188 F. 102 | U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Utah | 1911
Lead Opinion
(after stating the facts as above).
The question then is: Was the line of the Union Pacific Company, extending only from Omaha and Kansas City on the east to Ogden on the west a competing line prior to 1901 for transcontinental business with the Southern Pacific Company, whose line extended from New York on the east over the sea to New Orleans, and thence by rail to San Francisco and Portland on the west? The question is not. whether it constituted a continuous line over which traffic might possibly be moved from the Atlantic seaboard or interior to the Pacific Coast, but whether it constituted a feasible route over which it could enter naturally and profitably into competition with the Southern Pacific route for that traffic.
Claim is not made that it was such a competitor for any business originating on or near to its main line, but only for business originating in New York or Pittsburg- common points, 1,000 or more miles away from its line. Its traffic between New York and interior points, on the one hand, and Portland, Or., on the other, was of trifling importance, amounting for the fiscal year preceding the purchase of the Pluntington stock to only 0.46 per cent, of its total tonnage. -Accordingly its competitive relation to the Southern Pacific route with respect to traffic in and out of San Francisco, the chief gateway for transcontinental business, will first be considered.
It had a connection at Granger with its subsidiary lines, the Oregon Short Fine and the Oregon Railroad & Navigation Fine, extending to Portland, and there with a line of steamboats irregularly and infrequently running between that port and San Francisco. 'But, this detour through Portland and over the sea was long, unreliable, and unsatisfactory, and afforded no opportunity for fair and remunerative competition with the Southern Pacific for San Francisco trade. It was about 1,700 miles in length, as against 800 miles in direct line from Ogden to San Francisco. In fact, prior to 1901 it had never been employed in any substantial way as an outlet for the Union Pacific’s west-bound freight into San Francisco. It is inconceivable, therefore, that the Huntington stock was purchased to prevent, or had the
We shall accordingly dismiss it from further consideration so far as transcontinental business is concerned, and pass to the important question upon which argument was concentrated: Whether the right, privilege, or practice, whatever it may have been, of connecting with the rails of the Southern Pacific at Ogden and of using that company’s line between Ogden and San Francisco, together with the right, privilege, or practice of connecting at Omaha and Kansas City with the lines of other railroads, which by themselves and by successive connections led to the points of origin of the traffic, constituted the Union Pacific a competitor of the Southern Pacific for that traffic. It is certain the Union Pacific by itself could do none of that business. It extended neither to its origin nor destination. It depended For success upon its connections with other railroads at the east and'with its alleged competitor at the west end of its own line.
“It is conceded that tlie different railroads forming a continuous line of road are freo io adopt or refuse to adopt joint through tariff rates. The commerce act recognizes such right, and provides for the filing with the commission of the through tariff rates, as agreed upon between the companies. The whole question of joint through tariff rates, under the provisions of the act, is one of agreement between the companies, and they may, or may not, enter into it, as they may think their interests demand. And it is equally plain that an initial carrier may agree upon joint through rates with one or several connecting carriers, who between each other might be regarded as competing roads. It is also undoubted that the common carrier need not contract to carry beyond its own line, hut may there deliver to the next succeeding carrier, and thus end .its responsibility, and charge iis local rate for the transportation. If it agree to transport beyond its own line, it may do so by such lines as it chooses.”
