159 Mo. 410 | Mo. | 1901
The object of this original proceeding is to compel respondent, the Associated Press, to furnish to the Star Publishing Company for publication in its newspaper, “The Star,” the budget of news collected daily by respondent, and also its Saturday night news reports.
Relator avers tender of a sum above that for which other papers of St. Louis are served by respondent with such news, and also avers demand made on respondent for furnishing to it its Sunday morning reports as per contract, and for such daily news reports, and its refusal to furnish the same.
Relator also alleges: “That the relator herein now is and has been for a long time past, to-wit, for the period of six months, ready and willing to enter into a proper contract with the said Associated Press to receive and pay the'reasonable charges of the said Associated Press, not only for its Saturday night news reports, but also for its daily news reports, and to comply with all the terms and conditions which the said Associated Press imposes upon its other publishers of daily English newspapers in the city of St. Louis receiving such news reports.”
The substance of the issues presented by the pleadings of the parties to this litigation has been very well condensed by counsel for respondent, and we adopt such condensation.
Relator asserts:
1. That it has a contract with the Associated Press for the Sunday morning news.
2. That the gathering of general news for publication in a daily newspaper is a public employment which must be exercised by those who engage in it for all publishers of dailies who may desire it, upon equal terms and without discrimination.
3. That the Associated Press has by its charter assumed this public employment, and so is bound to exercise it on behalf
4. That the Associated Press has broken down all competitors and secured a monopoly of the business of news-gathering, in consequence of which it is not practicable to publish a daily newspaper without the aid of its service.
5. That the Associated Press has been granted telegraph and telephone franchises by the States of Illinois and Missouri, and also possesses the power- of eminent domain.
6. That the by-law of the Associated Press which makes the consent of existing members a condition of admitting new members in any locality is in violation of the anti-trust laws of Missouri, Illinois and the United States.
The respondent, on the other hand, asserts:
1. That it never made any contract with the relator.
2. That the gathering of news, whether for daily newspapers or for other publications, is a purely private business requiring for its conduct no public franchises or privileges.
3. That while the Associated Press is in form a corporation for pecuniary profit, in its substance it is but a voluntary association of publishers of newspapers who have combined their energies for the sake of greater efficiency and economy in news-gathering.
4. That it has not and can not possibly monopolize the business of news-gathering, and that in fact there are now other general news-gathering agencies in successful operation in the United States.
5. That it does not own or operate telegraph or telephone lines and has no means for the transmission of news except -sitch as- are open to everybody on like terms.
6. That it has never exercised and does not possess the power of -eminent domain.
8. That its business is national and international in its scope and character, and so is protected against State interference by various provisions of the Federal Constitution which are cited.
I. It is fundamental in the law of mandamus, that it is indispensable to granting the writ, that a prior express and specific demand be made of respondent of that which relator seeks, and that a refusal of such demand occur before relator has any standing in court, or his application for the writ contains any ground for relief (Tapping on Mand., 282; 2 Spelling Extr. Rel., sec. 1381); and it should also be shown that defendant has it in his power to perform the act. [Moses on Mand., 204; High Extr. Leg. Rem. (3 Ed.), sec. 13; 14 Am. and Eng. Ency. of Law (1 Ed.), 106.]
Mandamus is never granted in anticipated omission of a duty. An actual omission of duty must have occurred before application for the writ is made. [High Extr. Leg. Rem. (3 Ed.), sec. 12.] Here there is no averment that relator even attempted to enter into “a proper contract” with respondent, saying nothing as to what those words mean.
Not only must the petition for the alternative writ contain such specific allegations as to prior demand, met by a refusal, but the judgment, if for relator, must be equally specific both as to the rights of the plaintiff and the obligation imposed on the defendant. [Price v. Riverside, etc., 56 Cal. 431.] If the petition for the writ be defective as aforesaid, the defect is a fatal one. [Ib.]
Again, the allegations of a “reasonable agreement” or “proper contract” in the alternative writ are too vague and indefinite to base the judgment of a court upon. What is a “proper contract ?” or what a “reasonable agreement ?”
II. But in addition to the points above, courts will not by mandamus compel the making of a contract, because, in such case, the element of the specific act to be performed must be wholly lacking. [People v. Dulaney, 96 Ill. 503.] Nor has a court any authority to compel the performance of executory contracts. [Ib.] See, also, Railroad v. Railroad, 110 U. S. 667; Express Cases, 117 U. S. 1; Railroad v. Jacobson, 21 Sup. Ct. Rep. 115.
Besides, a contract of the kind in contemplation must necessarily involve and require for a long time the exercise of judgment, continuous supervision, special experience, and business discretion. [Ib. and 14 Am. and Eng. Ency. of Law, 104; People v. Dulaney, supra; High, Extr. Leg. Rom. (3 Ed.), secs. 25, 28; Iron Age Pub. Co. v. Tel. Co., 83 Ala. 498.]
The case last cited strongly bears on, and affords apt illustration of the principle now under discussion, as well perhaps as others involved in this case. The Iron Age Company had contracted with the New York Associated Press, whereby it asserted the exclusive right to receive and to publish at Birmingham, Alabama, the daily news reports of the New York association. The Iron Age Company complained of a breach of this contract for that the Western Union Company gave those reports to two other daily papers in Birmingham. On this basis of fact, the Iron Age Company prayed injunction
III. The same line of remark and of authorities would be applicable to by-law 'T had it been enacted for the benefit of relator, which is clearly not the case. Under that by-law relator asserts that it is entitled to the service of news for its Sunday edition under an existing contract with the United Press. But that by-law, which respects the admission of members, only allows the admission of new members upon the affirmative sanction of a majority of the board of directors. This sanction has not been obtained, nor is it asserted that it has. But had the by-law been enacted for relator’s express benefit, it lacks a great deal of being a contract in its favor. It fixes no compensation to be paid, nor any other terms which go to make up a contract between the respondent and its members. Price is as essential as any other of the terms of a contract, and without this agreed upon, no contract exists. [Kelly v. Thuey, 143 Mo. loc. cit. 435.]
And, as before stated, mandamus does not lie to compel parties to contract with one another; it would be wholly foreign to the nature and attributes, of such a, writ which issues only for the enforcement of a clear and specific legal right, which right has been omitted to be granted by one whose duty it was to grant it. Until the party .whose duty it was to grant such right makes default, mandamus does not lie.
IY. In so far ás relates to respondent being possessed by its original charter of a right to conduct a telegraph and telephone business; it never exercised that authority and therefore
Y. These remarks bring up for discussion the main issue in this cause, in which the doctrine announced in the Munn Case, 94 U. S. 113, is relied on by relator. That case has never received the entire sanction of the legal profession, nor indeed the entire concurrence of all the members of the two courts which announced the decision.
