
In regard to this evidence the Commission said:
"We believe that the theory adopted by this witness [Smith] is fundamentally unsound. It should not be used as a guide to fair return or capital requirements of the Company because investments are not made on such a wholly impractical basis. The investment in utility bonds and preferred stocks is made on the basis of a fixed return and the return on utility common stock is considered in connection with the fair rate of return. It is idle to argue that the obligations of the ratepayers to the Company should be based on *204 the fluctuating value of the dollar when the Company has no such obligation to its investors."
We deem the various propositions asserted in this statement by the Commission to be essentially sound. They will bear some amplification.
In his concurring opinion in Southwestern Bell Tel. Co. v.Public Service Commission,
"About 75 per cent of the capital invested in utilities is represented by bonds. He who buys bonds seeks primarily safety. If he can obtain it, he is content with a low rate of interest. Through a fluctuating rate base the bondholder can only lose. He can receive no benefit from a rule which increases the rate base as the price level rises; for his return, expressed in dollars, would be the same, whatever the income of the company."
This observation made by Justice Brandeis would also hold true as to preferred stockholders. The return which a preferred stockholder is to receive on his investment is a fixed return. He can gain nothing from having a fluctuating base which varies with the purchasing power of the dollar. The number of dollars which he would receive would not increase with an increase in company income. He like the bondholder could not gain by the adoption of a rate base that would fluctuate as the dollar changed in value.
It would be the common stockholder who could expect to reap any benefits that would inure to the Company as a result of tying the rate base to the fluctuating value of the dollar. If this factor is to be taken into account for the benefit of the common stockholders, we agree with the Commission that it can best be given effect in fixing the rate of return which is to be allowed. A fluctuating rate of return would be a much better way to control the amount which the common stockholder should receive than a fluctuating rate base. In its report the Commission stated that *205 the effect which changing price levels would have upon the fair return to the Company "will be adequately recognized and compensated for in the rate of return which we shall apply to the just and proper rate base." The Commission cannot be held to have been arbitrary in refusing to give effect to the evidence of cheaper dollars of 1941 and 1942.
The rate order directed the Company to formulate a schedule of charges for electrical energy so as to reflect reductions in price per kwh which, when applied to the 1941 volume of sales, would amount to a reduction in gross receipts of not less than $1,504,644. In making this order the Commission concluded that "There is no foreseeable condition which would warrant a conclusion that future revenues or earnings would be less than those of the year 1941." So long as operating expenses do not substantially exceed those of 1941 and the volume of sales of electrical energy remains substantially the same as in 1941, the Company will, on these new rates, be able to obtain a fair (6%) rate of return on the established rate base. *206
The company contends that 1941 was an abnormal year and that it could not be used as a guide to future revenues and expenses of the Company. The argument implicit in this contention is that sales were abnormally high and/or that expenses were abnormally low in 1941. The Company also urges that the Commission should have taken Company experience over several years as the true pattern. The Company, in support of its argument that sales in future years cannot be expected to equal the volume attained in 1941, produced evidence calculated to show that Utah Copper Company would soon supply its own electrical needs. Utah Copper Company, in 1941, was the Company's largest purchaser — it purchased nearly 50% of all power sold by the Company in Utah.
In attacking the choice of the year 1941 as the pattern year the Company seems to take the position that the Commission is only trying to fix post-war rates. It seems to forget that the rates established will also be in effect for the duration of the war emergency. The Commission was not required to set rates at a level which would permit excessive profits during the war merely because at some indefinite date in the unforeseeable future economic conditions might return to "normalcy." The president of the Company stated, in explanation of statements made in the 1941 annual report to the stockholders of the Company, that so long as the activities which have grown up as a result of the war continue in operation, it would be an advantage to the Company to be relieved of the necessity of selling low priced power to the Utah Copper Company. His testimony indicates that so long as present conditions prevailed the Company had no serious problem in selling all of the electric energy that it could produce with its present plant.
The revenues and expenses for 10 months of 1942 and estimated revenues and expenses for last two months of 1942 and all of 1943 were introduced in evidence. The net operating revenue for 1942 and estimated revenues *207 for 1943 were considerably higher than for 1941 when the figures for all years are considered before federal income tax and excess profit taxes were deducted.