Whether, therefore, the great Eastern lines and their connections, which gathered up the west-bound freight, should favor the Union Pacific, the Southern Pacific, or the Santa Eé routes, as their final connection into San Francisco, was optional with them. If they favored the Union Pacific, the terms of their arrangement, whether for a reasonable participation by each in the through rates, or on the basis of local rates for the service of each, or otherwise, were not within the power of the Union Pacific itself to determine, or of the courts, in the absence of legislative authority, to enforce. If, perchance, the Union Pacific had for a time a voluntary arrangement with the Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul, the Michigan Central, and the New York Central for a through route and joint rates on traffic destined from New York common points to Ogden and thence to San Francisco, can it he true that that fact by itself would have constituted the Michigan Central a competitor of the Southern Pacific for
But, it is argued, it could retaliate by using its influence to induce initial carriers or shippers to route transcontinental freight by way of Portland and the sea to San Francisco. This being such a long and unreliable route, little success could have been reasonably expected in such retaliation. If the Rio Grande should have been favored by the Southern Pacific as its Eastern connection, the Union Pacific, in the language of the witnesses, would have been practically bottled up at Ogden. With the advantage possessed by the Southern Pacific as an initial carrier to deflect all east-bound traffic to another line at Ogden, and with the right to exact on all east or west_ bound traffic local rates, instead of a fair and just proportion of an established through rate, the Southern Pacific would easily have put a quick and decisive ending to any hostile rivalry or competition, if such had been hazarded by the < Union Pacific. This absolute dependence by the latter upon the Southern Pacific for a distance of 800 miles of its only through route, to say nothing of its dependence upon the voluntary action of its Eastern connections already pointed out, in our opinion, rendered any equal or profitable competition between them impossible. No real rivalry in the nature of things could have subsisted as long as the success of one was dependent upon the consent or favor of the other. Instead of the situation being competitive, the two roads really acted together and co-operated between themselves and with their connections in securing as much of the transcontinental traffic, each for the other, according to their respective facilities, as they could get, and participated in the total revenue on a basis of comparative service rendered. Their relations were like those of a limited partnership, rather than those of hostile competitorship.
The act of 1862 not only provided for the continuous operation of the roads, but empowered them to consolidate (section 16); and so likewise did the act of 1864 (section 16). These acts were obviously intended to secure a permanent physical connection between the roads and to provide generally for equal accommodations to the public on the basis of independent carriers; but we discover in them no provisions or machinery by which the Southern Pacific, as successor to one of them, could have been compelled by the courts or otherwise to make agreements governing interchange of traffic or through rates, or fixing the division of such through rates between the two roads. Section 15 of the act of 1864 is not substantially different, so far as the matter under consideration is concerned, from section 3 of the interstate commerce act of 1887 (24 Stat. 380). They both forbid discrimination in rates between connecting lines. Section 3 has been held by the Interstate Commerce Commission and by the Court of Appeals of this circuit not to invest the commission or the courts with power to compel carriers to make contracts or agreements for through billing of freight or for joint rates. On the contrary, it was held that such matters are left to the voluntary determination of the interested carriers. L. R. & Mem. R. R. Co. v. E. Tenn., etc., Co., 3 Interst. Com. R. 1; Little Rock & M. R. Co. v. St. Louis & S. W. Ry. Co., 63 Fed. 775, 11 C. C. A. 417. See, also, to the same effect, Oregon Short Line. etc., v. Northern Pacific R. Co. (C. C.) 51 Fed. 465, 474, and Chicago & N. W. Ry. Co. v. Osborne, 52 Fed. 912, 914, 3 C. C. A. 347.
The voluminous evidence of officers, ag'ents, and shippers to the effect that active competition existed between the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific roads prior to 1901 must be considered in the light of the legal and physical relations of the roads to each other and of other related facts. Whether there "was competition or not, in view of all these things, is a mixed question of law and fact, and not susceptible of determination by the preponderance of proof as an issue of fact only. Without doubt there was active competition, but
The immediate and actuating intent and purpose of the Union Pacific Company in acquiring the Huntington stock, and thereby the control of the operations of the Southern Pacific line, were, according to the proof, to secure a permanent working and reliable connection at Ogden over an existing road for its through traffic; a connection not dependent upon the grace of a dominant copartner, but one within its own control. We recognize the proposition that, if the necessary and direct result of the purchase of the Huntington stock was to destroy or substantially suppress free and natural competition, before then existing between the two companies, or if that purchase put it within the power of the Union Pacific Company to destroy, or suppress such competition, the latter-named company would undoubtedly be held to have intended the natural and reasonable consequences of its act, and, notwithstanding the dominant purpose just mentioned, would have violated' the anti-trust law. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v. United States, 175 U. S. 211, 234, 20 Sup. Ct. 96, 44 L. Ed. 136; Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U. S. 197, 328, 332, 357, 24 Sup. Ct. 436, 48 L. Ed. 679.
Our conclusion is that all the facts of this case, considered in their natural, reasonable, and practical aspect, and given their appropriate relative signification, do not make the Union Pacific a substantial competitor for transcontinental business with the Southern Pacific in or prior to the year 1901. We therefore pass to a consideration of some less important matters relied upon by the government to establish destruction of competition between those companies.