Two dissents were entered at the time the majority opinion was delivered, Mr. Justice Eield writing the minority opinion, marked by his accustomed ability, and concurred in by Mr. Justice Strong. And there were two dissents also entered in the State Supreme Court (69 Ill. 80).
Since then, there have been various limitations to the doctrine suggested by various judges who concurred in the original opinion and subsequently pointed out what they understood the opinion to mean, and what they meant by their concurrence. And in subsequent cases there have been dissents which have .gone in direct opposition to the ruling in that case. Thus, in Budd v. New York, 143 U. S. 517, Brewer, Field and Brown, JJ., dissented, while in Brass v. Stoeser, 153 U. S. 591, Brewer, Eield, Jackson and White, JJ., dissented.
Munn’s case in brief was this: The Constitution of Illinois adopted in 1870, contained a provision which converted every warehouse in which grain or other property was
The authorities cited in the opinibn of the latter court, and we say it with due deference, scarcely warrant the conclusion reached. Thus, Hale, as quoted, in his treatise Be Portibus Maris, says:
“A man for his own private advantage, may, in a port or town, set up a wharf or crane, and may take what rates he and his customers can agree for cranage, wharfage, Jiousellage, pesage; for- he doth no more than is lawful for any man to do, viz., makes the most of his own. If the king or subject have a public wharf, unto which all persons that come to that port must come and unlade or lade their goods as for the purpose, because they are the wharves only licensed by the king, or because there is no other wharf in that port, as it may fall out where a port is newly erected, in that case there can not be taken arbitrary and excessive duties for cranage, wharfage, pesage, etc.; neither can they be enhanced to an immoderate*426 rate, but the duties must be reasonable and moderate, though settled by the king’s license or charter. For now the wharf and crane and other conveniences are affected with a public interest, and they cease to be juris privati only; as if a man set out a street in new building on his own land, it is now no longer bare private interest, but is affected by the public interest.”
In the first part of the quotation, distinct and express recognition'is given to the fact that private wharfs were in abundant existence in Hale's time and were, if remaining private, unrestricted in their charges. In sharp antithesis to the case of the owner of a private wharf, stands that of one, be he king or subject, who has in operation a public wharf. The reason of this is that “In England it hath always been holden, that the king is lord of the whole shore” (1 Black, 264), and being thus lord (and as Judge Coolet suggests) the title to the soil under the navigable water in England being invested in the Crown, therefore, such wharves can only be erected by express or implied license, and by making use of the public property in the soil. In such circumstances, then, the result naturally followed that such wharf was “affected with a public interest,” since it was public property, used either directly or indirectly by public permission, and, of course, subject to such terms as the sovereign might impose.
And the same rule would hold where the owner makes a dedication of his otherwise private wharf to the public use. In either case of erection by public permission or as a dedication, compensation for wharfage is limited to reasonable charges. Thus, the wharfinger occupies the same position, precisely, as does one who sets out a street in new building on his own land. [Heitz v. St. Louis, 110 Mo. loc. cit. 625, and cases cited.]
If the first part of the quotation heretofore made does not recognize that there are such things as private wharfs uncon
Allnutt v. Inglis, 12 East 527, decides nothing to the contrary of the doctrine asserted by Hale, for that was a case where the London Dock Company built warehouses in which wunes were deposited upon payment of such rent as the ware-housemen and the depositors agreed upon. Afterwards, however, the London Dock Company obtained from the government a certificate, whereby, under the general warehousing act, the importers could lawfully lodge and secure their wines, without paying the duties on them in the first instance; and this right was exclusive in the dock company and upon this it was held that in consequence of accepting the benefit arising from the certificate, such « monopoly and public interest attached upon the property of that company, as compelled it to charge only reasonable rates for receiving wines into its warehouses, Lord Ellenborough remarking: “There is no doubt that the general principle is favored, both in law and justice, that every man fix what price he pleases upon his own property, or the use of it; but if, for a particular purpose, the public have a right to resort to his premises and make use of them, and he have a monopoly, he must as an equivalent, perform the duty attached to it on reasonable terms.”
In short, it is the privilege conferred either directly or indirectly, or the dedication to the public use, which give origin to the duty toward the publi^ to demand only reasonable compensation for services rendered. And this is all, it would seem, that is meant by Hale when he speaks of “the wharf, crane,” etc., being “affected with a public interest.”
But for the acceptance of the exclusive-privilege-conferring certificate, there was n<f question, and there could be none, that the London Dock Company could have continued on the
And it is not inappropriate to say just here, that Allnutt v. Inglis, though quoted from on the basis and theory of being parallel to the Munn case, lacks such parallelism in this important and controlling feature and particular, to-wit, that in the former, the London Dock Company, of_ its own free will, accepted the warehousing act, and having done so, took its burdens along with its benefits, while Munn & Scott .were forced by the organic law, and in mvitum had their private elevator turned into a public one, without a single benefit received or a single privilege granted. Is it within the hounds or range of possibility for a distinction to be more plainly apparent than between these two cases ? Had the all-omnipotent Parliament of England forced the London Dock Company to accept the warehousing act, then this would have brought the Allnutt-Inglis case on the same plane and under the same rule as the Munn case announces, but had Parliament done so, it would have been incontinently regarded as a high-handed invasion of common right.
In ‘the License cases (5 How. U. S. 504), the only point decided was that various regulations for the sale of intoxicating liquors, and requiring licenses to issue, enacted by certain States, were not repugnant to the Federal Constitution. As to the case of Mayor, etc., v. Yuille, 3 Ala. 137, cited and quoted in Munn’s case to show that an ordinance regulating the weight and price of bread was valid, it suffices to say that the only point in judgment there was whether that portion of the ordinance was valid which regulated the weight of.bread; and it was adjudged valid in that particular. The baker in that case had failed to conform to the ordinance in
In the principal opinion reference is .made to the cases of public ferries, innkeepers, common carriers, 'hackney-coachmen, etc.; but in all these instances, those persons who engaged in such occupations or in building, owning or operating such properties, did so on the grounds and bases of some' special privilege granted by the sovereign power, or of some open and unambiguous dedication to the public use, which grant or which dedication took with them the necessity of submission to the terms on which the grant or dedications were made.
Thus, an inn at common law was publici. juris, and innkeepers compellable, where they had room, to receive all guests and their horses, and every man had a right to put up at such common inns, and they were devoted to the service of the community. [Robinson v. Walter, 3 Bulstr. 269; Rex v. Collins, Palmer 367; s. c., 2 Ro. Rep. 345.]
Eor this reason, they were granted protection by the law; had a lien on the baggage and horses of their guests; were liable if their guests’ goods were stolen, and were liable to suit
But although a livery-stable keeper does a very extensive business, yet he enjoys none of the privileges of an innkeeper, and contracts with his patrons on his own terms, and is not bound in law to receive coaches or horses, because he stands on the foot of private contract only, and is not under obligation by law to receive the horses, etc., of guests, as are innkeepers. [Francis v. Wyatt, 3 Burr. 1498.]