However, when federal income and excess profit taxes are included in the computations it appears that net operating revenues for 1942 and 1943 would be somewhat lower than those of 1941. This is occasioned by the fact that the figures when including said taxes include for 1942 nearly $1,480,000 in excess profit taxes, which taxes would not be imposed after the proposed rate order is put into effect and were not included in 1941. It would seem, therefore, that the Commission has ample support for its finding that net operating revenues for 1942 and estimated revenues for 1943 after the rate reduction would be higher than in 1941.
In answer to this, the Company notes that the comparison of one war year with another war year give no reliable guide to the expectancies of normal years of peace. With this we agree. But it should again be noted that the Commission was not establishing rates purely for the post-war era. These same rates are expected to be in effect for the duration of the war emergency. The fact that there may in the future be a business recession is no justification now for exorbitant rates. It is to be expected that if unusual economic repercussions follow this war that the Commission would make the necessary adjustments in the Company's rate schedule. These comparisons between 1942 and 1943 on the one hand and 1941 on the other do indicate that so long as the war and the increased industrial activity resulting from the war continue, the Company can be expected to equal 1941 net electric operating revenues. We are not prepared to say that the Commission was required to attempt to estimate how long it will be after the war before we return to "normalcy." The president of the Company, in testifying, stated: "When the war is over, and any speculation as to what is going to happen when the war is over reaches pretty far out into the realm of speculation — I think *208 when that time comes the job will be ours to get out to try and find this market." (The market for power released by Utah Copper.) It would appear that this is a correct appraisal of attempts to foresee economic conditions. Thus, unless there were evidence in the record which would affirmatively show that the established rates will not yield a fair return on the established rate base, we will not say that the Commission was arbitrary.
The Company relied primarily upon the loss of the Utah Copper Company business to show that future years would yield less revenue than was obtained in 1941. But the president of the Company in a report to the stockholders admitted that it would be an advantage to the Company to lose this account so long as the increased activity incident to the war continued. At the hearing he admitted that such a report was made to the stockholders and that the statements made in the report were true. The advantage came from the fact that power was sold to the Utah Copper Company at a rate considerably lower than it was sold to any other consumer. Because of the war activity in the area served by the Company, it was able to find other sales for its power and the sales would be at a higher rate per kwh. Since the Company could not have furnished the Copper Company with its full power needs and also furnished all the power needs of the war industries and regular consumers, it would have had to expand its productive capacity. This additional capacity may not be needed in post-war years. If the Company had been required to expand to meet the needs of the Copper Company and all other needs as increased by the war and then had lost the Copper Company business and had had its other purchases reduced by a post-war recession, it would have been faced with productive capacity far in excess of available purchasers. It is therefore understandable why the president of the Company said it was an advantage to have the Copper Company start to furnish its own power needs at this time. So long as the Company is able to replace the revenues *209 which would be lost by the loss of the Copper Company business, it will not be prejudiced by the Commission's rate order.8
In Los Angeles Salt Lake Railroad Co. v. Public UtilitiesCommission,
"The evidence adduced in the St. John Station Case in this regard cannot be considered as evidence adduced in this case. While the same counsel for the railroad may have appeared in both cases, and the same witnesses testified for the railroad in both cases, * * * yet the cross-examination which the railroad counsel might direct in the Faust case to the witnesses who appeared in the St. John case, if they appeared in the Faust case, might vary materially because of the new witnesses who appeared in the Faust case. The commission, like a jury, can consider such facts in relation to evidence adduced which constitute the common facts of life and which form the common knowledge of mankind and can take judicial knowledge of such fact as a court may take judicial notice of. Such facts permit the fact finder to interpret evidence and articulate it to the general facts of life. The commission may also, perhaps, take judicial notice of such facts and practices as are generally known throughout *211 the whole field of railroad transportation; * * * but it cannot take its special knowledge which it may have gained from experience or from other hearings and base any findings or conclusions upon such knowledge. That is fundamental."