It is contended that it was destroyed or suppressed in transcon•tinental business between the Atlantic seaboard and Middle states, ■ on the one hand, and Portland and Willamette Valley common points, on the other hand. The route of the Southern Pacific for this business was by its own line via New Orleans and San Francisco to Portland, and that of the Union Pacific was by its own line from Omaha and Kansas City to Ogden, together with its connections and subconnections eastward from Omaha and Kansas City, and Its subsidiary lines, the Oregon Short Line and Oregon Railroad & Navigation Company running northwestwardly into Portland and the Valley. The geographical relation of these routes to each other, and the dependence of one of them, at least, upon voluntary arrangements with other lines, would seem to render natural and fair competition between them for the Portland trade impossible; but the
Again, it is contended that the control of the Southern Pacific Company acquired by the Union Pacific Company suppressed free competition between them for business between the Atlantic seaboard and Colorado and Utah common points. The route of the Southern Pacific available for this traffic was from New York to New Orleans or Galveston by sea; thence over its0 own line to Ft. Worth, Tex. ; thence over its connection, the Colorado & Southern, to Denver; thence over another connection, the Denver & Rio Grande, into Utah.
The route of the Union Pacific Company available for it was its own line from Kansas City and Omaha to Denver and Ogden, with its numerous initial connections and subconnections, and also a line by sea from New York to Newport News and Savannah; thence by connections at those places with such railroads as would favor them through the interior of the country to the beginning of its own rails at Kansas City or Omaha.
Physically and practically speaking, in view of the circuity of the route of the Southern Pacific and of the necessary dependence of both companies upon volunteer connections, real rivalry between them for this traffic does not seem to have been possible; but here again the traffic itself was of little volume and comparatively unimportant. For the year ending January 30, 1900, the tonnage of the Southern Pacific in this business was only 0.19 per cent, of its total tonnage. For the same year the tonnage of the Union Pacific in this traffic was only 0.47 per cent, of its total tonnage.
A like contention is made concerning the traffic between San Francisco, on the one hand, and Portland and points in the Willamette Valley, on the other hand; but this traffic was also small. For the year ending June 30, 1901, the tonnage of the Southern Pacific in this traffic was only 0.36 per cent, of its total tonnage, and the tonnage of the Union Pacific Company in it for the same period was only 1.27 per cent, of its total tonnage.
A similar contention is made concerning the traffic from Portland and Willamette Valley common points, on the one hand, and Ogden and its common points, on the other. The route of the Southern Pacific Company for this business was by the so-called Shasta route from Portland to Sacramento, and thence via the old Central Pacific route to Ogden. This was a long and circuitous route, compared to that of the Union Pacific Company from Portland via Oregon Railroad & Navigation Company and Oregon Short Fine to Ogden. Not only is this so, but the business was trifling. P'or the year ending June 30. 1901, the tonnage of tile Southern Pacific in it was only 0.01 per cent, of its total tonnage, while that of the Union Pacific was only 0.35 per cent, of its total tonnage.
A like contention is made concerning traffic from San Francisco, on the one hand, and points in Montana, Idaho, Eastern Oregon, and
Claim is also made that the control which the Union Pacific Company acquired by the purchase of the Huntington stock suppressed free competition between them for the Oriental traffic. Many considerations arising out of the relations of the two roads to the transpacific steamship lines which carried the traffic from the coast have conduced to the conclusion reached; but bearing in mind that we are not considering this case in view of the present Oriental traffic, but in view of what it was 10 years ago, when the transaction complained of occurred, we find adequate reason for it in the small amount of this business also. For the year ending January 30, 1901, the tonnage of the Southern Pacific in handling it was only 0.20 per cent, of its total tonnage, while that of the Union Pacific both through San Francisco and Portland gateways was only 0.41 per cent, of its total tonnage.
The aggregate of all the business done by the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific Companies over all these routes for the years specified, which we believe fairly represent the general conditions prevailing at or before the Huntington stock was purchased, was for the Southern Pacific Company 0.88 per cent, of the entire tonnage of that system, and for the Union Pacific Company 3.10 per cent, of its aggregate tonnage. Tables in evidence also disclose that the total revenue derived from the traffic over these minor routes by the Southern Pacific .Company for the year preceding the year of the Huntington purchase amounted to only 1.25 per cent, of the total revenue of that system.