Thus, ferries were both private and public at common law; the former, where a person conveyed only himself and family across a stream of water; the other, where the owner could only operate it under a license, deemed a franchise, of the king, and where the ferry was treated as part and parcel of the public highway; and for so operating such ferry, the owner was permitted to take such rates of toll as the law allowed. [Mayor v. Starin, 106 N. Y. 1, and cases cited.]
Thus, with respect to mills, the lords of the manor having •erected mills on their respective domains for the public advantage, fettered their gift with the condition that those resident within their manors were to grind at their mills and upon this exclusive right to compel the public to grind at their mills, arose the right of the lord of the manor to regulate tolls taken 'at such public mills. [Woolrych on Waters, chap. 6; Hix v. Gardiner, 2 Bulstr. 195; 15 Viner’s Abr., 398, 399; Cooley, Const. Lira. (8 Ed.), 735, 736.]
In this country, mills being at an early day operated by water, they became affected by a public use by reason of the fact that in order to establish them it became necessary to exercise the power of eminent domain in flooding the lands of ■others, and thus the owner of the mill, having accepted governmental aid in establishing his mill, had to submit to govern
The same view_holds'as' to the right to fix the fees of hackmen, exercising, as they do, a public employment in the public streets and engaged in an occupation affording special opportunities for impositions and frauds, and therefore requiring close supervision, they are granted privileges of occupying certain public stands denied to others, and their charges to the public are regulated, which is only a condition imposed in return for privileges granted, privileges otherwise liable to abuse.
And a like rule holds as to a common carrier, one who holds himself out to the public as ready and willing to carry, for hire, certain classes of goods. Doing this, he thereby exercises, so it is said, “a kind of public office,” and grants the public such an interest in his business as authorizes each individual to demand the carriage of his goods upon tender of a reasonable, or a legally regulated, compensation. And as a result of his general assumpsit to the public, he is given a lien on the goods of his patrons, both for transportation and for advances made on them to the other carriers, and made responsible for their safe carriage except in certain cases.
Not so, however, with a mere private carrier, and no instance is on record where any legislation, even during the rigors of the common law, or the regime of an all-prevailing parliament has ever been attempted as to the regulation of his charges.
Nor can any instance be found where any lodging-house keeper, however extensive his business or numerous his patrons, has ever been deemed to have his “property affected with
The answer to the remarks thus made has already been ■given, and they may be further answered by saying that the cases of the common carrier, the innkeeper, etc., are exceptional to the general rule declaring that business relations of one man with another can not be made compulsory.
“It is a part of every man’s civil rights that he be left at liberty to refuse business relations with any person whomsoever, whether the refusal rests upon reason, or is the result of •whim, caprice, prejudice or malice.” [Cooley on Torts, •218.]
Commenting on the same topic, it is said by another author: “Business relations must be voluntary in order to be consistent with civil liberty. An attempt of the State to compel one man to enter into business relations with another,
So that it is only on the basis of the exercise of the police power, and that exercise based on certain exceptional conditions, that a person engaged in some quasi public business and enjoying some privilege or immunity incident to such business, or where he has dedicated his property to a public use,
As aptly remarked by Mr. Justice Eield, in his dissenting opinion: “One may go, in like manner, through the whole round of regulations authorized by legislation, state or municipal, under what is known as the police power, and in no instance will he’find that the compensation of the owner for the use of his property has any influence in establishing them. It is only where some right or privilege is conferred by the government or municipality upon the owner, which he can use in connection with his property, or by means of which the use of his property is rendered more valuable to him, or he thereby enjoys an advantage over others, that the compensation to be received by him becomes a legitimate matter of regulation. Submission to the regulation of compensation in such cases is an implied condition of the grant, and the State, in exercising its power of prescribing the compensation, only determines the conditions upon which its concession will be enjoyed. When the privilege ends, the power of regulation ceases. Jurists and writers on public law find authority for the exercise of this police power of the State and the numerous regulations which it prescribes in the doctrine already stated, that every one must use and enjoy his property consistently with the rights of others, and the equal use and enjoyment by them of their property. ‘The police power of the State,’ says the Supreme Court of Vermont, ‘extends to the protection of the lives, limbs, health, comfort, and quiet of all persons, and the protection of all property in the State. According to the maxim, sic utere tuo ut alienum non laedas, which, being of universal application, it must, of course, be within the range of legislative action to define the mode and manner in which every one may so use his own as not to injure others.’ [Thorpe v. Railroad, 27 Vt. 149.] ‘We think it a
As pointed out in the opinion just quoted from, Chancellor Kent, when treating of the protecting care which the Constitution throws over private property, says: “But though property be thus protected, it is still to be understood that the law-giver has the right to prescribe the mode and manner of using it, so far as may be necessary to prevent the abuse of the right, to the injury, or annoyance of others, or of the public. The government may, by general directions, interdict such uses of property as would create nuisances and become dangerous to the lives, or health, or peace, or comfort of the citizens. Unwholesome trades, slaughter-houses, operations offensive to the senses, the deposit of powder, the application of steam-power to propel cars, the building with combustiblé materials, and the burial of the dead, may all be interdicted by law, in the midst of dense masses of population, on the general and rational principle that every person ought so to use his property as not to injure his neighbors, and that private interests must be made subservient to the general interests of the community.” [2 Kent 340.]
Having made the quotations just above, Mr. Justice Eield proceeds to say: “The citations show what I have already stated to be the case, that the regulations which the State, in the exercise of its police power, authorizes with respect to the use of property are entirely independent of any question of compensation for such use, or for the services of
Judge Cooley in commenting on the “Police Power of the States,” says: “The police of a State, in a comprehensive sense, embraces its whole system of internal regulation, by which the State seeks not only to preserve the public order and to prevent offenses against the State, but also to establish for the intercourse of citizens with citizens those rules of good manners and good neighborhood, which are inculcated to prevent a conflict of rights and to insure to each other uninterrupted enjoyment of his own so far -as is reasonably consistent with a like enjoyment of rights by others.” [Const. Lim. (6 Ed.), 704.]
“The limit to the exercise of the police power in these
Further on the eminent author quotes from and discusses the Munn case, and in doing so, Says: “What circumstances shall affect property with a public interest is not very clear. The mere fact that the public have.an interest in the existence of the business, and are accommodated by it, can not be sufficient, for that would subject the stock of the merchant, and his charges, to public regulation. The public have an interest in every business in which an individual offers his wares, his merchandise,. his services, or his accommodations to the public; but his offer does not place him at the mercy of the public in respect to charges and prices. If one is permitted to take upon himself a public employment, with special privileges which only the State can confer upon him, the case is clear enough.” [-Ib. 736.] lie then proceeds to'state:
“In the following cases we should say that property in business was affected with a public interest: 1. Where the business is one the following of which is not of right, but is permitted by the State as a privilege or franchise. Under this head would be comprised the business of setting up lotteries, of giving shows, etc.; of keeping billiard tables for hire, and of selling intoxicating drinks when the sale by unlicensed parties is forbidden; also the cases of toll-bridges, etc. 2. Where the State, On public grounds, renders to the business special assistance, by taxation or otherwise. 3. Where, for the accommodation of the business, some special use is allowed to be made of public property or of a public easement. 4. Where exclusive privileges are granted in consideration of some'special return to be made to the public. Possibly there may be other cases.” [Ib. 738.]