To the same effect see Spencer v. Industrial Commission,
Gellhorn in his work on "Administrative Law" discusses these and various cases from other jurisdictions. See page 652 to 658. He suggests that in cases like these the administrative agency is in fact merely referring to its official files. He notes that while this is unconventional, it is likely to be a very trustworthy source of information and that the matters contained in the file may supplant the need for other evidence. He then concludes that:
"3. The objection that the material so incorporated in the record is incompetent because there is no opportunity for cross-examination, should be rejected; but
"4. Opportunity ought to be afforded to rebut, explain, or qualify, even where the material is derived from documents originally made available by the party against whom it is now being used."
Because of the above authorities, we must conclude that the frequent references by the Commission to matters not in the record was error. However, in no instance are any of the material findings or conclusions made by the Commission without other supporting competent evidence. For this reason, we are not inclined to reverse this case for this error. This is, however, the third time that this question has been before this court and we have condemned this conduct in unmistakable terms. This practice should not be followed in the future.
"* * * What annual rate will constitute just compensation depends upon many circumstances, and must be determined by the exercise of a fair and enlightened judgment, having regard to all relevant facts. A public utility is entitled to such rates as will permit it to earn a return on the value of the property which it employs for the convenience of the public equal to that generally being made at the same time and in the same general part of the country on investments in other business undertakings which are attended by corresponding risks and uncertainties; but it has no constitutional right to profits such as are realized or anticipated in highly profitable enterprises or speculative ventures. The return should be reasonably sufficient to assure confidence in the financial soundness of the utility and should be adequate, under efficient and economical management, to maintain and support its credit and enable it to raise the money necessary for the proper discharge of its public duties."
This language was also quoted with approval by the Commission in its report. Both sides apparently concede that it correctly states the law.
The Commission's report referred to Exhibit "M," introduced by the Commission's staff, to ascertain current data concerning interest rates, "utility interest rates and yields and recent financing, general economic conditions and comparative stability of utility earnings and earnings of other 23, 24 enterprises. Also presented in this exhibit is evidence as to local conditions in the area served by the Utah Company and as to idle investment funds and the factors contributing to such idle money." It noted that the Company was presently engaged in a refinancing program and could be expected to obtain capital at current rates. We have examined Exhibit "M" along with the other *213 matters referred to by the Commission and it appears that there is competent evidence from which the Commission could have concluded that a 6% rate of return would be fair and reasonable. In view of the pending refinancing program the past financial history of the company was not so important as current financial and economic conditions. There is no evidence which would require a holding that a 6% rate of return is not adequate. It therefore cannot be said that the Commission was arbitrary in fixing 6% as the fair rate of return. Further it is to be assumed that if future developments show that the Company has not been able to sell its bonds at anticipated low rates, it can apply to the Commission for any necessary relief.
"In the computation of the surtax a generous concession was made, to public utilities only, by allowing a credit for dividends paid on preferred stock." *214
It then concluded that
"In the instant case * * * the credits and exemptions to this Company under the Revenue Act of 1942 are liberal enough to exempt it from the payment of excess profits taxes under reasonable rates and earnings.
"The credit for preferred stock dividends allowed public utility corporations also exempts the Company from the payment of the surtax. Thus we need make allowance only for the 24% normal tax."
The Company in support of its contention that the Commission was arbitrary in its allowances for federal taxes notes that "The 1942 Revenue Act imposes a normal income tax of 24%, a surtax of 16% and an excess profits [tax] of 90%. It is undisputed that the base for the calculation of both the normal taxes and surtaxes, is the same." The Company then notes:
"But the Commission orders that the Company may not include surtaxes upon income in its operating expenses. Let us illustrate the effect of this. The Company might earn and have on hand $1,000,000 available for the payment of preferred dividends. Under the Revenue Act of 1942 the 16% Federal surtax upon that amount of earnings would be forgiven to the extent that the million dollars were paid out to preferred stockholders. But if the Company should decide that it could not afford to pay the dividends but needed the money to provide work for returning soldiers, it would be required to pay the surtax amounting to $160,000. Under all the cases upon the subject the Company would be entitled to charge the amount of such taxes to its operating expenses. But the Commission, upon the erroneous and bold assumption that the Company may and will pay all dividends accruing upon its preferred stock, has ruled that no deduction on account of surtax may be made as an operating expense. This is not only unreasonable, arbitrary and capricious, but is an attempt to substitute its judgment for that of the Company's Board of Directors in determining whether earnings should be paid to stockholders or employed for Company purposes."
