29 Minn. 474 | Minn. | 1881
April 15, 1858, the people of Minnesota adopted an amendment to the constitution, providing for the loan to certain railroad companies of bonds of the state, to be denominated “Minnesota State Railroad Bonds,” to the amount of $5,000,000. They were to be payable to the order of the company to whom issued, transferable by the indorsement of the president of the company, and redeemable at any time after ten and before the expiration of twenty-five years from the date thereof, and were to bear interest at the rate of seven per cent, per annum. The faith and credit of the state were, in express terms, pledged for the payment of the interest and the redemption of the principal thereof. The amendment contained provisions for each company securing the state, and making provision for the punctual payment and redemption of the bonds, principal and interest, in such manner as to exonerate the treasury of the state from any advances of money for that purpose. These provisions for security operated only as between the state and the companies to whom the bonds were to be issued, and were not intended to affect the relations between the state and those who might become holders of the
After the default of the companies to perform the conditions in the amendment imposed on them, and after it had become manifest that all intention to proceed with such performance was definitely aban dbned by the companies, the people of the state, on November 6, 3860, by a large vote, adopted two amendments to the constitution proposed to them by the legislature, one of them expunging from the constitution the amendment of April 15, 1858, “excepting and reserving to the state, nevertheless, all rights, remedies, and forfeitures accruing under said amendment.” The other amendment was in these words: “But no law levying a tax, or making other provisions for the payment of interest or principal of the bonds denominated ‘Minnesota State Railroad Bonds’ shall take effect or be in force until such law shall have been submitted to a vote of the people of the state, and (adopted by a majority of the electors of the state voting upon the same.” March 2, 1881, the legislature passed an act, the general purpose of which was to adjust, with the consent of the holders, the bonds outstanding, by taking them up and issuing in lieu of them new bonds of the state, for fifty per cent, of the amount which appeared by their terms to be due upon them. A notable feature of this act is that section 4 proposes the issue of the new bonds without submission to a vote of the people, and section 5 proposes it to be submitted to a vote of the people, the bonds to be issued only upon their ap
■ The writ of prohibition issues usually ,to courts, to keep them within the limits of their jurisdiction. But it may also issue to an officer, to prevent the unlawful exercise of judicial or quasi judicial power ; and, the other reasons for it existing, we see none why it should not issue to a person, or body of persons,- not being in law a court, nor strictly officers; as, if the legislature should assume in an unconstitutional manner to create a court of justice, and the person or persons appointed as its judge or judges should enter upon the exercise of the judicial functions thus attempted to be conferred, the same reasons might exist for arresting their action as exist in the case of a court exceeding its jurisdiction. The exercise of unauthorized judicial or quasi judicial power is regarded as a contempt of the sovereign, which may result in injury to the state or citizens. Three things are essential to justify the writ: First, that the court, officer, or person is about to exercise judicial or quasi judicial power; second, that the exercise of such power by such court, officer, or person is unauthorized by law; third, that it will result in injury for which there is no other adequate remedy.
The act of March 2, 1881, does not attempt to confer on the respondents judicial power in the strict sense of the term. • It submits to their decision a judicial question, and, although their decision upon it could-not have the authoritative and binding force of a decision by a court of justice, yet the act provides for carrying it into effect as though it -were binding, thus giving it a quasi judicial operation.
Before proceeding to a consideration of the main questions involved in the ease, we take pleasure in acknowledging the signal assistance which the arguments of the counsel on both sides have rendered to the court. The discussion took a very wide range, and occupied an unusual time, though not more than was profitably employed, and disclosed the most thorough and minute research and investigation. It has rarely been the good fortune of any court to have a cause before it so ably and exhaustively presented by counsel as this has been.
The basis of the application is the proposition that the act of March 2, 1881, is unconstitutional and void. It is claimed to be unconstitutional for various reasons, only two of which, on account of their superior importance, we think it necessary to consider. We state them in the order of their importance. They are — First, be-cause it is contrary to the amendment to the constitution of November 6, 1860, to the effect that no law levying a tax, or making other provision for payment of the bonds, shall take effect till approved by a vote of the electors of the state; second, because it is an attempt to delegate to the judges legislative power inasmuch as it leaves it for them to determine whether section 4 or section 5 of the act shall be law.