Elsewhere, Judge Cooley touches on the same subject by saying: “The general rule undoubtedly is, that any person is at liberty to pursue any lawful calling, and to do so in his own way, not encroaching upon the rights of others. This general right can not be taken away. It is not competent, therefore, to forbid any person or class of persons, whether citizens or resident aliens, offering their services in lawful business, or to subject others to penalties for employing them.” [Ib. 744, 745.]
And in treating in this connection,' of the regulation of business charges and the power of the State in this regard, he makes these observations: “In the early days of the common law it was sometimes thought necessary, in order to prevent extortion, to interfere, by royal proclamation or otherwise, and' establish the charges that might be exacted for certain commodities or services. The price of wages was oftener regulated than that of anything else, the local magistrates being generally allowed to exercise authority over the subject. The practice was followed in this country, and prevailed to some extent up to the time of independence. Since then it has been commonly supposed that a general power in the State to regulate prices was inconsistent with Constitutional liberty.” [Ib. 734.]
Similar observations respecting the regulation of prices of labor, manufactures and commodities by the different States before the American Revolution, and of the abandonment of such regulations after our independence was achieved, and Federal and State Constitutions were framed and adopted, are
Of course, isolated cases, sporadic instances, perhaps, may be found of statutes making regulations of the sort, but they are extremely scarce; and it is to the last degree doubtful whether such an enactment is yet. to be found lingering obsoletely on the statute books of any of our States; certainly it is not enforced.
The Supreme Court of Illinois, in Munn’s case, when speaking of the power to “make needful rules and regulations respecting the use and enjoyment of property,” speaks of familiar instances in which the exercise of it in the State has been unquestioned, and among them, “in delegating power to municipal bodies to regulate charges of haekmen and draymen and the weight and price of bread.” Whereupon Judge Cooney says: “Regulating the weight of bread is common, and necessary to prevent imposition; but regulating the price of bread we should suppose would now meet with such resistance anywhere, as would require a distinct determination upon its constitutional rightfulness. How the baker can have the price of that which he sells prescribed for him, and not the merchant or the day laborer, is not apparent. Indeed, to admit the power seems to render necessary the recognition of the principle that there is and can be no limit to legislative inter
And if the extensive nature and magnitude of the business is to authorize legislative interference with the rates of prices charged, and thus “affect with a public interest” the property employed in such business, as is the evident theory which bore with great weight on the mind of the court of ultimate resort, then in addition to numerous instances suggested by Judge Cooley and by Justices Eield and Brewer where legislative interferences would logically follow the rule adverted to, may be mentioned the case of the farmers of this country whose labors on many million fields supply not only their own native land, but a large portion' of the civilized world with corn, wheat, pork and beef; surely the products of these farms on which they labor,’ if not the farms themselves, are “affected with a public interest,” for, in the language of the Federal Supreme Court: “Property does become clothed with a public interest when used in a manner to make it of public consequence, and to affect the community at large. When, therefore, one devotes his property to a use in which the public has an interest, he, in effect, grants to the public an interest in that use, and must submit to be controlled by the public for the common good. He may withdraw his grant by discontinuing the use; but, so long as he maintains the use, he must submit to the control.” [Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 126.]
If the property of these farmers is not “used in a manner to make it of public consequence and affect the community, (indeed the world), at large,” if they do not “devote their property to a use in which the public has an interest” (a very great interest), and thereby “in effect grant to the public an interest in that use,” it is difficult to conceive of a case where “property does (not) become clothed with a public interest,”
Contrasted with such a business, which is truly a “virtual monopoly,” all other human occupations fall into insignificance. Assuredly then, the business of farming is necessarily a “devotion of property to a use in which the public has an interest,” and its pursuit, “in effect grants to the public an interest in that use,” and this being the case, submission to public control as to rates, a fortiori, follows. But he would indeed be regarded as a bold innovator, if not a madman, who, keeping within the lines marked out in Munn’s case, and following the premises there laid down, to their logical conclusion, should offer a bill establishing the maximum rates at which wheat, pork, etc., could be sold, or merchandise or wares of the shoemaker or the potter or the blacksmith; certainly all of these products of labor do “become clothed with a public interest,” because “used in a manner to make them of public consequence, and affect the community at large.” It is not easy to see how they could be used in any other manner.
In the State Supreme Court in defense of the decision as to regulation of prices, the case of regulating interest on money is instanced. But at common law, taking any interest on money'was called usury, was a crime, punishable by écclesiastical censures during life, being regarded by canon law
Afterwards, Parliament made it lawful to take a limited rate of interest, but it is said that this was not on the theory of legislation arbitrarily fixing the price for the use of property, but of granting a privilege which the common law denied. Judge Cooley is of opinion that usury laws are not sustainable on principle. [Princip. Const. Law (3 Ed.), 260.]
It was asserted in the State Supreme Court that so long as one retains title and possession of his property, he is not deprived of his property within the meaning of the fourteenth amendment. The “destruction must be, for all substantial purposes, total.” This doctrine was echoed by the higher court. The latter court seems to regard it as a matter of regret that the word “deprive” used in the above amendment was not therein “defined.” Apart from the fact that the same word had long before been employed in the Constitutions of the several States, in fact or in substance (2 Story Const., sec. 194(1), and the word itself, in article 5 of the original Constitution, and in article 5 of the amendment thereto, and apart from the fact that it is not customary in framing an organic law to define the words used in composing it, the standards of our language, as well as judicial decisions, may be consulted; turning to those standards, we find that the word “deprive” “conveys the idea of either taking away that which one has or withholding that Avhich one may have.”- [Crabb’s Synonymes.] Other standards of our language define the word “deprive,” “To take something from; to keep from acquiring, using or enjoying something.” [Standard Dictionary.] Deprive, “To take arvay; end, injure or destroy.” [Cent. Dictionary.] And the synonyms of “injure,” are: “To do harm to; inflict dam
Turning to judicial decisions, we find that in Pumpelly v. Green Bay Co., 13 Wall. 166, it was field tfiat tfie flooding of a man’s land by constructing a dam across a river, under authority of a State law, was a taking within tfie prohibition, and required compensation to be made to tfie owner of tfie land thus flooded in order to meet tfie demands of tfie Constitution, and that it was not necessary tfiat property sfiould be absolutely taken in tfie narrowest sense of tfiat word, to bring tfie case within tfie constitutional provision; tfiat consequential injury was in many cases a sufficient basis on wfiicfi to invoke tfie protection of tfie fundamental law, and tfiat serious interruption of tfie common and necessary use of property is such as will be equivalent, under tfie Constitution, to a taking.
