65 A. 392 | N.H. | 1906
"The public charges of government or any part thereof may be raised by taxation upon polls, estates, and other classes of property, including franchises and property when passing by will or inheritance." Const. [1903], art. 6. The main argument of the opponents of the tax is in support of the contention that any inheritance tax violates well known constitutional principles. It is not claimed that the language of article 6, as it now stands, is not sufficient to authorize legislation of this character; but the contention is that such action is contrary to the requirements of other provisions of the instrument, namely article 12 of the bill of rights, — "Every member of the community has a right to be protected by it in the enjoyment of his life, liberty, and property, He is, therefore, bound to contribute his share in the expense of such protection," — and the provision of article 5, part second, granting "full power and authority" to the general court "to impose and levy proportional and reasonable assessments, rates, and taxes upon all the inhabitants of, and residents within, the said state, and upon all estates within the same." It is claimed that an inheritance tax is of necessity disproportional and in that sense unequal, does not provided for an equal division of public expense, and is contrary to the special provisions cited, as applied in a long line of decisions of this court. This claim has the support of the decision in Curry v. Spencer,
"The definition of taxation, given in the foundation, is taken from books with which the leading statesmen of the Revolution were familiar." State v. Express Co.,
However equitable as an abstract proposition and logically correct in principle the rule of the compact of 1783 may be, or however just it proved in practice as applied to conditions then existing, the practical operation of that rule in promoting justice and prosperity under conditions developed by the changes of one hundred and twenty years in the manners, customs, habits, and possessions of a people is at least a question open to debate. The science of government was not exhausted by the writers who preceded the Revolution, nor did the principles laid down by them and adopted by the fathers conclude further thought upon the subject of taxation. It has been suggested since then that a government should impose such a tax as is "easily assessed and collected, and is at the same time most conducive, all things considered, to the public interests." McCullough on Taxation 19 (1844). "Equality of taxation, therefore, as a maxim of politics," says Mill, "means equality of sacrifice. It means apportioning the contributions of each person towards the expenses of government, so that he shall feel neither more nor less inconvenience from his share of the payment than every other person experiences from his." Mill Pol. Econ., bk. 5, c. 2, s. 2. Or, as stated by Adam Smith: "The subjects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of the government, as nearly as possible, in proportion their respective abilities, that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state." Wealth of Nations, bk. 5, c. 2, pt. 2. See Fawcett Pol. Econ., bk. 4, c. 1; 23 Enc. Brit. (9th ed.) 85. There is evidence that this was the equality sought by the framers of the constitution. Judge Sawyer's Report 9, 10, citing acts of April 12, 1770, and January 2, 1772, in which the object of the legislature was declared to be "that every person may be compelled to pay in proportion to his income." But the questions whether an annual distribution of public expense in proportion to the property of each taxpayer is the most equitable method, — whether in that or some other way *93 the public charges can be met so as to be least of a burden to the people, — are questions of economics not open in a judicial forum, but properly considered and determined in a convention of the people engaged in arranging the terms of the social compact and settling the fundamentals of government.
While an inheritance tax, or death duty, has been recognized as a method of governmental support from very early times, it was practically unknown in England at the time of the Revolution, but has since that time been in use there and more recently has been adopted in many of the states. Curry v. Spencer,
If at the making of the social compact the right of property, as then understood and reserved, did not include any right of control death, — if the property right was merely a life estate, remainder in the survivors united in the corporate organization called the government, — any power of testamentary disposition would be a grant from the many to the individual, a privilege which could be incumbered, limited, withdrawn, or regulated at will. If by natural right, or preexisting compact, the right of property enjoyment does, or does not, include the untrammeled power of disposition at death, the parties in revising or renewing the governmental compact may by mutual agreement add to, or detract from, the nature of the right. It might be agreed that all property on the death of the owner should be the property of the survivors. All inheritable quality might be taken from the conception of property as now understood. While such taking or such right of survivorship, if limited in amount and for use for public purposes, would possess some of the elements of a tax, it would lack fundamental elements of taxation as understood in this state from 1784 to 1903. It would be an application of property for public charges, but not a proportional division of public expense.
The sole question, therefore, is whether in 1903 the people intended to provide, in addition to taxation as hereto defined and understood, a different method for meeting public charges by the exaction for that purpose of part of the property of the individual upon his death. The express language is admittedly sufficient for the purpose. The only adverse argument urged is the failure to introduce express limitations of the provisions requiring proportion and equality in the distribution of the public burden. But the evidence is very clear that the intent was to authorize such taxation. The fact that such method of defraying governmental expense was not within the terms of the existing social compact as judicially defined, the growing favor with which such method was with almost entire uniformity regarded in other jurisdictions, the well understood need of additional sources of revenue to defray the increasing state expense, render certain that the purpose of the action upon the subject was to grant a power not understood to be given by the existing compact. The language used, — "property when passing by will or inheritance, -" similar *95 in form with the language of the statute, which is identical with the Massachusetts statute (Mass. R. L., c. 15, s. 1), indicates that to make clear that the desired power was granted language similar to that used elsewhere in imposing the tax was employed. The question submitted to the people and upon which they voted was: "Do you approve of empowering the legislature to impose taxes, not only upon polls and estates, but also upon other classes of property, including franchises and property when passing by will or inheritance, as proposed in the amendment to the constitution?" This proposition having been adopted by the requisite constitutional majority, it is impossible seriously to maintain that it was not intended to so amend the constitution as to permit the taxation of "property when passing by will or inheritance."
The only position left is, that though the people intended to so amend the instrument which evidenced their governmental agreement, they failed to express their purpose because they omitted to negative in express terms in this particular the general intent of the document. "The rule, that the general intent appearing shall control the particular intent, must sometimes give way, and effect be given to a particular intent plainly expressed in one part of the constitution, though apparently opposed to a general intent deduced from other parts. . . . The people having voluntarily agreed with each other to form themselves into a body politic, the legal meaning of the written agreement is their intention and understanding shown by competent evidence." State v. Express Co.,
But although the power to impose an inheritance tax is clear, it must be exercised so far as possible in accordance with all other provisions of the constitution. It must be an equal tax in the sense that it must affect all persons equally. In the present law all property taxed is taxed at the same rate, and the difficulty found in some cases with exemptions of a certain amount of property and with a tax varying according to the amount of property does not appear. But it is claimed that the tax is unequal in *97
that it is not assessed upon all property passing by will or inheritance. In Minnesota, under a constitutional provision authorizing the taxation of all inheritances, this was considered to be a fatal objection. Drew v. Tifft,
In Curry v. Spencer,
Case discharged.
All concurred.