Clearly the Commission had no authority to determine when the Company should pay dividends to its preferred *215
stockholders. If in the sound business discretion of the directors of the Company it were determined that dividends should not be paid for any particular year, 26 it would be no concern of the Commission. If the directors of the Company elect in the future for sound business reasons to withhold payment of dividends on preferred stock and as a consequence a Federal tax (surtax) of 16% is imposed, it would appear that the Company should be permitted to include the surtax so paid in its operating expenses. See GalvestonElectric v. Galveston,
Under the above authorities it appears that the Company would be entitled to an allowance for all surtax payments actually made. But there is no basis for an allowance for surtax payments unless the Company in fact is required to make such payments. The Company argues for a position which would grant it an allowance sufficiently large to pay a 16% surtax without regard to whether any payments are actually made. Then if the Company were to elect to pay dividends so that the surtax would be excused, the allowance would in effect be a gratuitous award to the Company. The dividend history of the Company set out in Exhibit "R" shows that the Company paid a full dividend in 1941 and that, except in 1933, it has paid some dividends every year since 1913. In view of this history there is no justification for an assumption that no dividends will be paid in the future. The indication is that at least some of the surtax will be forgiven every year because of the payment of some dividends. The making of any allowance for taxes which may or may not be paid depending upon whether the Company pays dividends is at best highly speculative. Perhaps the allowance of any amount under such circumstances should await the actual happening of the event — the payment of the tax. But we need not decide that point now for it appears that the Commission made a sufficient allowance for taxes to cover any surtax which *216 the Company might be required to pay. This being so, the Company cannot claim that it has been prejudiced by the Commission's ruling that it need "only make an allowance for the 24% normal tax."
On page 7 of Exhibit "T" various figures taken from the Company's income tax work sheets are set forth. This exhibit shows a net taxable income in 1941 of $1,868,662. The rate order would cut down the gross revenues of the Company by $1,504,644. Expenses are apparently expected to remain the same. The exhibit indicates that the total reduction in gross revenues (1,504,644) is properly taken from the net taxable income to give net taxable income expected after the rate reduction goes into operation. This would leave a net taxable income of $364,018. A 24% normal tax on this amount would be $87,364. A 16% surtax on this amount would be $58,243. The total normal and surtax would thus be $145,607. The Commission allowed $174,651 for federal taxes. It therefore appears that the Company has not in any event been prejudiced in this regard.
It should be noted here that the net taxable income is not computed in the same manner nor does it contain the same elements as the return allowed to the Company by the Commission. The Commission found that the correct rate base would be $64,249,502 for Utah operations and that the Company would be entitled to earn 6% on this base. Said 6% is to be above all costs of operation, including federal income taxes. This would net the Company $3,854,970 from which the Company could pay its proportion of fixed charges and dividends allocable to Utah. In addition the Company would have earnings from its other properties not used and useful in Utah operations, that is, its properties here and in the other states. This is noted so that it will not be inferred that the Company had only a net income of some $364,018 for purposes of meeting all fixed charges, debt retirement and dividends. This last mentioned figure is the net for tax purposes under the anticipated rate reduction and for that purpose alone. *217
In this regard it might also be noted that the public should not in any event be forced to pay rates based on the amount paid in by stockholders unless the amount paid is represented in properties used and useful in serving the public. It may be that the capital of the preferred stockholders was impaired by payment of some $7,200,000 in common stock dividends over the years from 1925 to 1932 inclusive. So long as the Commission has included in the prudent investment base all of the investments which should have been properly included and has allowed a reasonable rate of return thereon, the fact that the return allowed will not yield a sufficient amount to pay full dividends on the Company's stock is not grounds for complaint. Using 1941 as the pattern year the return allowed here is adequate to pay all fixed charges and to allow substantial payments on that portion of the preferred stock dividends allocable to property used to serve the Utah customers. Future anticipated reductions in fixed charges over those payable in 1941 present a picture not unfavorable to preferred stockholders.