This court reached a similar conclusion under tfie Constitution of 1865, “tfiat no private property ought to be taken or applied to public use without just compensation,” where the city built a dike out into tfie river several hundred feet, thus filling up with mud tfie channel at tfiat point, thereby cutting off tfie plaintiff, a riparian owner, from fiis customary access to tfie stream where fiis landing was. [Myers v. City, 82 Mo. 367.]
It is familiar law tfiat tfie fee of land will pass by deed wfiicfi grants tfie rents; issues and profits of tfie land mentioned [3 Wasfib. (5 Ed.), 406], and tfie same method of description holds good in a devise. [Scfiouler, Wills (3 Ed.), sec. 503.] And so of a devise of tfie income of land. [Ryan v. Allen, 120 Ill. 648; Parker v. Plummer, Cro. Eliz. 190.] This was so in tfie days of Lord Coke, who, when treating of this rule of description, said: “Eor what is land but tfie profits thereof ?” [Coke on sLitt. 4 b.]
So tfiat, it results tfiat “to deprive one of tfie use of fiis
These observations drawn and deduced from the authorities cited, find ample and felicitous illustration in the case of Eaton v. Railroad, 51 N. H. 504. In that case the railroad corporation, claiming • to act under legislative authority, removed a natural barrier situated south of E.’s land, which theretofore had completely protected E.’s meadow from the effects of floods and freshets in a neighboring river. In consequence of this removal, the waters of the river, in times of floods and freshets, sometimes flowed on to E.’s land, carrying sand, gravel, and stones thereon. Held, that this was a taking of E.’s property, within the meaning of the constitutional prohibition; and that the Legislature could not authorize the infliction of such an injury without making provision for compensation.
In discussing the points presented by the record, Judge Jeremiah Smith delivered an opinion which for close analysis and exhaustive research, is seldom equaled. Among other things, he said: “The vital issue then, is, whether the injuries complained of amount to a taking of the plaintiff’s property, within the constitutional meaning of those terms.....The constitutional prohibition (which exists in most, or all, of the States) has received, in some quarters, a construction which renders it of comparatively little worth, being interpreted much as if read — ‘No person shall be divested of the formal title to property without compensation, but he may, without compensation, be deprived of all that makes the title valuable.’ To constitute a ‘taking of property,’ it seems to have sometimes
“In a strict legal sense, land is not ‘property/ but the subject of property. The term ‘property/ although in common parlance frequently applied to a tract of land or a chattel, in its legal signification ‘means only the rights of the owner in relation to it.’ ‘It denotes a,right .... over a determinate thing.’ ‘Property is the right of any person to possess, use, enjoy, and dispose of a thing.’ [Seldon, J., in Wynehamer v. People, 13 N. Y. 378, p. 433; 1 Blackstone Com., 138; 2 Austin on Jurisprudence (3 Ed.), 817, 818.] If property in land consists in certain essential rights, and a physical interference with the land substantially subverts one of those rights, such interference ‘takes/ pro tanto, the owner’s ‘property.’ The right of indefinite user (or of using indefinitely) is an essential quality or attribute of absolute property, without which absolute property can have no legal existence. ‘Use is the real side of property.’ This right of user necessarily includes the right and power of excluding others from using the land. [See 2 Austin on Jurisprudence (3 Ed.), 836; Ells, J., in Walker v. Railroad, 103 Mass. 10, p. 14.] Erom the very nature of these rights of user and of exclusion, it is evident that they 'can not be materially abridged without, ipso facto, taking the owner’s ‘property.’ If the right of indefinite user is an essential element of absolute property or complete ownership, whatever physical interference annuls this right takes ‘property/ although the owner may still have left to him valuable rights (in the article) of a more limited and circumscribed nature. He has not the same
“If, on the other hand, the land itself be regarded as ‘property,’ the practical result is the same. The purpose of this Constitutional prohibition can not be ignored in its interpretation. The framers of the Constitution intended to protect rights which are worth protecting, not'merely empty titles, or barren insignia of ownership, which are of no substantial value. If-the land, ‘in its corporeal substance and entity’ is ‘property,’ still, all that makes this property of any value is the aggregation of rights or qualities which the law annexes as incidents to the ownership 'of it. The constitutional prohibition must have been intended to protect all the essential elements of ownership which make ‘property’ valuable. Among these elements is, fundamentally, the right of user, including, of course, the corresponding right of excluding others from the use. [See Comstock, J., in Wynehamer v. People, 13 N. Y. 378, p. 396.]......
“The principle must be the same whether the owner is wholly deprived of the use of his land, or only partially deprived of it; although the amount or value of the property taken in the two instances may widely differ. If the railroad corporation take a strip four rods wide out of a farm to build their track upon, they can not escape paying for the strip by the plea that they have not taken the whole farm. So a par
A ruling in which, in similar circumstances, a like result was reached, has occurred in England. [Lawrence v. Railroad, 20 L. J. N. S. 293; s. c., 2 Eng. Law and Eq. 265, cited Angelí, W-ater Courses (7 Ed.), sec. 331a.]
“Depriving an owner of property of one of its essential attributes, is depriving him of his property within the constitutional provision.” [People v. Otis, 90 N. Y. 48.]
As the right to the use of property is all that makes it valuable, and there may be a partial deprivation of such use equally demanding compensation as would a total deprivation, then it must also follow that a legislative and compulsory diminution of “the price of the use of property” (to phrase it as does the learned Chief Justice) must be equally as obnoxious to constitutional prohibitions as a similar diminution or deprivation of the use itself. It would seem nothing could be more logically clear than this.'
Both in the State Supreme Court and in that of the Nation it was ruled that the fixing of a reasonable compensation for the use of property was wholy a legislative and not a judicial question, that is, a maximum in rates beyond which the owner could not go; and that the only redress against these arbitrary legislative edicts was: “For protection against abuses, by legislatures, the people must resort to the polls, not to the courts.” According to'this, if the owner of a water mill should have the stream which turns it diverted by legisla
This-position as to regulating rates by law was not, however, long maintained; it was abandoned in subsequent cases, holding that “the element of reasonableness, .... is eminently a question for judicial investigation, requiring due process of law for its determination.” [Railway v. Minnesota, 134 U. S. 418.] To the like effect are Reagan v. Trust Co., 154 U. S. 362; Railway v. Gill, 156 U. S. 649, and other cases.
But the court has never yet ventured to fix what rates would be reasonable; though “judicial protection,” is certainly more preferable than “resort to the polls.”