Certainly the desire to appropriate the trifling business done by the Southern Pacific Company on these minor lines, or' to suppress a competition in traffic which was in the aggregate of such small proportions, could not have been the inspiration of the vast outlay involved in the purchase of the Huntington stock. Neither was the suppression of competition in this infinitesimally small proportion of the business of both companies a substantial or natural consequence of that important transaction. It did not amount to a direct and substantial restraint of either interstate or international commerce. It was at best only contingently, incidentally, and infinitesimally affected by it. This is not sufficient to bring it within the condemnation of the anti-trust law. United States v. Joint Traffic Association, 171 U. S. 505, 19 Sup. Ct. 25, 43 L. Ed. 259; Anderson v. United States, 171 U. S. 604, 19 Sup. Ct. 50, 43 L. Ed. 300; Field v. Barber Asphalt Co., 194 U. S. 618, 24 Sup. Ct. 784, 48 L. Ed. 1142; Northern Securities Co. v. United States, supra; Cincinnati Packet Co. v. Bay, 200 U. S. 179, 26 Sup. Ct. 208, 50 L. Ed. 428; Phillips v. Iola Portland Cement Co., 61 C. C. A. 19, 12. Fed. 593; Arkansas Brokerage Co. v. Dunn & Powell, 97 C. C. A. 454, 173 Fed. 899; United
It is however, contended that in the adjustment of differences between the Union Pacific and its allied or subsidiary companies with the Clark interests, resulting in the construction of one line between Salt Lake City and Los Angeles, instead of two, as projected, there was a suppression of competition which would have existed between the two, if they had built separately. We, however, are unable to discover anything in the transaction except a laudable purpose to adjust differences and construct a line _ of railroad between the two points which would serve their joint interests as well as those of the public. The evidence discloses that it was not feasible to construct two lines of road over the only practicable route throu'gh the canyon in the mountains, known as “Meadow Valley Wash.” This, with other reasons of a practical nature, fully justified the abandonment of the project of constructing two lines and the consolidation of them into one.
Some minor agreements fixing the relations between the new San Pedro line and the other lines composing the system of the Union Pacific, as well as the. provisions for fixing through and local rates, were made; but these are so incidental to the main transaction, already found not to have violated the interstate commerce act, as to warrant no further consideration. If it be true, as already pointed out, that the San Pedro line was not naturally competitive with the Union Pacific or. Southern Pacific lines, none of these incidental things would disturb legitimate competition within the purview of the antitrust law.
The evidence discloses certain transactions between the Southern Pacific Company, on the one hand, and the Phoenix & Eastern and the California & Northwestern Railroad Companies, on the other hand, which are claimed to have been in restraint of competition' between them; but as they affect local transportation only, and are not complained of in the bill as substantive wrongs, and as neither of the two last-mentioned companies are made parties to this action, it is not perceived how any independent relief with respect to them' can be granted. We therefore refrain from considering them, except in so far as they afford relevant evidence on issues joined in the case.
The large number of initial carriers striving for that traffic have continued their active solicitation for business over the line which assured them the longest haul or otherwise benefited them most, and although some agents of the two roads, which before 1901 were separate, are now joint, they have continued to exercise their influence to secure business for either road according to its availability, and always in opposition to other active competitors, like the Santa fie and Denver & Rio Grande roads. A substantial majority of the stock of the Southern Pacific Company has been held by parties other than the Union Pacific Company; but we fail to find any complaint by such holders of any discrimination against their road or of any failure to properly promote its welfare. None of the minor points charged to have been deprived of competitive opportunities by the Huntington purchase are shown to have suffered as a result of that purchase. On the contrary, hundreds of millions of dollars have since 1901 been expended on these roads. Their physical condition has been vastly improved, and their efficiency for public service as well as for private profit has been greatly enhanced. The whole proof, taken together, we think, fails to disclose any conspiracy to restrain interstate or foreign commerce, in violation of the first section of the act.
The same considerations lead to the conclusion that no combination or conspiracy to monopolize or attempt to monopolize trade or commerce among the states or with foreign nations was entered into. Moreover, the fact that the Union Pacific Company did not secure or undertake to secure the control of the Santa Fé road, a thoroughly sufficient, well-equipped, and powerful rival for transcontinental business, or the Denver & Rio Grande road, a potential, and later an actual, powerful rival for the same business, affords additional and conclusive evidence of no such combination or conspiracy. The purchase by the Union Pacific Company, soon after acquiring the Huntington stock, of a majority of the capital stock of the Northern Pacific Company, tends to the opposite conclusion; hut, in view of the main reason for its acquisition and its disposition by the Unión Pacific Company, we are indisposed to give to that purchase alone any considerable significance.
