25 F. Cas. 581 | U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Pennsylvania | 1818
The question in this ease is, whether the action is maintainable. The objection to the action of debt, where the penalty is uncertain is, that this action can only be brought to recover a specific sum of money, the amount of which is ascertained. It is said, that the very sum demanded, must be proved; and on a demand for thirty pounds, you can no more recover twenty pounds, than you can a horse, on a demand for a cow. Blackstone says (3 B1. Comm. 154) that debt, in its legal acceptation, is a sum of money due, by certain and express agreement; where the quantity is fixed and does not depend on any subsequent valuation to settle it; and for nonpayment. the proper remedy is the action of debt, to recover the specific sum due. So if I verbally agree to pay a certain price for certain goods, and fail in the performance, this action lies; for this is a determinate contract. But if I agree for no settled price, debt will not lie, but only a special action on the'-case; and this action is now generally brought, except in cases of contracts under seal, in preference to the acton of debt; because, in this latter action, the plaintiff must prove the whole debt he claims, or recover nothing at all. For the debt is one single cause of action, fixed and determined; and which, if the proof varies from the claim, cannot be looked upon, as the same contract of which performance is demanded. If I sue for thirty pounds, I am not at liberty to prove a debt of twenty pounds, and recover a verdict thereon; for I fail in the proof of that contract, which my action has alleged to be specific and determinate. But indebitatus assumpsit is not brought to compel a specific performance of the contract; but is to recover damages for its non-performance; and the damages being indeterminate, will adapt themselves to the truth of the case, as it may be proved; for if any debt be proved, it is sufficient.
The doctrine laid down by this writer, appears to be much too general and unqualified; although to a certain extent, it is unquestionably correct. Debt is certainly a sum of money due by contract, and it most frequently is due by a certain and express agreement, which also fixes the sum, independent of any extrinsic circumstances. But. it is not essential, that the contract should be express, or that it should fix the precise arnpunt of the sum to be paid. Debt may arise on an implied contract, as for the balance of an account stated; to recover back money which a bailiff has paid more than he had received; and in a variety of other cases, where the law, by implication, raises a contract to pay. 3 Com. Dig. 365. The sum may not be fixec by the contract, but may depend upon something extrinsic, which may be averred; as a promise to pay so much money as plaintiff shall expend in repairing a ship, may be sued in this form of action; the plaintiff averring that he did expend a certain sum. 2 Bac. 20. So, on promise by defendant, to pay his proportion of the expenses of defending a suit, in which defendant was interested, with an averment that plaintiff had expended so much, and- that defendant’s proportion amounted to so much. 3 Lev. 429. So an action of debt may be brought for goods sold to defendant, for so much as they were worth. 2 Com. Dig. 365. So debt will lie for use and occupation, where there is only an implied contract, and no precise sum agreed upon. 6 Term R. 63.
3 Wood. 95, states, that debt will lie for an indeterminate demand, which may readily be reduced to a certainty. In Emery v. Fell, 2 Term R. 28., in which there was a declaration in debt, containing a number of counts for goods sold and delivered, work and la-bour, money laid out and expended, and money had and received; the court, on a special demurrer, sustained the action, although it was objected that it did not appear that the demand was certain, and because no contract of sale was stated in the declaration. But the court took no notice of the first objection, and avoided the second, by implying a contract of sale, from the words which stated a sale. These cases prove, that debt may be maintained upon an implied, as well as upon an express contract; although no precise sum is agreed upon. But the doctrine stated by Lord Mansfield, in the case of Walker v.