This change in position would appear quite a modification of the original doctrine. The case of Budd v. New York, 117 N. Y. 1, was a case of a “floating elevator,” but the same doctrine was announced as in Munn’s case, where the elevators were stationary. Mr. Justice Pecki-iam (with whom concurred another member of the court), delivered a most exhaustive and instructive dissenting opinion in which are reviewed a great array of authorities all bearing on the subject under discussion and all opposed to Munn’s case. When the cause reached the final tribunal (143 U. S. 549) Mr. Justice Brewer, in dissenting, said with great force and aptness (rem acu tetigit):
In concluding his opinion, in which Mr. Justice Eield and Mr. Justice Brown concurred, the learned Justice expressed the hope; “I believe the time is not distant when the evils resulting from this assumption of a power on the part of government to determine the compensation a man may receive for the use of his property, or the performance of his personal services, will become so apparent that the courts will hasten to declare that .government can prescribe compensation only when it grants a special privilege, as in the creation of a corporation, or when the service which is rendered is a public service, or the property is, in fact, devoted to a public use.”
In his dissenting opinion in Budd’s case (117 N. Y. 1), Mr. Justice Peckham noticed the fact that in Railroad v. Illinois, 118 U. S. 557, Mr. Justice Miller, speaking for the court in regard to Munn’s case, and what was there decided, said: “And in that case the court was presented with the question, which it decided, whether any one engaged in a public business, in which all the public had a right to require his service, could be regulated by acts of the Legislature in the
But this states a very different doctrine and very different facts to those announced in the case to which it refers, because Munn was not “engaged in a public business,” nor did the “public have a right to require his service.”
In Brass v. Stoeser, 153 U. S. 391, the defendant owned a small elevator located on his own land; capacity, 30,000 bushels; his exclusive- business was buying and selling grain, although occasionally he accommodated his neighbors with the temporary use of his bins, when those bins were temporarily empty; but yet it was held that under the rule in Munn’s case, he was bound to accommodate all comers, notwithstanding the “admitted fact that if compelled, as he was compelled by the mandate, to receive gram as tendered so long as-he had storage capacity unoccupied in his elevator, his principal business and that for ivhich he built the elevator would be utterly ruimectt and destroyed." To this ruling, Brewer, Field, Jackson and White, JJ., dissented.
Recurring to the views of Lord Hale as heretofore quoted, it is not thought, as already stated, that those views give countenance to what is asserted of them in the principal case, nor does Judge Cooley approve of the construction placed upon them by the court, as above pointed out. But granting that Hale's views are as extreme as represented, or that certain deductions are warranted therefrom, yet it must not be forgotten that he wrote at a time when paternalism was in flower, and its veritable exponent, chapter 4 of 5th Elizabeth, was in-full force.
“That statute assumed to regulate the existence and determine the number of the artisans in the whole country. It provided how long one should work as an apprentice; how many there should be in proportion to journeymen; where they should
“During this time, also, there were statutes making it a felony to export wool from England, and the exporter of sheep, rams or lambs was liable to imprisonment, the forfeiture of all his property, and to have his left hand cut off for the first offense, and for the second offense to be adjudged a felon and to suffer death accordingly. (See 8 Eliz., ch. 3; 13 and 14 Chas. 2, chap. 18). Provisions were extant forbidding exportation of hides, raw or tanned leather, and many other things, and all for the supposed benefit of the kingdom or the various interests in whose favor the legislation was enacted. (Smith’s Wealth of Nations, by McCulloch, p. 292 et seq.)' Laws were then in force which regulated down to the minutest detail the manner of life, and the texture of dress and the costliness thereof, and the variety of dishes upon the tables of the people; special laws determined how much land of an estate should- be plowed and how much left in pasture; how much was to surround a laborer’s cottage; how many sheep should be supported on a farm. (England in the Eighteenth Century, Lecky, vol. 6, p. 231 et seq.) ” [Budd v. New York, 117 N. Y. loc. cit. 45.]
That Hale’s views were- colored by the state of the then existent statutory law, no one can doubt who has any knowledge of the nature of the human mind. Besides, when Hale wrote, the country where he wrote was under the dominion of a practically omnipotent Parliament, unfettered and unhampered by
Now, if by this statement it is meant to be intimated, as seems to be the case, from subsequent observations, that a State Legislature is possessed of substantially the same powers as the Parliament of Great Britain, the intimation is unfounded in, and unsupported by, recognized authority. Discussing the essential difference between the powers of the British Parliament and those of a State Legislature, Judge Cooley says: “It is natural, also,.......to concede without reflection that whatever the legislature of the country from which we derive our laws can do, may also be done by the department created for the exercise of legislative authority in this country. But to guard against being misled by a comparison between the two, we must bear in mind the important distinction already pointed out, that with the Parliament rests practically the sovereignty of the country, so that it may exercise all the powers of the government if it wills so to do; while on the other hand the legislatures of the American States are not the sovereign authority, and, though vested with the exercise of one branch of the sovereignty, they are nevertheless, in wielding it, hedged in on all sides by important limitations, some of which are imposed in express terms, and others by implications which are equally imperative.” [Cooley Const. Lim., 102.]
Touching this matter it is said by the author of the Insti
Parliament “is at once a legislature and a constitutional convention.” [1 De Tocqueville’s-Democracy in America, c. 6, p. 103; Eaton v. Railroad, supra, loc. cit. 516.]
Munn’s case has met with many criticisms of an adverse character in addition to those above noted. Speaking of the doctrine it establishes, Tiedeman, in reviewing that case, remarks: “I say this rule has been laid down for the .first time, although the Chief Justice refers to it as a long established rule, and refers to Lord Hale as his authority. A careful study of Hale's writings will disclose the fact that to no case does he refer in which the business does not under the law constitute a privilege, more or less of a legal monopoly. There is nothing in his writings to justify the application of his rule or his reasoning to a business, which is a virtual monopoly, but is not made so by law.” [-Tiedeman’s Lim. Pol. Pow;, pp. 230, 231.]
Yol. 16 Am. Law. Eegis. (N. S.) 526, published the opinion as well as a very 'copious note, citing many authorities, which concludes thus: “No other court has ever held that a Legislature .could fix the rate at which a private person performing a service, in which he has no other monopoly than that
' And criticism has not been confined to this side of the Atlantic ; even in the land from whence our common law is derived, Mr. Bryce, a lawyer and statesman of distinguished ability and author of the great work, “The American Commonwealth,” in reviewing the case, thinks that the decision was, perhaps, more the effect of public opinion in its action upon the court than of a strict adherence to legal principles; and while, as he says, not presuming to question its correctness, yet adds that it evidently represents a different view of the sacredness of private rights, and of the powers of the Legislature, from that entertained by Chief Justice Marshall and his associates. [See 1 Bryce’s American Commonwealth, p. 267.]
Much was said in the opinion in question, about a “virtual monopoly.” These words were, it is true, used by Lord Ellen-borough in 12 East, but those words must be construed with reference to the facts then presented. It was a clear case of a legal monopoly; for there the London Dock Company was mentioned by name in the warehousing act, and was the only company into whose warehouses wines- could be stored, without prior payment of excise duties.