In answer to the first of these positions, the respondents urge that the amendment of 1860, referred to, is itself void, because repugnant to the constitution of the United States. A more important and difficult question has rarely, if ever, come before a court in this country. Courts always regard it a matter of great delicacy to pass on the validity of an act of the legislature. It is much more so when the validity of a constitution adopted by the people of a state is called in question. Yet, when a law of a state is alleged to be contrary to some clause in the constitution of the United States, it is immaterial whether it wras passed by the legislature, or by the people in framing a constitution for themselves. The constitution of the
One of the limitations imposed by the federal constitution is upon the power which it is assumed a state would otherwise have to legislate with respect to contracts. This it does by the clause which declares that no state shall pass any law impairing the obligation of contracts. It may be doubted that any other, single provision of that constitution has had so beneficial and conservative an operation as this inhibition against improvident and unjust legislation, which might affect the life of business throughout the country. By it the great principle was established that contracts shall be inviolable. Sturges v. Crowninshield, 4 Wheat. 122. Probably no provision of the constitution has been more frequently before the courts, or more thoroughly and learnedly discussed, than this. There seems to have been doubt suggested at an early day that the clause applied to contracts made by a state. The question was first raised in the supreme court of the United States, in 1810, in the case of Fletcher v. Peck, 6 Cranch, 87. That was the case of a contract of a state — an executed contract —a grant of lands. The court held that the contract of a state is within the inhibition of the constitution, and said, (page 137:) “Since the constitution uses the general term ‘contract,’ without distinguishing between those which are executory and those which are executed, it must be construed to comprehend the latter as well as the former. ” In Green v. Biddle, 8 Wheat. 1, came in question the validity of two acts of the legislature of Kentucky, which were claimed to impair the obligation of a compact between that state and the state of Virginia. The objection that a contract made by a state is not protected by the constitution against legislation by the state seems to have been made, though, as the court said, it was not much pressed. Referring to the decision in Fletcher v. Peck, the court, (page 92,) said: “The principles laid down in that ease are that the constitution of the United States embraces all contracts, executed or executory, whether between individuals or between a state and individuals; and that a
The relator does not deny that there-may be a contract of a state, the obligation of which the state cannot impair. He admits this as to contracts which are executed, — ras, for instance, grants, — and also admits it as to an executory contract, to enforce which against the state the other party has a perfect judicial remedy. But he claims that executory contracts of a state, which the state cannot be compelled by judicial means to perform, (and this includes all those, the performance of which rests with the legislature, or with some state officer over whom the judiciary has no control in the matter,) have no obligation, within the meaning of the constitution of the United States, and are, therefore, not embraced in its prohibition. His propositions are, in brief, these: First. It is legal obligations, and not merely moral obligations, which the constitution aims to protect.
If it be true that there is no legal obligation to a contract where there is no judicial remedy to compel the defaulting party to perform it, — that is, if the legal obligation and a perfect judicial remedy directly against the party to enforce the contract be synonymous,— then most executory contracts of a state are at the mercy of the state that made them, the bonds here in question are in that predicament, and subject to any legislation the state of Minnesota might choose to make with regard to them. The proposition, if conceded and followed to its necessary logical consequences, will lead to results somewhat startling. State executory contracts to pay, like similar private contracts, are not protected by the federal constitution, except as to the legal obligation. If there be no legal obligation to them, the state that made them may at its pleasure annul them, and there can be no reason why one state cannot annul the executory contracts of another, ■or so legislate as to destroy any market value which they might otherwise have within its jurisdiction. Indeed, they are not in a legal sense contracts (,at all, have no value as such which the law will recognize, are not to be regarded as property, and all the hundreds of millions of federal and state bonds which are regarded as property by the financial world, are in law merely pieces of worthless paper.