Thus it appears, that in all cases of contracts, unless a special damage was stated, the primitive action was debt; and that the action of indebitatus assumpsit succeeded, principally. I presume, to avoid the wager of law; which in Slade's Case, was one of the main arguments, urged by the defendant’s counsel, against allowing the introduction of the action of assumpsit: as it thereby deprived the defendant of his privilege of waging his law. Buller seems therefore to have been well warranted in the ease of Walker v. Witter, in saying; that all the old cases show, that where indebitatus assumpsit will lie. debt will lie. The same doctrine is supported by the case of Emery v. Fell, 2 Term R. 30, which was an action of debt, in which all the counts of indebitatus assumpsit are stated; where the objection to the doctrine was made and overruled. So in the case of Herries v. Jamieson, 5 Term R. 557, Ashurst refers with approbation, to the opinion delivered in the case of Walker v. Witter. That debt may be brought for foreign money, the value of which the j ury are to find, had been deckled before the case of Walker v. Witter; as appears by the case of Rands v. Peck, Cro. Jac. 618; and in Draper v. Rastal, Id. 88, the same action was brought, though in different ways, for current money, being the value of the foreign.
Com. Dig. tit. “Debt,” p. 366., where he enumerates the cases in which debt will not lie, states uo exception to the rule that where indebitatus assumpsit will lie, debt will lie, but one for the interest of money due upon a loan. But the reason of that, is explained by Lord Loughborough in the case of Rudder V. Price; who states, that until the case' of Cooke v. Whorwood, 2 Saund. 337, upon a covenant to pay a stipulated sum by instal-ments, if the plaintiff brought assumpsit, after the first failure, he was entitled to recover the whole sum in damages; because he could not in that form of action, any more than in the action of debt, support two actions on an entire contract. Until that decision, the only difference between debt and assumpsit in such a case, was. that the former could not be brought, until after the last instalment was due; and. in the latter, though it might be brought after the first failure, yet the plaintiff might recover the whole, because he could not maintain a second action on the same contract.
I proceed with the doctrine of Judge Blackstone before stated. After stating what constitutes debt, he observes, “that the remedy is an action of debt, to recover the special sum due.” It is observable, that he does not say, that the plaintiff is to recover the sum demanded, by his declaration; and no person will deny, but that he is to recover the special sum due. After stating what constitutes a debt, and prescribing the remedy, Judge Blaekstone proceeds to the evidence and recovery; and says, “the plaintiff must prove the whole debt he claims, or he can recover nothing.” On this account he adds “the action of assumpsit is most commonly brought; because in that, it is sufficient if the plaintiff
In tlie case of M’Quillin v. Cox [1 H. Bl. 249], thei sum demanded was five thousand pounds; which was fifty more than appeared to lie due by the different sums. The objection was made on a special demurrer, that the declaration demanded more than appeared by the plaintiff's own showing to be due. The court did not notiee the alleged variance between the writ and declaration, or the mis-reeital of tlie writ; but overruled the demurrer. because the plaintiff might, in an action of debt on a simple contract, prove and recover a less sum than he demanded in tlie writ. From this last expression it might lie supposed, that the court meant to distinguish between the sum demanded by the writ, and that demanded by the declaration; but this could not liave been the case, because the sum demanded by the writ, and that demanded by the declaration was the same; viz. iive_ thousand pounds. There was, in fact, no variance; for, though the declaration recites tlie writ, yet tlie sum demanded, and which the declaration declared to be the sum which the defendant owed and detained. was tlie same sum as that mentioned in the writ; and the objection stated in the special demurrer, was made to the variance, between tlie sum demanded by the declaration, and the sum alleged to be due.
The distinction taken in the case of Ingledew v. Cripps, 2 Ld. Raym. 815, Salk. 659, runs through all tlie above cases, and appears to be perfectly rational, viz. that where debt is brought on a covenant, to pay a sum certain, any variance of the sum in the deed will vitiate. But. where the deed relates to matter of fact extrinsic, there, though the plaintiff demanded more than is due, he may enter a remittitur for the balance. This shows, that debt may be brought for more than is due. and that the jury may give less; or if they give more than is due. tlie error may be corrected by a remitter. -
Thus stands the doctrine in relation to the action of debt on contracts; and if debt will lie on a contract, where the sum demanded is uncertain, it would seem to follow. that it would lie for a penalty given by statute, which is uncertain, and de-