There can be no such thing as a legal monopoly unless based upon a license or privilege allowed,by the king, etc. (4 Bl. Com. 159. To same point are: Charles River Bridge v. Warren Bridge, 11 Pet. 420, 606, 607, per Story, J.; Railroad v. Richmond, 26 Iowa 191, 201, 202; affirmed, 19 Wall. 584; In re Greene, 52 Fed. Rep. 104), and necessarily, the party to whom the license is granted, takes it on such conditions as the license-granting power may see fit to impose.
The controlling element which gave origin to the opinion relied on seems to.have been that of a monopoly. But of course, that element can have no place in the present instance, because respondent has been granted no special or exclusive right or privilege by the State, nor has it received any benefits from that quarter. Nor has the respondent acquired any additional right by reason of its incorporation, to that it possessed before. Every one is at liberty to gather news; and the fact that one has greater facilities or finances for gathering and transmitting news, or that the business has grown into one of great magnitude, wide-spread in its ramifications, or that mere incorporation has been granted a company organized for the purpose of gathering news, does not and can not of itself give the State the right to regulate what before incorporation, was but a natural right. [Tiedeman’s Bol. Pow., sec. 93, p. 234.]
Were the rule otherwise than as just stated, the effect would be to deprive a person of a right to pursue any lawful calling or to contract where and with whomsoever and at what price he will. The right thus to contract can not be interfered with; it is part and parcel of personal liberty, and therefore under the protection of section 30, article 2 of our State Constitution and of the fourteenth amendment of the Constitution
If relator’s position as to its right to compel respondent to turn over to it the results of its labors and researches after news, is correct, then by the same token, any citizen could compel any newspaper to admit him as a Subscriber; or as news is a synonym of information, intelligence, knowledge, then a lawyer profoundly versed in his profession, could be compelled to yield his treasures of erudition to some less fortunate member of the bar, of the type described by Swift:
“Who knows of law nor text nor margent, Calls Singleton his brother sargeant.”
And even if the business of respondent can justly be deemed a monopoly, then relator’s efforts should be directed toward the destruction of that monopoly and not towards obtaining the mandate of this court compelling relator’s admission into that “real genuine article,” as counsel are pleased to designate it.
Conceding respondent’s business to be in truth a monopoly, would furnish an all-sufficient reason and answer for denying the relief relator asks; because the addition of one more monopolist to a monopolistic organization, would not lessen its monopolistic features, or abate its vicious tendencies. But there is nothing here on which a monopoly can attach. The business is one of mere personal service; an occupation. Unless there is “property” to be “affected with a public interest,” there is no basis laid for the fact or the charge of a monopoly. [See, on this point, Morris v. Colman, 18 Ves. 437 (per Lord Eldon);
Nor is there any more property in “news” to-wit, “information,” “intelligence,” “knowledge,” than there is in the “the viewless winds,” until the “guinea stamp”-of a copyright is impressed upon its external similitude, thus giving it one of the elements of property, to-wit, governmental protection for a limited period. That there is no monopoly even in fact, in the business in which respondent is engaged, is shown in the clearest possible manner by this record. Other news-gathering agencies have the same facilities over the wires of the Western •Union Telegraph, as has the Associated Press; the terms of the telegraph company are uniform as to all organizations, and such other agencies are at work in their occupation, and it would seem with great success. Hundreds of daily newspapers in every quarter of the Union, leaders in point of circulation in their respective localities, look for their news supplies to some other agency than that of respondent. Some publishers accustomed to receive reports from respondent have discontinued their business relations with it and gone to some rival or competing organization. The New York Sun, repeatedly urged to join the respondent, has continuously declined. And the relrtorcompany, notwithstanding the allegations of its petition, that its paper could not be published with a profit without the aid of the Associated Press, Mr. Lowenstein, the Star’s business manager, gives it as his opinion under oath, that “the Star prints a better budget of news than any of its rivals.”
Eor the purpose of obtaining its supplies of news, the Star is affiliated with the New York Sun or Laffan News Bureau, and concerning the efficiency of that service, Mr, Laffan testifying, says: “It has no equal at all, 'from our point of view.” And answering the question whether “as a
If these statements are to be taken as true, and so they will be regarded for the purposes- of this case, relator has no standing in court, because Lord Ellenborough in the Allnutt-Inglis case, supra, after commenting on the fact that the London Dock Company's warehouses were the only places where wines of importers could be bonded, went on to say: “If the Crown should hereafter -think it advisable to extend the privilege more generally to other persons and places, so far as that the public will not be restrained from exercising a choice of warehouses for the purpose-, the company may be enfranchised from the restriction which attaches upon a monopoly.” [12 East, loe. cit. 540.]
And because, further, a court in circumstances as above related, will not award a discretionary writ as now here prayed, for the mere purpose of determining an empty and barren technical right in behalf of a petitioner; it will “let well enough alone.”
Subsidiary to considerations heretofore mentioned, may be suggested others tending in the -same direction. In Mathews v. Associated Press, 15 N. Y. Supp. 887, defendant, a corporation organized under the act “to incorporate the Associated Press of the State of New York” (Chap. 754, Laws of 1867), adopted a by-law prohibiting its members from receiving or publishing “the regular news dispatches of any other news association covering a like territory and organized for a like purpose.” A suspension of all the rights and privileges of the association was provided as a penalty for a violation of said provision. In an action to restrain defendant from enforcing this penalty, held, that the association had power to enact the
It appeared that while defendant only appoints and engages agents, in the strict sense of the term, in the State of New York, by virtue of contracts with other associations, it receives from them news collected from the principal portions of the civilized world. Plaintiffs are also members of, and they publish the news received from, another press association which collects its news, by its own agents, from substantially the same territory. Held,' further, that this action' of plaintiffs came within the prohibition of the by-law and authorized defendant to enforce the penalty.
The court in general term among other things said: “The business of collecting the news of the day and furnishing reports of it to the press for a compensation has become a very well known and important industry. It can scarcely be called a branch of trade. There is no right of property in the news itself. That is neither bought nor sold. Any man who hears it may make such use of it as he can for his own advantage or may communicate it to others. So he may make a business of collecting news and furnishing reports of it to the newspapers or to such of them as will compensate him for his trouble. The work is commonly done in the locality of each newspaper by its own reporters employed and paid for that' purpose........In this case the agents are employed by the defendant, the Associated Press of the State of New York, acting for all the publishers who are comprised in its membership. As to all these, the charter and by-laws of the corporation constitute the contract between themselves and between them and the association. Among the provisions of that contract is one to the effect that none of the members shall contract with any other news association to employ for them agents for
This ruling of the Supreme Court was unanimously affirmed by the Court of Appeals, Mr. Justice Peckham delivering the opinion, who afterwards delivered the opinion of the court in United States v. Freight Ass’n, 166 U. S. 290.