What constitutes the legal-obligation of a contract has been much discussed by courts and text-writers almost ever since the adoption of the federal constitution. Some have insisted that it is the judicial remedy given to enforce the contract; that" the legal obligation consists of and is precisely co-extensive with such remedy, and that those agreements from which a judicial remedy is withheld, have merely moral, or, as they are sometimes termed, imperfect obligations. Others have insisted that the legal obligation of the contract is entirely distinct from the remedy to enforce it, and may exist without it. The latter seems to be the opinion recognized in the supreme court of the United States. The acts of state legislatures claimed to impair the
So in the case, put by way of illustration in Ogden v. Saunders, of two men thrown together upon a desert, uninhabited island, and making a contract for exchange of commodities. It is difficult to suppose any one could deny that the duty and obligation of each to do what he had stipulated to do, and the right to demand what the other had stipulated to perform, would be as'complete as though they had made the contract in a country governed by law; yet, so long as they remained on the island, the only remedy either would have to compel performance by the other would be a resort to force. If, however, before the contract was performed, they should both remove to a country governed by law, there would then spring up the judicial remedy provided by the laws of that country upon contracts of that kind.
The cases of Rees v. City of Watertown, 19 Wall. 107, and Meriwether v. Garrett, 102 U. S. 472, present instances where judicial
Mr. Story, in his work on the constitution, gives, as instances of legal obligations existing where there is no judicial remedy to enforce them, the case of a contract by a state, which does not permit its citizens to sue it, with one of its citizens, and of a contract between the United States and one of its citizens, as to which he says no one would doubt their legal obligation. And here we may say that, although there have been before the supreme court of the United States very many cases in which contracts by a state came more or less in question, and in some of which, especially in Railroad Co. v. Tennessee, 101 U. S. 337, and Railroad Co. v. Alabama, Id. 832, it was held there was no judicial remedy to enforce the performance of the contracts, there is no case to which our attention has been called where it was even suggested that a contract of a state has not, within the meaning of the federal constitution, the same legal obligation as a similar contract of an individual. In one of the latest cases before it, it said: “States and cities, when they borrow money and contract to repay it with interest, are not acting as sovereignties. They come down to the level of ordinary individuals. Their contracts have the same meaning as that of similar teontracts between private persons.” Murray v. Charleston, 96 U. S. 432, 445. A citizen may, upon one of its contracts, sue the United States in the court of claims; a state may sue another state for a debt in the supreme court of the United States; some of the states permit suits to be brought by citizens upon claims against them, in their own courts; and in all these cases the courts may proceed to decision and judgment; but the courts
Originally a citizen of one state could sue another state in the supreme court of the United States. This -was decided in an action on a contract, the case being Chisholm v. Georgia, 2 Dallas, 419. If that right to sue had secured a judicial remedy, then, if the proposition of the relator be true, this singular result must follow: that if a state made a contract with one of its citizens it would have no legal obligation, and would not be protected by the federal constitution, be
Thus far we have assumed a judicial remedy upon a contract to imply only a direct judicial proceeding against the party to compel him to perform its stipulations. But the term in its largest sense comprehends something more than this. It comprises, also, judicial protection against invasion by others of the rights vested by the contract. If the rights so vested are such as the law will, in case of such invasion, recognize and jirotect, then there is a judicial remedy belonging to the contract. In the ease of executory contracts with the state, the state might assail the rights of the other party to the contract, either by a suit in disregard of its contract, or in some other
To show how the party contracting with the state might have judicial protection against an attempt by the state through other means than a suit to invade or disregard his rights, suppose the case of a contract by the state to convey land. This state has many such-contracts outstanding. Suppose the state should assume to annul one of these contraetsvand afterwards convey the land to some other person having notice of the first contract. There would be a very complete and effectual judicial remedy in such case for the first purchaser. Many instances like this are to be found in the books. Others than the state might violate the rights acquired under an executory contract with the state. As in case of these bonds, a wrong-doer might convert one of them. In that event, would not the contract of which the bond was the evidence be the reason or occasion for a perfect judicial remedy against the wrong-doer? Would not such contract, rather than the paper on which it was printed, be the chief consideration fixing the damages to be recovered? The bonds are contracts, the obligation of which cannot be impaired by state legislation.