The conclusions of fact already stated dispose of this case without the necessity of determining the question, much debated in brief and argument, whether securing control of the Southern Pacific Company by purchasing stock of individual owners could in any view of the case have contravened the anti-trust law. On the facts of this case, with all their reasonable and fair inferences, we conclude that the government has failed to substantiate the averments of its bill.
The bill must be dismissed, and a decree will be entered to that effect.
SANBORN, Circuit Judge, concurs.
Dissenting Opinion
(dissenting). Briefly stated, the decision of the court, in which I am unable to concur, is that the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific Railroads, universally regarded as parallel in a broad geographical and legal sense, for about 2,000 miles, were not competitors in 1901 for transcontinental or other traffic, and therefore their merger in that year was not contrary to the Sherman antitrust act. I agree with the court upon the minor features of the case, including, in a general way, that of the control of the San Pedro line by the Union Pacific Company. The latter is much as if a railroad company, with a line from the west through Omaha or Kansas City to Chicago, should obtain control of a branch from Omaha or Kansas City to St. Louis. In the absence of a more direct competitive relation than appears here, the Sherman act should not be held to cover such tangential acquisitions.
But the chief complaint of the government is of an unlawful contract or combination in restraint of trade and commerce, by which the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific transportation systems are held under a single control, and competition between them is suppressed or -destroyed. The combination was effected through the purchase by the Union Pacific of part of the capital stock of the Southern Pacific. Upon this two important questions arise. The first, which is one of law, is whether the purchase by one railroad company of corporate stock of another, less than the majority, but sufficient in amount according to the practical experience of men to enable the purchaser to dominate or control the policies and operations of the other, is a form of combination within the prohibitions of the Sherman act. The conclusion of the court being against the government on another ground, it was unnecessary to determine this question; but as I do not assent to the conclusion, and as the question lies at the threshold of the government’s case, I should briefly express my view concerning it.
There is no substantial difference between the holding of the corporate stocks of two companies by a third, such as was condemned in the Northern Securities Case, 193 U. S. 197, 24 Sup. Ct. 436, 48 L. Ed. 679, and the holding by one of those two of the stock of the other. The form is somewhat different, but the effect, which is the chief concern of the law, is the same. If prior competition disappears as a direct and natural result, trade and commerce are restrained. If it is unlawful in the one case, it must be so in the other. It would be idle to hold that, while two competing railroad companies cannot lawfully submit to a common control through a separate stock-holding organization, they may do so by dispensing with that medium. That would be regarding shadows and letting the substance go. The
I grant it is a serious thing to disturb a great business transaction like that shown in the case at bar; but, given the power of Congress to legislate, and clear words to express what a judge conceives to have been its purpose, his duty is plain, whatever he may think of the wisdom of the law. Even if public regulation is believed to be a wiser solution of the important economic problem than enforced competition, with its necessary wastes and burdens, nevertheless his judgment of a law embodying the latter policy should proceed as with distinct approval of its selection. It is quite clear that, with the growth and development of governmental regulation of common carriers engaged in interstate commerce, there is decreasing reason for holding them subject to the Sherman act, and it may be that as regards rates of transportation the Interstate Commerce Commission could perform its duties with equal justice to the public and greater justice to the railroads if they were released. . But certainly that is for Congress, not the courts. The judicial function is properly exercised when the Sherman act is construed and applied as though it were the only legislative remedy on the statute books.
The other question in the case is decided by the court against the government. It is whether the two great transportation systems, the Union Pacific and the Southern Pacific, were in a substantial sense competitors in interstate and foreign commerce. This question involves the relative location of their lines on land and sea, and not only the parts they actually performed, but also those they were naturally capable of performing, in the movement of traffic. Albeit in part within the domain of judicial knowledge, this seems to me to be a pure question of fact. Some hundreds of witnesses, practical railroad men and shippers of wide experience, testified upon it, and a great mass of evidence was taken, showing almost without dispute that, using the term “competition” as business men understand and use it, there was active, vigorous, and substantial competition between the Union Pacific and the Southern Pacific before the former obtained control of the latter. But the court holds the question of competition to be one of mixed law and fact, not determinable by the evidence alone, and as such it is answered against the government.