In a prior case, Dunlap’s Cable News Co. v. Stone, 15 N. Y. Supp. 2, the contention was made that news-gathering was a “public business.”
The Cable News Company was a corporation engaged in collecting news and selling the same to all newspapers applying therefor. The New York Associated Press was an association of newspaper proprietors also engaged in the business of collecting news and furnishing it to newspapers. The association had a by-law to the effect that none of its members should take news from any other agencies. For violation of this by-law by a number of publishers the association threatened to discontinue its service to them. The suit was to enjoin the association from such proposed action. The plaintiff alleged that
A motion for an injunction pendente lite was denied. On appeal to the general term the ruling below was sustained. The court said: “The plaintiff’s application amounted to nothing more nor less than an attempt to restrain the defendants from transacting their lawful business in their own way, lest in doing so plaintiff’s rival business should be injured or diminished. The defendants have a perfect right to limit the sale of the news which they collect to those who contract to deal exclusively with them. They.are private individuals, dealing, it is true, with a large public, but governed by no corporate duty or statutory obligations. They certainly owe no duty to the plaintiff, which is a foreign corporation, attempting to compete with them, and with whom they have no privity or relations of any kind.”
In the latter case the defendant association was not incorporated ; in the former it was, but both cases were treated alike in this respect.
And it has been determined that: “A voluntary association, whether incorporated or not, has, within certain well-defined limits, power to make and enforce by-laws for the government of its members. Such by-laws are ordinarily matters between the association and its members alone, and with which strangers have no concern.” [Live Stock Com. Co. v. Live Stock Exch., 143 Ill. 210.]
In making this ruling, not only was Munn’s case on the point involved, cited with approval, .but in addition thereto, Ladd v. Southern Cotton Press Co., 53 Tex. 172, was cited, and its language approvingly quoted:
“We know of no authority, and none has been shown us, for saying that a business strictly juris privati will become juris publici, merely by reason of its extent. If the magnitude of a particular business is such, and the persons affected*463 by it are so numerous, that the interests of society demand that the rules and principles applicable to public employments should be applied to it, this would have to be done by the Legislature (if not restrained from doing so by the Constitution), before a demand for such use could be enforced by the courts.”
It is not pretended here that such legislation as would make respondent corporation’s business juris publici, has been enacted, granting that such legislation could have any extraterritorial effect (as to which see Vawter v. Railroad, 84 Mo. 679; State v. Gritzner, 134 Mo. 512, and cas. cit.; Harris v. White, 81 N. Y. loc. cit. 544).
It is needless to discuss, in this connection, cases which bring into view the duties of railroad, telegraph and telephone companies, since those companies, having accepted legislative favors, right of eminent domain, etc., must shoulder the burdens along with the benefits, and their business becomes, by such acceptance, ipso fado, publici juris. Not so, however, with respondent, which was granted no privileges, asks none, and can not, therefore, be burdened with conditions such as pertain to common earners and the like.
As to the case of Minnesota Tribune Co. v. Associated Press, 83 Fed. Rep. 350, it seems to recognize the validity of such contracts by the Associated Press, as are the subject of complaint here. But if this is not so, we prefer the ruling and reasoning on this point in Matthews’ case.
In regard to Stock Exchange v. Board of Trade et al., 127 Ill. 153, much relied on by relator: For many years the Board of Trade had been accustomed to furnish to all customers, the telegraphic reports as to daily and hourly conditions of the grain and other markets; having done so for such a long time, it undertook suddenly to disrupt those long continued business relations and leave the plaintiff, a corporation
Relative to the recent decision by the Supreme Court of Illinois in the Inter-Ocean Publishing Company v. The Associated Press, to -which our attention has been called: The Inter-Ocean Company was engaged in publishing two newspapers in Chicago, the Daily and the Weekly Inter-Ocean. A contract was entered into between the parties as to furnishing-news in accordance with the by-laws of the Associated Press. This contract the Inter-Ocean Publishing Company violated by procuring and publishing news obtained from other news concerns located in the city of New York. Being notified by the Associated Press to appear to answer such charges of violation of contract, the Inter-Ocean Publishing Company resorted to injunction to prevent expulsion for violation of the by-laws of the Associated Press, which formed part and parcel of the contract between the parties. The Inter-Ocean Publishing Company admitted, in its bill for injunction, that it had violated its contract, and seemingly, by way of excuse, alleged that it could not obtain all the news from the other contracting party, and so was forced to engage the services' of other news-gathering associations. Answer was filed, and upon hearing had, the bill was dismissed for want of equity,'
1. The by-law and contract created a monopoly.
2. That it was necessary to publish news from other sources to make a check on the defendant.
3. That the by-law tends to restrict competition, because it prevents members from purchasing news from any other source.
4. That the contract and by-law are void as being beyond the power of the defendant to make.
5. That the “obligation (of the defendant) to serve the public is one not resting on contract, but grows out of the fact that it is in the discharge of a public duty, or a private duty, which has been so -conducted that public interest has attached thereto.”
And sixth, that the fact that the defendant possessed the right to use the power of eminent domain as to telegraph and telephone lines, although not exercised, contributed to determine the character of its corporate organization. And on these grounds was based the ruling that the defendant must furnish everyone applying, with the same service of news. The above decision is evidently at war with the rulings in the Live Stock Commission Case, supra, where “the amount of business annually transacted at said stock-yards is such as to constitute the market thus established the largest live-stock market in the world.” If the facts just related did not impress the business with a public use, it is difficult to conceive what facts could do so, and in addition to the utterances heretofore quoted in the Live Stock Commission case, the court there also said: “The views here expressed do not conflict with what was decided in Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113.
That case clearly announces that it is necessary in cases like the present one, that the Legislature should declare that the business “had in fact become impressed with a public use;” something which, as there stated, the courts were powerless to declare. But that case was wholly ignored in the case under comment.
Eor these reasons, besides those already given during the course of this investigation, we decline to follow that case or regard its rulings authoritative.
YU. There is one remaining point to be considered and that relates to the anti-trust laws. . So far as concerns those of Illinois they are not of force in this State, and as to those of the United States, they must be enforced in another forum.
The law on the subject in this State prohibits “any pool, trust, agreement, combination,” etc., “to regulate or fix the price of any article of manufacture, mechanism, merchandise, commodity, convenience, repair, any product of mining, or -any
Nothing is discovered in this section which is at all applicable to the business in which respondent is engaged. Whether we apply to the words of the statute the rule of noscitur a sociis (McNichol v. U. S. Merc. Rep. Ag., 74 Mo. 457); or that of ejusdem generis (State v. Schuchmann, 133 Mo. 111), the result must be the same.
And there is an especial reason why the ruling in this regard should be a strict one, and this is because the statute is highly penal.
Moved by these considerations, we deny the peremptory writ.