The objection made to the amendment of 1860 is that it impairs the obligation of these contracts; and it is claimed that the power and duty of the legislature to provide by levy of taxes, or by the appropriation of other funds, vested in and imposed on the legislature when the bonds were issued, was the remedy upon them, and the amendment impairs their obligation by destroying the remedy; that the exercise of such power and duty by the legislature having been
It has been insisted on the part of the relator that the only legal remedy there can be to enforce a contract is the judicial remedy; that is, the enforcement of it through proceedings in a court of justice. That is the usual remedy, and the exceptions are so rare that, in speaking of the remedy, the judicial remedy is,usually intended. But there may be other remedies than judicial ones. One of the remedies by act of the party aggrieved, enumerated by Blackstone, book 2, c. 1, is that of distress for rent, which existed at the common law and was regulated by statute, by which the landlord might seize and sell the tenant’s property to enforce payment of the rent. Another non-judicial remedy is the right of a pledgee to sell the property pledged for payment of the debt for which it is pledged. Another is the power of sale contained in mortgages or trust deeds, wdiere they are permitted by the law of the state. This power of sale is not the principal contract. The principal contract in such case is the agreement creating the debt and the security. The power of sale is given only to enforce the debt against the property constituting the security. And, in general, we may say that any means in the hands of the party aggrieved, or of any other person, though not a court, for enforcing performance of a contract, — any mode of enforcing it agreed on by the parties, if recognized and permitted by the law, — is a legal remedy; and where the power of administering a remedy is lodged by law with any person or body, especially if the duty to administer it
The proposition that when the legislature employs its authority to bring about performance of a state contract, it is the state itself which acts, and that the act is therefore voluntary and not remedial, may be stated with as much propriety of the state judiciary when it administers a judicial remedy against the state. For the judiciary is not superior to nor independent of the state. It is, as the legislature is, only a branch or department of the state government. It exercises, as does the legislature, only a part of the sovereign power of the state. It is 'true that the action of the legislature within its proper sphere is the action of the state. But it is equally true of the action of the judicial and executive departments, acting within their respective proper spheres. Though each exercises the sovereign power of the state belonging to its department, neither of them is the state, nor do they all together constitute it. They are the instru-mentalities appointed by the state to govern it — to employ its sovereign power, and control its actions. Nor do the people constitute the state, though it exists for their benefit, and is maintained by their means. A people without any political organization, without any government, is not a state. The people are only an element of the state. When, within prescribed territorial limits, they effect a political organization and establish a government, a state arises. The government is established to protect them frbm external wrong and internal disorder. In this organization and government what is called sovereign power rests. Under American organization it does not all reside in any one department, but is distributed among them, each wielding the portion vested in it, as well against the body of the people as against individuals. Each exercises within its proper
Whether a court may exercise the pqwer entrusted to it against the state, and, if so, to what extent, depends on what the people, in distributing the governmental power by means of the organic law or constitution, deem expedient. To what extent the legislature has entrusted to it power and the duty of administering remedies in favor of state creditors depends also on the same thing. When the legislature, by law, directs the treasurer of the state to pay to its creditors money of the state in the treasury, how does that differ, so far as compelling the state is concerned, from the case of a court, if the public policy of the state permitted it, directing the same officer to pay the same money to the same creditor? Or, if the constitution placed it within the judicial power — and there is no reason, except of expediency, why it might not — to lay and distribute the burden of a state debt upon the taxable property within the state, how, so far as regards compulsion of the state, would the action of the courts in doing .it differ from that of the legislature in levying and distributing a tax upon the same property for the same debt ? In such eases the action of the legislature and the action of the judiciary would be equally compulsive, though in the one case it would be legislative, and in the other judicial, action. That where the legislature acts its commands are executed by one set of officers, and where the judiciary acts its commands are executed by another set, could make no difference so far as the power is to be deemed compulsive or not. The exercise of power to do is always compulsive; so, if judicial ac-. tion in favor of a creditor is a remedy because it is compulsive, legislative action for the same purpose is also, for the same reason, a remedy. It is true, the legislature is independent of the other departments, and there are no means to compel it to perform its duties and exercise its power. It is equally so with the judiciary. Each has its duty to perform. The duty is as imperative upon the one as upon the other. We see no reason, therefore, why the power and duty
It is sometimes difficult to say whether a law operates directly on the contract to change its terms, or upon the remedy to regulate or vary that. It is so here; for it may be a question whether it did not enter into and become a term or condition of the contract, as much as though expressed in the bonds, that the legislature of the state should provide and appropriate money for their payment; and, if there were no other funds available for the purpose, should provide them by the levy and collection of taxes. Of course a state can bind itself to pay money, and it must follow that it can bind itself to provide the funds by the means necessary for that purpose. It may irrevocably bind its taxing power. We are speaking now of the state, not of the legislature. The power of that department to bind the state in the matter of taxation will necessarily depend on the authority conferred on it by the constitution. Its authority in that regard need not be considered here; for, if the taxing power was bound at all in respect to these bonds, it was done by the state in the constitution. A state may, by contract, irrevocably bind itself not to exercise, or may irrevocably limit the exercise of, its power of taxation.