Roughly stated, the situation was this: In 1901, when the stock purchase was made, the Union Pacific had lines of railroad from the Missouri river, at Council Bluffs, Iowa, and Kansas City, Mo., to Cheyenne, Wyo.; thence a line through Ogden, Utah, to Portland, Or., lines of steamers from Portland to San Francisco, Cal., and from San P'rancisco and Portland to Oriental ports; also certain rights under an act of Congress (13 Stat. 356) with respect to the Central Pacific Railroad, which was controlled by the Southern Pacific, from
Reduced to the simplest terms the conclusion of the court that the two companies were not competitors and the Sherman act was not violated is based on these two grounds: (1) Trade and commerce were not restrained, because before the combination the competitive interstate and foreign traffic of the two railroad companies was not a substantial percentage of their total traffic, including in such total the traffic entirely within the several states, over which Congress had no control. (2) Trade and commerce were not restrained because before the combination one of the lines of railroad, the Union Pacific, was 'an intermediate one in a through route, and depended for competitive traffic upon the business interests of connecting carriers, and therefore could not by itself alone, unaided by the concurrence of its natural allies, make a joint through rate over the entire route. In other words, each party to a contract or combination between railroad companies, which the government assails as being contrary to the Sherman act, must have owned or controlled an entire through route over which competitive traffic moved. That it may have performed an essential part, or have been a necessary factor, in the transportation, is insufficient. That connecting carriers may have voluntarily joined it in making through rates for the traffic is immaterial.
With the greatest deference to my Brothers, I am so profoundly impressed with the conviction that these conditions are without substantial relevance to the question before us that I am constrained to dissent from the opinion of the court. Moreover, their introduction so greatly narrows the act of Congress, which, however it may be
The traffic for which the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific competed in 1901, and which one or the other secured, was of enormous volume when considered by itself. It ran into millions of dollars, and with the natural development of the country and the growth of commerce, reasonably to have been foreseen, it has since then greatly increased. The competition was direct, not incidental, and the business for which they strove was appreciable or substantial, not insignificant. But tables of figures are given by defendants from which it appears that the interstate and foreign traffic between competitive points secured by each was hut a small percentage of the tonnage of its entire system, and it is therefore argued that the competition to which the act of Congress applies was relatively so small there could have been no restraint or suppression in a substantial sense, and hence no intent to restrain or suppress it. The comparisons being with the total tonnage of the railroads, obviously an element is included which is wholly beyond the power of Congress, namely, the traffic local to the states. The logical conclusion from this view must be that the Sherman act is not violated whenever the trade or commerce within its operation, affected by' the contract or combination, however great in
In a'broad and substantial sense, in the sense in which the terms are used in constitutions and statutes and .in railroad and business circles, the Union Pacific and Southern Pacific lines were parallel and competing. That they were so regarded by practical men having to do with transportation in its various phases is shown,'I think, by an overwhelming mass of evidence. But, had no witness testified regarding- it, we should come to the same conclusion. There are occasions when courts in the exercise of their judicial functions are entitled to look out into the world of affairs to observe whether there is not a common knowledge of the subject before them, so universal and pervading as not to admit of testimonial controversy. That is termed “judicial notice,” and it proceeds upon the assumption that a judge should not be blind to what all others see and understand. It embraces the great currents of trade and commerce in his country — the general movements of products and manufactures — as completely as it does the important features of its physical geography, the location of the cities, the ports, the navigable waters, and the lines of railroad.
