191 F. 172 | U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Maryland | 1911
Lead Opinion
The United States brings this suit. It will be called the government. Its petition is filed under the fourth section of the Sherman anti-trust act. It charges that the defendants have violated the first and second sections of that act. It says that they have conspired to restrain interstate trade in sanitary enameled iron ware, and have attempted to monopolize such trade therein. All the defendants are concerned in making and selling that ware. It is made of cast iron. It is coated with enamel. It has the appearance of being porcelain lined. Bathtubs, lavatories, closet bowls, and tanks, sinks, and urinals are among the. more important articles made of it. It will be referred to as the ware.
There are 50 defendants. Sixteen are corporations. They will be called the corporate defendants. Thirty-four are individuals. They are styled individual defendants. One of them is Edwin L. Wayman. With him each of the corporate defendants made an agreement. ‘These agreements the government says restrain trade in the ware, and attempt to monopolize it. The other 33 individual defendants are officers of the corporate defendants. The government charges that they each were among the persons who knowingly caused the corporate defendants to do that of which it complains.
These 16 agreements were, with exceptions to be mentioned, identical in their language. At least 15 of the 16 corporate defendants had directly or indirectly taken part in drafting the common form. They were executed by nearly all the corporate defendants on the same day and at the same place. No defendant entered into the' agreement without knowing that at least 13 of the other corporate defendants had executed it, or intended so to do. Without this knowledge no one of them would have become a party to it. Each of these agreements is in the form of a license granted by Wayman accepted by a corporate defendant. The patents under which the licenses purported to be granted were first put into Wayman’s name two days before most of the agreements were executed. The terms of the agreements had been definitely settled at least two weeks earlier. There were three patents. They all were for automatic dredgers. A dredger is a tool used in the enameling step of making the ware. The licenses were granted for a period of two years, beginning June 1, 1910. Each licensee promised on the 5th day of each month to pay $5 a day for each furnace used by it for the making of the ware during the preceding month. Wayman undertook that he would three months later pay back $4 out of every $5. This undertaking was conditioned upon the licensee having in the meantime done all he had agreed to do. There are about 25 working days a month. Wayman
The principles upon which these resale prices were to be worked out in detail had been agreed upon between Wayman and a committee chosen by nearly all of the corporate defendants. This agreement was reached before any licenses were accepted, and before any of the patents had become Wayman’s. The licenses provided that no changes in the sale or resale prices could be made without the consent of Way-man and the majority of a committee elected by the corporate defendants. The agreements restricted in a number of ways the freedom of both the corporate defendants who made the ware and the jobbers
' On the other hand, there was from the jobbers’ standpoint much that was attractive in the scheme as a whole. Competition had been fierce. It had not always been either wise or honest. A badly made article may look well enough to deceive the average householder. Many such had been put on the. market. When the defects were speedily discovered, the jobber might have to take back the article. The cost of doing so ate up the profit on a number of like articles which were not returned. There was little profit in handling the ware. If every dealer signed the agreement, none of them could gain by taking from the makers and putting off on the public any ware ' except bathtubs, riot standard of it's kind. The lowest price the male
Of 250 furnaces in the country the defendants owned 195, or 78 per cent. In drawing building specifications architects frequently called for ware made by a particular manufacturer. A jobber who could not furnish a plumber with what he wanted for a large job was likely to lose his custom altogether. May, 1910, must have been a trying time for jobbers with a stubborn liking for independence, and a taste for managing their own business in their own way. As already stated, in the end four out of every five of the jobbers signed up. Many of them did so willingly and even enthusiastically. It is probable that the large majority of them welcomed the chance of doing so. Their associations had been urging the manufacturers to put in force a resale arrangement. A number of them have testified that they wanted it. While it lasted, they say they found it pleasant and profitable. In consequence of these proceedings and of other action taken by the government, the corporate defendants on January 1, 1911, suspended so much of the agreements as fixed original and resale prices. Many of the jobbers regret the suspension.