In the case of State of New Jersey v. Wilson, 7 Cranch, 164, the colony of New Jersey, in 1758, by contract, pursuant to an act of its legislature, conveyed certain lands to or for the use of the Delaware tribe of Indians. In the act authorizing the contract it was provided that the lands “shall not hereafter be subject to any tax, any law, usage, or custom to the contrary thereof, in anywise, notwithstanding.” In 1801, an act of the legislature of the state, without mentioning the subject of taxes, authorized the lands tobe sold, and they were accordingly conveyed to other persons. In 1804, the legislature passed an act repealing so much of the act of 1758 as exempted the lands from taxation. The supreme court of the United States con
In the case of the State Bank of Ohio v. Knoop, 16 How. 369, an act of the'legislature of Ohio, passed in 1845, under which the bank was incorporated, provided that any bank incorporated under it should pay to the state semi-annually six per cent, on the net profits of its business, “which sum or amount so set off shall be in lieu of all taxes to which the company, or the stockholders therein, would otherwise be subject.” In 1851, the legislature passed another act, providing that the capital stock of banks incorporated under the laws of the state should be taxed for the same purposes, and to the same extent, that personal property was or might be required to be taxed, in the place where such banks should be located. The effect of this was to increase the rate of tax upon this bank. It was urged in the supreme court of the United States, in support of the right to change the mode and rate of taxation, that the power to tax is a sovereign power, and that a state cannot barter away any part of its sovereign power. But the court held that the exempting of certain property from taxation is not'a relinquishment of a sovereign power, and said, (p. 384:) “The taxing power may select its objects of taxation, and this is generally regulated by the amount necessary to answer the purposes of the state. Now, the exemption of property from taxation is a question of policy and not of power,” and, (p. 390,) “the vague and undefined and indefinable notion that every exemption from taxation or a specific tax, which withdraws certain objects from the general tax law, affects the sovereignty of the state, is indefensible.” The court held a state may, by contract, bind itself in a particular case not to tax, or to do it in a particular way, and, upon the binding force of a contract by the state, quoted with approbation the language of the court in Dartmouth College v. Woodward, and of the supreme court of Ohio, in State v. Com. Bank of Cincinnati, 7 Ohio, 125, 129, that “a contract between the state and individuals is as obligatory as any other contract.” The court, therefore, held that the act of 1845 constituted a contract between the state and the banks, which organ
Dodge v. Woolsey, 18 How. 331, was of a' similar character, except that it presented a case where a constitution, adopted subsequently to the incorporation of the bank under the act of 1845, prescribed a rule of taxation upon such bank different from that agreed upon in that act. The doctrine of the case in 16 Howard was reaffirmed, and it was held that a constitutional provision was equally ineffectual with an' act of the legislature to affect prior contracts of the state. In McGee v. Mathis, 4 Wall. 143, the United States had granted, in 1850, to the state of- Arkansas, swamp and overflowed government lands, on condition that the lands, or the proceeds of them, should be applied in reclaiming the lands for cultivation by means of levees and drains. The state accepted the grant, and its legislature, in 1851, passed an act providing that the lands should be exempt from taxation for ten years, or until they should be reclaimed, and for the sale of them by the issue of transferable scrip, receivable for any of the lands not previously taken up, to be selected by the holder. After the issue of scrip pursuant to the act, another act was passed, in 1855, repealing the section in the act of 1851 which exempted the lands from taxation, and making provision for taxing those sold or to be sold, precisely as other lands; and also, in 1857, another act was passed authorizing a special tax upon the lands. It was held that the act of 1851 constituted a contract between the state and the holders of the scrip issued under it that the lauds should not be taxed for ten years, or until the lands should be reclaimed, and the state could not impair the contract by subsequent legislation, and the repeal of the exemption was void.