"The amount required to make replacements or to save whole the investment will not be same as the cost of the retired unit shown on the books of the Company, except by accident, because of the change in price levels and the use of different dollars to state the original cost and current construction cost and may not in all cases be the amount required to make replacements."
In short, the Company takes the position that it is entitled to charge as a depreciation expense a sum large enough to replace the property which it from time to time *218 has to retire — enough to keep up the value of the property. The Commission allowed only enough to preserve the amount invested in the retired property.
The Company primarily relies upon the holding of the case ofUnited Railways Electric Co. v. West,
"One of the items of expense to be ascertained and deducted is the amount necessary to restore property worn out or impaired, so as continuously to maintain it is nearly as practicable at the same level of efficiency for the public service. The amount set aside periodically for this purpose is the so-called depreciation allowance. Manifestly, this allowance cannot be limited by the original cost, because, if values have advanced, the allowance is not sufficient to maintain the level of efficiency. The utility `is entitled to see that from earnings the value of the property invested is kept unimpaired, so that, at the end of any given term of years, the original investment remains as it was at the beginning.' [City of] Knoxville v. [Knoxville] Water Co.,
To this holding Justice Brandeis entered a vigorous dissent. In a learned opinion, well documented, he discussed the prevailing theories of depreciation accounting and the economic concepts involved. He advocated the use of cost as a basis for computing annual depreciation and criticized the use of value in the place of cost. This dissent is of particular importance for it has subsequently been cited with approval by the United States Supreme Court and the holding of the majority in this regard has been expressly overruled. See Federal Power Commission v. HopeNatural Gas Co.,
"`When the cost of an asset, less any salvage value, has been recovered, the process of depreciation stops, the consumer has paid for that particular item of service. There are those who maintain that the obligation of the consumer is one rather of replacement — *219 building for building, machine for machine. According to this view depreciation should be based on replacement cost rather than actual cost. The replacement theory substitutes for something certain and definite, the actual cost, a cost of reproduction which is highly speculative and conjectural and requiring frequent revision. It, moreover, seeks to establish for one expense a basis for computation fundamentally different from that used for the other expenses of doing business. * * * As one writer has expressed: "The fact that the plant cannot be replaced at the same cost, but only at much more, has nothing to do with the cost of its product, but only with the cost of future products turned out by the subsequent plant." As the product goes through your factory it should be burdened with expired, not anticipated, costs. Charge depreciation upon actual cost lessany salvage.'"
As already noted the Supreme Court cited Mr. Justice Brandeis' dissent with approval in the Hope Case. At page 606 of 320 U.S., at page 289 of 64 S.Ct., the court stated (omitting footnotes):
"* * * this Court recognized in Lindheimer v. Illinois BellTel. Co., supra, the propriety of basing annual depreciation on cost. By such a procedure the utility is made whole and the integrity of its investment maintained. [Citing the opinion of Mr. Justice Brandeis in footnote.] No more is required. We cannot approve the contrary holding of United Railways v. West,
The authorities upon which the Company relied in support of its position on depreciation allowance have been overruled by this decision in the Hope case. The position by the Company cannot be sustained.
The above discussion covers every major assignment of error urged by the Company in support of its petition to have the order of the Commission set aside. We find no prejudicial error in the proceedings before the Commission nor in its holdings. It follows that the order of the Commission must be and it is hereby affirmed.
LARSON, McDONOUGH, and WADE, JJ., concur.
HOYT, District Judge, sat in place of MOFFAT, J., deceased.
"The so-called rule of Smyth v. Ames is, in my opinion, legally and economically sound. The thing devoted by the investor to the public use is not specific property, tangible and intangible, but capital embarked in the enterprise. Upon the capital so invested the federal Constitution guarantees to the utility the opporunity to earn a fair return.