With whatever of enthusiasm, with whatever of reluctance, the makers of nearly four-fifths of the ware and more than four out of every five dealers in it became parties to the combination. The corporate defendants, and many, if not most, of the jobbers, were engaged in interstate commerce in the ware. Such commerce was directly restrained by the agreements. The makers who became parties to them could no longer sell the jobbers who did not. The jobbers who did could no longer buy from the makers who did not. The defendants did their best to get all the makers of importance and all the dealers to become parties to the scheme. If they had succeeded, Wayman and a committee of the corporate defendants would for two years from June 1, 1910, have been able to say that no man anywhere in the United States should buy a bathtub or any other article of the ware at a lower price than it might have suited them to fix. If the trade would then have been monopolized, the defendants attempted to monopolize it.
The important questions in the case are two: (1) Would such a combination as was attempted, and in large part brought about, have violated the Sherman act, had patents on automatic dredgers played
The defendants argue that not every agreement to fix and maintain prices in interstate commerce violate the Sherman act. They say that •eyes illumined by the light of reason will see that what the defendants did was from the standpoint of the public interests good, and not evil. They contend that the jobbers were making little profit on the ware. It was troublesome and costly to handle. “Seconds” were on the market. The ware was getting a bad reputation. If the defendants had not done what they didj there would soon have been no trade either to restrain or to monopolize. There is little in the record to support this contention. Such an apprehension is vaguely expressed by some witnesses. If there had been marked falling off in the sale of the ware, the defendants know it. They could have shown it by definite and precise figures. They made no attempt to do so. If there was any such danger, it was very remote, far too remote to justify the defendants in doing anything which except for it would have been unlawful. That there was any real danger at all is not shown. According to the defendants, the public gained by what was done even upon the assumption that, if it had been-left undone, the trade would have continued in undiminished volume. The ultimate purchaser qí the ware seldom knows whether he gets a well-made article. To his eyes it may look well. He may think that it will for years be useful, sightly, and sanitary. In a few months he may find that it is wearing badly, and has become unsightly. He may have reason to fear that to some slight extent it has become dangerous to the health of himself and his family. He suffers from the greed of the maker, the jobber, or the plumber, or of two or all of them. He will be in no danger from that greed when no one of them can any longer make any money by selling him a bad article for the price of a good. Human nature being what it is, no other effective protection can be given him. If the so-called “seconds” and “Bs” are put upon the market at all, most of them will in the end be bought by people who do not know what they are buying. It is useless, according to this argument, to call the makers together and ask them to stop selling such goods. Resolutions pledging all the manufacturers to stop making and selling them, it is true, may be easily passed. They will be adopted with enthusiasm or with solemnity according to the mood of the moment, but always with absolute unanimity. L,ike so many other gentlemen’s agreements, they will be straightway broken.
If an enforceable bargain can be made that no goods shall be sold below a certain fixed price, which will yield a reasonable profit on a first-class article, jobbers and plumbers can be depended upon not to pay that price for an inferior article. The -defendants say that in no •other way can seconds be taken off the market and kept off. They point to what happened after January 1, 1911, when the price-fixing provisions of the agreement were suspended. The prohibitions against selling “Bs” and “seconds” were still in full force. Nevertheless the defendants’ witnesses say that the market was at once flooded with low-grade ware. Much of it came from some of the corporate de
Still, two questions remain: (1) Does the law permit the additional price which the public is to pay to be fixed by a combination of dealers even if the latter do so, because they cannot in any other way keep some of their own number from selling bad ware for good? (2) Has the experience of mankind led them to believe that to permit all the makers and dealers in articles of common use to combine to fix the prices and terms below which those goods may not be sold will tend in the long run to improve the quality of the goods?
The second question is not for the courts. The learned counsel for the defendants say that the first need not be answered in this case. They claim that prices were not raised by the defendants. They assert that the evidence shows that they were in fact lowered. The contention rests on a statement of Wayman. He says that the prices as fixed were intended to be on an average about 5 per cent, below those named in the last previously published price list of the defendant. the Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Company. The counsel for the defendants in supposing that Wayman meant that he reduced the then actually prevailing prices have misapprehended the market conditions. They assume that the Standard and the other corporate defendants were in fact getting the prices set forth in their catalogue. The record shows that they were not. Whether they 'ever had does not appear. They certainly had not during any of the period as to-which the record speaks. If in the winter and spring of 1910 those prices had prevailed, there would have been no agreements and consequently no case. The agreements as made'became fully operative June 4, 1910. No witness says that the published list prices had for many months been generally paid. The evidence is overwhelming that they had not.