There are many other cases in the reports of the decisions of the supreme court of the United States involving the same question, and in all of them the rules laid down in the cases we have specifically referred to were followed. Although some of the judges have expressed doubts on the power of a legislature, by virtue merely of its general legislative authority, to make an irrevocable contract binding the state not to exercise, or limiting its exercise of, the taxing power, that the state can make such contract, and that wdien made it is
The proposition that, a state may, by contract with an individual, obligate itself beyond its power of revocation to abstain from use of its taxing power, would seem to require the converse, that it may likewise so obligate itself to use that power. There is no ease that we are aware of where the question arose whether the state, as an entirety, in its organized capacity as a body politic, may be so bound. Those which come nearest to it are the cases of municipal corporations. These bodies are subdivisions or instrumentalities of the state government, established for the administration of the government in matters of local concern, and vested with a portion of the sovereignty of the state, to be exercised in such matters. In respect to these subdivisions of the state, where they have the power of taxation to meet the demands of contracts, they may, by entering into such contracts, not only bind themselves to exercise the power, but bind the state, so that it cannot withdraw the power till the contracts are satisfied.
In the case of Von Hoffman v. City of Quincy, 4 Wall. 535, the legislature of Illinois authorized the city of Quincy to issue its bonds, bearing interest, and to levy and collect a special annual tax upon the property within the city sufficient to pay the annual interest upon the bonds which should be issued. The tax was to be applied to payment of the interest, and to no other purpose whatsoever. The bonds were issued, and subsequently, in 1863, the legislature passed an act wdiich repealed all former laws touching the levy or collection of taxes on property within the city, except those regulating the collection and as to taxes relating to streets and alleys, and which prescribed the
In City of Galena v. Amy, 5 Wall. 705, the same principle was recognized.
In United States v. New Orleans, lately decided, an abstract of the decision being given in 13 Chi. Leg. News, 207,
The principle was recognized in United States v. County Court, in the United States circuit court for the eastern district of Missouri, 2 Fed. Rep. 1. The court said: “A legislative act which assumes to repeal any tax law in force when relator’s bond was issued, and under
There is, of course, always a difficulty in comprehending the idea of any one, state, municipality, or individual, being bound, where . there is no external power to maintain and enforce the obligation. In the case of municipalities and of individuals, it is easy to concede that they are bound, because the judicial power extends to them; and it is so of a state obligation, whenever it comes before a court to maintain it. But of those state obligations which can be carried out only by legislation, which can rarely be brought within the reach of judicial power, and never directly for the purpose of compelling their performance, it is more difficult to conceive a power external to the state which may enforce them. The difficulty, more apparent than real, arises from confounding the state with one of the departments of its government, the legislative, which department the state has appointed to enforce state obligations in certain cases. As soon as it is understood that the legislature is not the state any more than the judiciary is, and that, like the judiciary, there is entrusted to it the power, in cases coming within its proper sphere, of enforcing state obligations, the difficulty of accepting the idea that there is a binding force to such obligations ceases. Whenever any undertaking of the state — as, for instance, the undertaking to use the taxing power —comes in question before a court, it is the province and duty of the court to recognize it, and, so far as required by the case before it, to maintain its integrity. But it is ordinarily the province and duty of the legislative department to directly enforce the obligation in the first instance, and of the courts to sustain its action, when its validity comes in question in a case properly before them. As, in the case before us, if there was a binding obligation of the state to use the power of appropriation and taxation, and if the amendment of 1860