The question whether a combination of two transportation lines is contrary to the Sherman act-is not always to be reduced to a .close consideration of the number of tons of competitive freight they car7 ried within a given period, much less the precise relation of the competitive tonnage to their total business of all kinds. ' Were they, at the time of the combination, in a substantial degree competitive factors in interstate and foreign commerce? Were they so laid upon land and sea as inherently to possess a substantial competitive capacity for the movement of such traffic? It is not merely the extent to which that capacity was utilized yesterday, but the extent to which the transportation facilities were naturally capable of being utilized; and reasonable, not speculative, regard should be had for the developments of to-morrow. Were it otherwise, Congress in the making of laws would be denied that ordinary foresight which men engaged in business commonly possess and practice. Competition, as the antithesis of monopoly, is the influence which those in the same line of business have on each other, and that influence may as well be manifested in
When the argument was made at the hearing that, because the Union Pacific was an intermediate, not a through line, it was not a competitor for traffic moving over it and its connections for which it could not have made a joint through rate, counsel admitted that the rule contended for would have made it lawful under the Sherman act for all intermediate lines in transcontinental transportation, such as the Chicago, Rock Island & Pacific from Chicago to El Paso, the Atchison, Topeka & Santa Eé from Chicago to Mojave (before it gained entrance to San Francisco), the Missouri, Kansas & Texas from St. Louis and Kansas City to Texas points, the St. Louis & San Francisco from St. Louis and Kansas City to the Southwest, the Missouri Pacific with the Denver & Rio Grande from St. Louis to Ogden, and the Union Pacific to have combined and agreed among themselves, as was done in the Trans-Missouri Freight Association Case, 166 U. S. 290, 17 Sup. Ct. 540, 41 L. Ed. 1007, if they confined their combination to transcontinental traffic; in other -words that those intermediate railroads could not be competitors for the traffic, and a confederation with respect thereto could not be unlawful. It seems to me that a statement of the contention shows its unsoundness. Anything that affects the rate over a substantial part of a transportation route is calculated to affect the charge as an entirety; and so of the other features of railroad competition. The competition of the all-water route by the Atlantic -and Pacific Oceans with the all-rail transcontinental routes in the United States is so fully recognized that it is safe to say almost every car load rate to the Pacific coast from the territory between the Missouri river and the Atlantic seaboard exhibits a recognition of its influence. And yet it is contended that the
The practical aspect of the question is shown by the cases in which railroad companies have asserted the existence of competition from rival lines or routes of transportation as evidencing conditions justifying discriminations and preferences under the interstate commerce act —that the rates objected to as discriminative were controlled by competition, and if they abandoned the rates they would lose the business. An instance of this appears in Texas & Pacific Railway v. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U. S. 197, 16 Sup. Ct. 666, 40 L. Ed. 940. The Texas & Pacific Railroad from New Orleans to El Paso, Tex., and the Southern Pacific Railroad thence to San Francisco, formed a through route over which traffic, both foreign and domestic,, moved. The Texas & Pacific Company successfully defended its right to charge and receive more for its proportion of the through rate on traffic originating in New Orleans than it charged and received on import traffic originating in London and Liverpool and billed through New Orleans over the same route to San Francisco, and it did so on the ground asserted that the rate from .the English cities to San Francisco was determined by competition with the following routes: By vessel around the Horn; by vessel and by rail across the Isthmus of Panama; and (162 U. S. 216, 16 Sup. Ct. 674, 40 L. Ed. 946) by vessel and by rail across Canada. Were all those transportation agencies subject to the laws of the United States, could it with reason be urged that a contract or combination between them, suppressing a competition which actually existed, would not contravene the Sherman act, because all but one of them were composed of connecting links severally owned or controlled? If that which men engaged in transportation recognize as substantial competition in shaping their policies and their conduct is not so regarded in the courts, the statute will not have the operation intended by its enactment. Laws are generally framed to apply to the everyday affairs of men, who are not given to the study of nice differences and distinctions, and that should always be borne in mind in determining their meaning.
But it is said there was no competition, because the Union Pacific depended upon the Southern Pacific line from Ogden to San Francisco. It is true that much of the transcontinental traffic of the Union Pacific went that way; but it is not unusual for railroad systems to connect at points and interchange business, though they are active competitors in other respects. In fact, a large proportion of them are so related. Competition, within the laws which seek to preserve it, does not imply absolute nonintercourse, as between hostile armies, which exchange no prisoners and give no quarter. Moreover, the use of the Ogden line was neither a necessity to the Union Pacific nor a pure favor or concession by the Southern Pacific. Aside from the mutual benefits from the interchange of traffic, the former had its own line from Ogden, by way of Portland, which, though not as desirable, was more than an important strategic advantage necessary to be reckoned with. But were all this otherwise, the undeniable fact remains,
I think that upon the main feature of the case the government is entitled to a decree.