On August 4, 1909, Wayman became commissioner or actuary of a newly organized or reorganized Sanitary Enameled Ware Association. All the corporate defendants, except the Kerner Manufacturing Company, belonged to it. Four other makers of the ware were members of it. These four refused to enter into the price agreements. Consequently they did not take licenses from Wayman. One of his duties as commissioner of the association appears to have been to do what he could by argument and expostulation to prevent price cutting among its members. To this end he wrote many letters. In one of them he speaks of cuts from 214 to 5 per cent, below the published prices as the norma! ana usual thing. He takes them for granted. They are not cause for complaint. What worries him is the cuts of 20 per cent, which he says were then being made. In March, 1010, the terms of the agreements executed two months later were being worked out by correspondence and conferences among the defendants. In that month Commissioner Wayman urged the members of the association to stop quoting what he called the “ridiculous” prices which had recently been made. The Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Company, whose published price lists defendants’ counsel suppose show the actual market prices, appears to have had a regularly organized system
The record contains many letters written by jobbers to some one or the other of the corporate defendants asking that orders alleged to have been sent in before Jfine 4, 1910, should be filled at the old prices. Sometimes their requests were granted. They were grateful. Sometimes they were told that their order had not come to hand before June 4th. If filled, it must be at the new prices. A long correspondence usually followed. The jobber tried hard to get the ware at the old price. Many letters passed between one Sullwold and the defendant Ahrens. Ahrens is president of the Standard. Sullwold is head of a Minneapolis jobbing house. He did not like the new scheme. Ahrens tried to get him to 'come into it. They wrote each other at great length. They go into many details. Whenever one thinks he can make a point on the other, he does so. Sullwold repeatedly says that the ware- will cost the jobbers more. Ahrens does not deny. Both take it for granted. Wayman testifies that to stop “ruinous competition” was one of the purposes of the agreements.
The J. M. Kohler Sons Company of Sheboygan, Wis., was a member of the Sanitary Enameled Ware Association. Wayman and a number of the defendants worked hard to get it to take a license. It would not. It claimed that the scheme was a price agreement, pure and simple. It said that price agreements were forbidden by the laws of the United States and of Wisconsin. One Kroos is connected with it. He was' a witness for the government. He presented some elaborate calculations as to the difference between the prices his company had been getting for the ware and the prices it would have received under the Wayman plan. As he figured it, the latter were in every instance greater. The difference ranged from 1 to 45 per cent. Defendants’ counsel say that he did not know what he was talking about. According to them, he did not understand how the price tables of the defendants were to be applied. He, however, gave the prices of his own company for the various articles principally dealt in by it and the defendants. It would have been easy for the latter to show what the true comparison was, if it had seemed to them expedient so to do. It is, however, not- important to determine whether Kroos did or did not fall into error. There is in the record a letter to the Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Company from one of its customers. It was written shortly after the price agreements went into effect. In it the writer remarks that, of course, the Standard understood that he could not do much with their prices so long as Kohler continued to sell at the prices it was then making. Quite clearly the new prices were materially higher than Kohler’s. The record shows that the agreements
Not only did the agreements raise prices — they prevented reductions that would otherwise have been made. The market conditions in the winter and spring of 1910 were such that prices left to themselves would have gone still lower. How rapidly the drop would have run into money is shown by a statement of the president of the Standard. Pie was trying to get the Kohler Company to take a license. He pointed out how good a thing the scheme was from the manufacturer’s standpoint. 1 ie said, if it did not go through, it would cost the Standard’s stockholders $300,000 in 1910, for in that event he would have to reduce prices. The defendants say that prices may be too low for the public good. Competition may be carried far enough to hurt everybody concerned. It may in the end he the direct cause of monopoly. Under its stress all but the strongest producers may go to the wall. The government replies that, if all the makers of an article of common use combine to raise and maintain prices and to punish any one of their number who reduces them, all the evils which to common experience of mankind result from monopolies will surely follow. Possibly both the defendants and the government speak truly. It may be that one of the great problems of the day is to find some way of protecting the general public against monopolistic combinations without compelling business men to subject themselves and their capital to all the perils of unrestrained competition. To find its solution would appear to be the business of the statesman. The defendants say the courts may give it. In their opinion makers and dealers may combine to raise prices without violating the Sherman act, provided that the prices fixed by their agreement are not unreasonably high.