Having reached the conclusion that there rests on the state a legal obligation to perform its contracts; that, where the power and duty to bring about performance of them are in the legislative department, there is a legislative remedy, the destruction of which may impair the obligation of the contract, as the taking away a remedy within the power of the judiciary may; and that the state may, by contract, disable itself to abolish or fetter the pow'er of legislative appropriation and taxation, where they constitute the means to perform its contracts, it remains to be considered: Did the state, by its contract with the bondholders, bind itself to leave the power in the ordinary legislative body? and did the amendment of 1860 lessen the value of the creditors’ remedy, when it removed the pow'er of providing for payment of the bonds from the ordinary legislative department, and remitted it to the electors at large? And here we may refer to a suggestion which has been made, that the undertaking of the state was general to pay the money, and was not a promise to employ any particular means for payment, — for instance, taxation, — and that legislation affecting only particular means of payment, or a particular mode of payment, does not impair the integrity of the general promise to pay. The amendment takes from the legislature the power to employ any means of payment, by taxation or otherwise. Even though the treasury might have in it millions of unappropriated and unneeded funds, it could not, according to the amendment, pay a cent of such funds upon this debt. The proposition would be absurd that a legislative act leaves a contract to pay money unaffected, if it do not prohibit the debtor to pay, but only disables him to employ the only means through which he can pay. The debtor’s promise to pay is usually general; it is rarely a promise to pay only from a particular fund, as from his personal property, or from his real estate. But could any one say that a law which should put it out of his pow'er to appropriate his personal property, or his real estate, to pay a gen
At the time the bonds here in question were issued, the constitution of the state — the same instrument pursuant to which they were issued — provided, (section 2, art. 9:) “The legislature shall provide for an annual tax sufficient to defray the estimated expenses of the state for each year; and whenever it shall happen that such ordinary expenses of the state for any year shall exceed the income of the state for such year, the legislature shall, provide-for levying a tax for the ensuing year, sufficient, with other sources of income, to pay the deficiency of the preceding year, together with- the estimated expenses of such ensuing year.” We do not regard it as of special importance, as relates to the question now before ns, that this power and duty of the legislature are expressed in the constitution; for, had they not been expi’essed, they would, in the absence of words excluding the implication, have been implied. But the section was there when the bonds were issued; and, in respect to the power and duty on the part of the legislature thus expressed, counsel for the respondents argue that among the expenses which the legislature was thus directed to provide for, was the annually-accruing interest, and ultimately the principal, of these bonds; but, as the state had no other reliable source of income except through taxation, the parties — the state and the receivers of the bonds — must have looked to and intended taxation as directed by the constitution, to wit, through the legislature, as the means through which the interest and principal of the bonds •were to be paid; that is, that it amounted to a contract that the legislature should provide by taxation to pay the bonds, and that such contract is as unimpairable by the state as the contracts, in the cases
Was it a contract that this power and duty should remain in the legislature ? The decision of this question involves the same consideration as is involved in the question, whether, treating the power and duty then in the legislature as a then-existing remedy for the bondholders, taking it away or changing it, as provided in the amendment of 1860, lessens the value of the obligation to pay the sums.stipulated in the bonds. For, no agreement to leave with the legislature the power and duty to provide for payment of the bonds being expressed, it would not be implied, unless essential to the better fulfillment of the contract on the part of the state. It would not be implied, if it might be regarded as indifferent to the bondholders whether the power and duty remained in the ordinary legislative department of the state, or was vested elsewhere; and, regarding it only as a remedy, there would be no legal objection to the state taking it away, providing it substituted an equally effectual one in its stead; for it is the substance and effectiveness, and not the mere forms of remedies, which must be preserved.