* * * * *
"The investor agrees, by embarking capital in a utility, that its charges to the public shall be reasonable. His company is substituted for the state in performance of the public service, thus becoming a public servant. The compensation which the Constitution guarantees is an opportunity to earn the reasonable cost of conducting the business. Cost includes not only operating expenses, but also capital charges. Capital charges cover the allowance, by way of interest, for the use of the capital, whatever the nature of the security issued therefor, the allowance for risk incurred, and enough more to attract capital." [
See also West v. Chesapeake Potomac Telephone Co., 1935,
"We held in Federal Power Commission v. Natural Gas PipeLine Co., supra, that the Commission was not bound to the use of any single formula or combination of formulae in determining rates. Its rate-making function, moreover, involves the making of `pragmatic adjustments.' Id., page 586 of 315 U.S., page 743 of 62 S.Ct.,
Concurrence Opinion
I concur in the opinion of the CHIEF JUSTICE. I do not, however, agree with implications which might be drawn from language quoted in the opinion from the case of Federal PowerCommission v. Hope Natural Gas Company, and because I deem the matter vital I shall call attention to it. The language referred to is as follows:
"When the Commission's order is challenged in the courts, the question is whether that order `viewed in its entirety' meets the requirements of the Act. * * * Under the statutory standard of `just and reasonable' it is the result reached not the method employed which is controlling. * * * It is not theory but the impact of the rate order which counts. If the total effect of the rate order cannot be said to be unjust and unreasonable, judicial inquiry under the Act is at an end. The fact that the method employed to reach that result may contain infirmities is not then important."
From that language contained in a decision of the highest court in the land, other courts and public service commissioners may argue that a rate order should be upheld unless it can be shown to be confiscatory, regardless of whether the Commission based it upon relevant facts or upon a throw of dice or instinct or intuition. That is obviously not the law. Rate limitation is a legislative function, it is true, but courts should set aside a rate order unless constitutional procedure has been followed. Due process requires not only notice and opportunity to be heard, but requires that, in making a rate order, the Commission must give consideration to operating costs, maintenance, taxes, capital charges, reserves for depreciation, etc. and must also consider aproper basis upon which to fix the rate or amount of return tothe owners. The Hope case does away with the rule that the owners of a utility are entitled to a reasonable return based upon reproduction cost or so-called present fair value of the properties constituting the utility system. But I think, regardless of the language above quoted, it should not be construed as holding that there is no fundamental basis required to be considered in determining the amount or rate to be allowed the owners. It is shown from *221
the record in the case that the Commission had given consideration to evidence of operating costs, maintenance, taxes, capital charges, reserves for depreciation, the financial history of the company, the general economic conditions, the rates of earnings on investments with similar risks, and the amount invested in the property by the owners; also that the Commission had decided that the proper rate base upon which to fix the amount of profit or percentage of return to the owner was the amount actually and prudently invested in the property, after deduction for accrued depletion and depreciation. The commission then decided that a reasonable return, based upon such rate base, was 6 1/2 per cent per annum. Obviously the rate of return decided upon in the case was not the result of intuition or dice-casting but was fixed upon the logical foundation of the "prudent investment" base advocated by Mr. Justice Brandeis inSouthwestern Bell Telephone Company v. Public ServiceCommission,
There must be some yardstick to be used by the commissions and the courts in determining whether a rate of return or dollar amount of return is or is not confiscatory. The abrogation of the rule of Smyth v. Ames must not be taken to mean that there is no need to establish a rate base. There must be a rate base upon which the rate of profit is to be calculated. Both public service commissions and the courts must concern themselves with the property affected by a rate-fixing proceeding. Upon the property devoted to the public use the owner is entitled, under the Constitution, to the opportunity to earn a fair return, except that rates may, in no event, be prohibitive, exorbitant, or unduly burdensome to the public. But the property or thing devoted by the investor to the public use is not specific items of property but capital embarked in the utility enterprise. That is the Brandeis doctrine, as I understand it. In the Hope case the Commission followed that doctrine and the Supreme Court affirmed it. That should be remembered in connection with the language from the opinion above quoted. *222