In each particular case upon the evidence submitted the courts must say whether the prices asked are or are not reasonable. It would not be an easy task. Some standard of reasonableness would have to he worked out. The factors to he taken into account would he numerous and complex. The labor and expense of finding out what all the relevant facts were would he enormous. After all was done and said, the margin of doubt would usually remain large. If the dealers were bound to show affirmatively that their prices were reasonable, the government would usually win. If the government had to show that they .were unreasonably high, it would ordinarily lose. In this case the defendants assume that the burden of proof as to the unreasonableness
These opposing contentions raise questions of great moment and of exceeding difficulty. To answer them wisely rtiay require going to the very roots of our conceptions of what the relation of the state to the industrial life of its people should be. Every one has the right to discuss them. It may be a duty to do so at all reasonable times and in all proper places. This opinion is not a proper place for such a discussion. Some men believe that price agreements should be sustained by the courts, unless they are shown to be against the public interest. Others hold that they may be permitted only when it is affirmatively shown that they promote the public interest. Still others say that a price agreement pure and simple is always illegal. That the Supreme Court has declared the last of the above-stated contentions to be the law is conclusive here. Only a few months ago it said:
“Agreements or combinations between dealers having for their sole purpose the destruction of competition and the fixing of prices are injurious to the public interests, and void.” Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U. S. 408, 31 Sup. Ct. 384, 55 L. Ed. 502.
The patents spoken of in this case are for automatic dredgers. A dredger is used to sprinkle the powdered enamel on the ware. It serves no other purpose. It is not used in making the iron, or the ware out of the iron, or the liquid, or the powdered enamel, nor in the construction, the heating, or operation of the furnace, nor in taking the weighty and red-hot metal out of the furnace and putting it back. In the doing of these things many compositions of matter, machines, tools, appliances, and processes are employed. Upon the well doing of every one of them the usefulness, the attractiveness, and the durability of the ware depend. Whether any one of them shall be well or ill, cheaply or expensively, done, turns in greater or less degree upon the fitness and adaptability of the compositions, machines, tools, appliances, and processes used. Any patentable improvement in any one of them would hear the same relation to the ware as is borne by the automatic dredgers. There might be differences of degree in either direction. In legal theory no distinction would be possible. From •this point of view further inquiry into the precise degree of usefulness of the automatic dredger in the sprinkling step of the enameling process of making the ware might be omitted.
The question of law will be, in any event, whether the owner of a patent on one of many tools used in the making of a particular kind of unpatented ware may lawfully make such agreements with reference to it as those in the record. This case is, however, one of importance. In certain respects it is suggested that it is one of the first impressions. It will be well, therefore, to understand, how the enameler would like to sprinkle the powder, and to what extent and in what way the automatic dredger helps him to do it as he would. He wants to use little powder. It is more or less costly. The thinner the enamel coat, the better the ware looks and lasts. The whole surface ■of the article must be covered; otherwise it will be almost or altogether useless. The more uniform the coat of enamel is, the more .sightly and durable it will be. 'If little powder is to fully cover the
When makers of enameled ware first wanted to sprinkle powder on iron, they-set about doing it in the way in which men had for countless centuries been wont to sprinkle powder for other purposes. They took an ordinary sieve, dredge, or sifter. It was not unlike in size and shape that with which housewives had for time out of mind sifted flour or meal. The enameler, it was true, could not handle his sifter as his wife handled hers. He could not stand beside the surface he was to cover, and with both hands shake the dredge over it. He could not because that surface was part of a mass of red-hot iron. He must stand back from it. Accordingly a handle was put on the dredger. He could not shake it as his wife shook hers. Her only object was to reduce the meal to a fine powder. It made no difference whether more of it fell upon one portion of her board or pan than on another. He must sprinkle his powder uniformly. He could not .force it through the meshes by moving the whole dredger and its contents more or less briskly back and fro. He must move it regularly and in one direction. It was not desirable to let it come back on its own tracks. The enameler shook his sieve by tapping upon the handle with a piece of iron. Tfiis tapping occupied one of his hands. He had to support and guide the dredger with the other. He had a disagreeable choice to make. If he used a dredge with a short handle, he had to stand very near large articles of glowing iron. If he lengthened the handle, the weight of the dredger and its contents, at the end of so long a lever became too great for his strength. What he in fact at first did was to use a dredger with a handle three or four feet long. This brought him very close to the red-hot metal. To partially protect himself from the heat he wore asbestos masks, gauntlets, and breast-plates. Even so he had an uncomfortable job. The heat was always disagreeable. At times it must have been trying. Supporting the dredger with six to eight pounds of powder in it, and moving it steadily, firmly, and accurately over the surface, was hard work.
Whether they were, or were not frequent is now immaterial. Before the first automatic dredger was invented, it had ceased to be necessary for the enameler to stand close to the glowing metal or to support the weight of the dredger and its contents. It had occurred to some one that the handle might be supported from the ceiling. It could easily be balanced by a counterweight. The length of the handle was no longer limited by the physical strength of the workman. It was made seven or eight feet long. The asbestos armor was discarded, except tipon the arm and hand most exposed. The enameler had no great weight to support. One arm could be devoted solely to guiding the dredger. The other was still necessarily occupied in keeping up a continuous tapping. This form of dredger had come generally, if- not universally, into use before the invention of the pneumatic dredger some 12 or 13 years ago. In essence the patented dredgers differ from the unpatented in one respect only. Tn the former the tapping is done by machinery. In their predecessors it was done by hand. The handle of the patented dredger is made of hollow metal. In it a plunger is fitted. By compressed air or by electricity the plunger is made to keep up a continuous and perfectly steady and uniform tapping. The workman by the pressure of his thumb may at his will increase or decrease the frequency of these tap-pings, or he may stop them altogether. The automatic dredgers were supported in the same way as the unpatented long-handled dredger had been. The enameler who works with one can use both hands to guide the dredger. He has nothing else to do. His work is much simplified, and made far easier and more agreeable. The use of both
The patented dredger was useful in other ways. It could be fitted with a finer mesh. It puts the powder on the metal in a more finely divided form. This, as has been already pointed out, is an advantage. So long as the tapping was done by hand, the blows upon the handle would not always be hard .enough to force the powder through a mesh as fine as that which may now be used. The powder falls from an automatically tapped dredge with a regularity and uniformity greater than that which can be given to it by the average workman. The use of the patented dredgers may or may not save enameling powder. There is testimony both ways. With such dredgers .more work can be done in the same time. Other things being equal, it is probable that ware, in the enameling of which they have been used, will on the average be somewhat better enameled than it would have been had hand dredgers been employed.
The record does not enable us to tell in either absolute or relative figures or percentages how great is the saving of time or the bettering of quality. The same number of men in the same time now usually turn out more work then they formerly did. In the attainment of this end the patented dredger helps. Other things contribute. Some, but not all, of these other improvements can be used to greater advantage in connection with the automatic than with the hand dredger. How much the use of the patented dredgers improves the quality is still harder to figure out. Some men with fine tools cannot do as good work as other men with poor. The defendants’ evidence seems to -show that the percentage of ware of high quality turned out depends much more largely upon shop management and efficiency than it does upon the use of one form of dredger rather than another. One of the defendants’ witnesses says that with the hand dredge his shop made 95 per cent, of second and only 5 per cent, of first class goods. With the automatic dredger he gets 25 per cent, of seconds and 75 per cent, of firsts. This is definite enough. Another witness for the same side, but whose experience has been had in another factory, says that with the old hand dredge he made only 5 per cent, of seconds. By the use of the automatic dredger he has brought that proportion down to 1 per cent. If each of these witnesses is even approximately accurate, it follows that one of them with an automatic dredger made five times as large a proportion of inferior goods as did the other when using a hand dredger.
All that can be safely said is that the automatic dredgers are useful tools. By their use, all other things being equal, ware can be made more cheaply and on the whole of a somewhat better average quality. No one claims that he can tell by inspection of a completed article whether the enameling powder was sprinkled upon it with a hand or
It follows that there is no respect in which every tub in the enameling of which an automatic dredger has been used differs from every tub in the enameling of which the hand dredger has been employed. Whether the ware shall be well or ill made, whether it shall be durable or the reverse, whether it shall be sightly or unsightly, depends upon many circumstances of which the kind of dredger used to sprinkle the powder is only one, and probably not the most important. Much turns on the composition of the enamel. Each factory makes it according to its own formula, which it tries to keep secret. Perhaps none of the powders in use give complete satisfaction. Experiments for their bettering are continually being made. How controlling a part the composition of the powder plays is shown by the account given by one of defendants’ witnesses of the disastrous results upon the ware of an experimental change in the powder made since the first of the present year by one factory. The liquid enamel or slush coat must be properly made and fittingly applied. The furnaces must be adapted to the work to be done by them. The appliances for putting the ware into the furnace and for taking it out again must be constructed, so that with little consumption of time and labor the work will be done without damaging the delicate enamel not yet firmly fused upon its base. The castings must be well made and of the right kind of metal. It is quite possible that a new tool, appliance, or process may be invented for the better doing of any one of them. Its use may improve the average quality or cheapen the average cost of the ware, or both. Every such an inventor, if he obtained a patent for his invention, would be as much entitled as Waymau to say at what price and upon what terms men might deal in the finished article in some stáge of the making of which his invention had been used.
Defendants say that while it is true that the automatic dredger is a mere tool, used in only one operation of a number required for the making of the ware, and while it is conceded that merchantable ware can be made without its use, still ihe advantages of using it are so
The ware is absolutely unpatented. Any one may sell it as freely as he may a loaf of bread. No one- can tell by looking at a bathtub whether enameled powder has been sprinkled upon it by a patent dredger any more than any one who eats a loaf of bread can tell whether it has been baked in an oven with a patented grate, or who lights a kerosene lamp can tell whether in the process of refining a patented tool has been used, or by taking a pinch of snuff can be sure that there was or not a patented mill used in grinding the tobacco.
If agreements in this case are not violations of the Sherman act, similar agreements among all the bakers of bread, the refiners of petroleum, the grinders of snuff will be legal, provided that somewhere in the process of making the bread, refining the petroleum, or grinding the snuff a patented tool has been used. The issue is important: It cuts deep. The record squarely presents it. It must be passed upon. The defendants say they have broken no law, even if all that has thus far been said herein be true. They rely upon what they understand to have been decided by the Circuit Court of Appeals of the Seventh Circuit in the case of Rubber Tire Wheel Co. v. Milwaukee R. W. Co., 154 Fed. 358, 83 C. C. A. 336. There the court said that no one can use a patented article without the consent of the patentee. He may fix his own conditions. It adds:
“Whatever the terms the courts will enforce them provided only that the licensee is not thereby required to violate some law outside of the patent laws, like the doing of murder or arson.”
The defendants ask: “Is not the legal title to the dredger patents in Wayman?” “May any use the automatic dredgers without his consent?” “May he not make what terms he will for his license to use them?” “Will not the courts enforce those terms, provided they do not call for the violation of some law outside the patent law, like murder or arson?” “Have the defendants committed murder or arson
A patentee may not require his licensee to sell a patented oil which flashes below the minimum temperature prescribed by state, law. Patterson v. Kentucky, 97 U. S. 501, 24 L. Ed. 1115. He may not authorize his licensee to prescribe and sell his patented medicine in a state which requires of all who write prescriptions that they shall have qualifications not possessed by the licensee. Jordan v. Overseers of Dayton, 4 Ohio, 295. Selling oil with a low flashing point or prescribing patent medicine without having a state license to practice medicine would no more strike the average man as akin to murder or arson than would a combination to fix prices. In one respect they are like murder and arson. They are violations of law outside the patent-laws. So is a combination in restraint of trade. What the court meant was what the court said — a patentee cannot require his licensee to violate a law outside of the patent law. Murder and arson are out
The defendants have pressed upon our attention many cases in the ■Circuit Courts and in the Circuit Courts of Appeal. Many of them have upheld the right of a patentee to fix the price below which a purchaser from him of patented articles may not sell those articles. In some of these cases it has been held that one who sells at a lower price thereby becomes an infringer, and that the federal courts have
In a number of cases the owner of a machine patent has licensed others to use the machine on condition that they would buy certain unpatented things upon which the machine operated exclusively from the patentee. Those conditions have been held valid by a number of courts. Persons who with knowledge of the terms of the license have sold to the licensee some of the unpatented things to be used on the patented machine have been held liable for contributory infringement. Heaton Peninsular Button Fastening Co. v. Eureka Specialty Co., 77 Fed. 288, 25 C. C. A. 267, 35 L. R. A. 728; Rupp, Wittgenfeld Co. v. Elliott, 131 Fed. 730, 65 C. C. A. 544; A. B. Dick Co. v. Henry (C. C.) 149 Fed. 424; Æolian Co. v. Harry H. Juelg Co., 155 Fed. 119, 86 C. C. A. 205; Crown Cork & Seal Co. v. Brooklyn Bottle Stopper Co. (C. C.) 172 Fed. 225; Crown Cork & Seal Co. v. Standard Brewery (C. C.) 174 Fed. 252. In the case of Cortelyou v. Johnson, 145 Fed. 933, the majority of the Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit declined to hold that a third person who with knowledge of the restriction sold to a licensee ordinary articles of commerce to be used upon the licensed machine was a contributory infringer. All the judges held that in the particular case there was not sufficient evidence that the defendant made the sale with knowledge as to the terms of the license, and the use to be made of the ink. The Supreme Court affirmed the decision below on the ground of want of sufficient evidence of notice. It expressly refused to express any opinion as to whether the defendant could have been held had notice been shown. Cortelyou v. Johnson, 207 U. S. 196, 28 Sup. Ct. 105, 52 L. Ed. 167. A patentee may or may not be entitled to obtain his pay for his patented machine in whole or in part by stipulating that he shall have the sole right to furnish material to be used with it. We express no opinion upon the question. It would have been presented in this case had Wayman bargained with the corporate
What has been said is sufficient for the determination of this case. The ware is not patented. The agreements or licenses attempt to fix the price of unpatented ware and to monopolize the trade in it. The fact that Wayman had a patent on something else, even though it was a tool used in one step of the making of the ware, gives neither him nor his licensees the right to restrain interstate trade in the ware. The ownership of a patent for a tool by which old, well-known, and unpatented articles of general use can be more cheaply made gives no right to combine the makers and dealers in the unpatented articles in an agreement to make the public pay more for it. The first and second sections of the Sherman act, “when taken together, embraced every conceivable act which could possibly come within the spirit or purpose of the prohibitions of the law without regard to the garb in which such acts were clothed. * * * In view of the general language of the statute and of the public policy which it manifested, there was so possibility of frustrating that policy by resorting-to any disguise or subterfuge of form, since resort to reason rendered it impossible to escape by any indirection the prohibitions of the statute.” United States v. American Tobacco Co., 221 U. S. 181, 31 Sup. Ct. 648, 55 L. Ed. 663. In what has been said it has been assumed that Wayman was the real and substantial owner of the patents. That scheme was his. That his purpose was merely to make money for ■ himself by selling to the corporate defendants indulgences to sin against the Sherman act.
The government contends that this was not the real situation. In its view there is nothing before the court except an ordinary combination to raise and maintain wholesale and retail prices and to force all the makers and dealers in the country into it. Wayman, it says, was nothing more than the ordinary promoter. The patents served the purpose of the certificate of incorporation from New Jersey or Delaware used when the combination became a consolidation. We have not discussed this branch of the case. We will not. We refrain from doing so not because it would not be pertinent. It would. Ordinarily it would’ receive full consideration. Unusual circumstances shown by the record make it inexpedient and even improper to do so, if the case can be disposed of without commenting upon that aspect of it.
Some months before the Standard Sanitary Manufacturing Company, which until May 4, 1910, owned the basic automatic patent, had given the Colwell Company a revocable license to use the dredger. The latter wanted Wavman to renew the license. It apparently did not want it badly enough to be willing to bind itself to charge the uniform resale prices of the New York City plumbers to whom it sold a large part of the ware. Wayman finally agreed in writing that, if it would take a license, he would try to get from the commission of the corporate defendants leave to cut these prices whenever it found that maintaining them would seriously handicap it. If the commission would not let the Colwell Lead Company do so, the latter on 10 days' notice could terminate the agreement. It would appear that it became a party to the combination to an extent sufficient to entitle the government to injunctive relief against it.
Dissenting Opinion
(dissenting). I cannot assent to the conclusion reached by the court in this opinion. The facts established by the testimony, considered in the light of the law applicable thereto, compel me to conclude that the allegations of the petition have not been sustained.