Though the obligation of the contract is distinct from the remedy to enforce it, and the two ought not to be confounded, yet they are so nearly connected that a law lessening the force of the remedy must necessarily affect the value of the obligation. The inhibition of the federal constitution being absolute, it operates to prevent any attempt, either direct, against the contract, or indirect, against the remedy, to impair the obligation of contracts. A law affecting the remedy, if it lessen the value of the obligation, is equally void with one which does so by operating directly on the contract. “One of the
If the natural effect of so removing the power and duty from the legislature would be to render the payment of the bonds less certain than if the legislature should retain the power to provide for such payment, then it may safely be implied that such removal would be contrary to the then intentions of the parties, the state and the receivers of the bonds; and it is also clear that it impaired the obligation of the contracts by baking away a then-existing remedy, without giving an equally efficient one instead. • We are relieved in this case from any necessity to consider how far a state may go, and to what extent remedies may be rendered less speedy or convenient, when, upon considerations of public policy and expediency, and consulting the general public good, it changes its laws or its constitution, or mode of administering its government. - The power to .make such changes from such motives, even though they incidentally affect existing contracts of the state or individuals, may b'e conceded. But any supposed advantage to the state of repudiating its debts, or of obstructing its creditors in respect to their payment, can never be admitted as a consideration of public policy or expediency, or of good to the public, which will justify a change. If it might, it would apply equally to all state contracts, executory or executed, and indeed to all contracts between individuals, and the clause in the federal constitution could thus be successfully evaded. It is apparent, upon the face of this amendment, that the only motive operating in its adoption was the intent to affect these bonds. If the effect of the amendment was to prevent or postpone or obstruct their payment, that, and no consideration of general public policy, was the motive of its adoption. It must, therefore, stand or fall, according as it af
The idea of remedy in the hands of any one but the aggrieved party implies the right to make application to the body or person in whose power the remedy is, to set it in motion. Thus, judicial remedy necessarily includes the right to apply to a court, and show reasons why the remedy should be made available. And a legislative remedy, or one within the power of the legislature, includes the right in the party entitled to it to present his case to that body, and demand its action in his behalf. It requires no argument to-show that such a right is of value, for the application of the remedy may depend upon it. To take away the right, or, what would be the same in affect, to deprive him of an opportunity to exercise it, would certainly affect seriously the value and efficiency of his remedy.
It may be assumed that, with the same opportunity in the bondholders to fully present their'claims to the people, and in the people to properly investigate, deliberate upon, and decide the justice of the claims, the people would grant,the relief to which the holders were entitled as readily as the legislature would. When the bonds were issued, the holders had a right to apply for relief to the legislature, and there was no difficulty in the way of exercising the right. The legislature is small in numbers, select, its members supposed to be
The objection that the act of March 2, 1881, attempts to delegate-legislative power, requires a reference to several sections of the act ,to ascertain what is referred to the judges to decide, what effect is given to their decision, and what is made to depend upon their decision.
Section 2 constitutes the judges of the supreme court a tribunal (the places of those judges disqualified or declining to act to be filled, as provided in section 8, by the governor appointing judges of the district courts) to hear, consider, and determine the matters submitted to them by the act'. Section 2 provides: “Said judges shall hear arguments, determine and decide whether the legislature has power to provide for the payment, adjustment, or settlement of the liability of the state on said Minnesota state railroad bonds without submitting the matter to a vote of the electors of the state, notwithstanding the amendment to section 2, article 9, of the constitution, adopted November 6, 1860.” It appoints a time and place for them ■to meet, and for filing their decision with the clerk of the supreme-court. Section 4 provides that the clerk of the court, as soon as the decision shall be filed with him, shall prepare and file with the state auditor a certified copy of such decision, and it proceeds: “If the decision be against the validity of such constitutional amendment, or that the legislature has power to provide for the settlement of said bonds without submission to the people, then it shall be the duty of
It then provides the mode for submitting it to the people-, and of voting on it. Section 6 provides for the tribunal computing and reporting the amount due on certain judgments, and the payment by the state in the new bonds, or in money, of fifty per cent, of such amount. Section 7 provides for the tribunal ascertaining and reporting upon claims for work, labor, or services performed, or for provisions, boarding of contractors, workmen, or others, or for material or supplies of any kind furnished and actually used in the location and construction of either or any part of the lines of railroad of the land-grant railroad companies which received said state railroad bonds from the state, which occurred prior to the time when the state acquired and transferred said lines of railroad, and for the payment, within a stated aggregate amount, of fifty per cent, of such claims in money or the now bonds. Section 9 establishes a fund for the payment of the interest on the new bonds.
It is a principle not questioned that, except where authorized by the constitution, as in respect to municipalities, the legislature cannot delegate legislative power; cannot confer on any body or person the power to determine what shall be the law. The legislature only must determine what it shall be. The courts only must authorita
It is not questioned that within certain limits the operation of a legislative act may be made to depend on a future contingency; upon
While some of the members of the court do not entirely agree with some of the reasoning in the opinion, yet they all concur in these' conclusions, viz.: First, that the constitutional amendment of November 6, 1860, providing that “no law levying a tax or making, other provision for the payment of interest or principal of the bonds denominated ‘ Minnesota state railroad bonds’ shall take effect or be in force until such law shall have been submitted to a vote of the people, and adopted by a majority of the electors of the state voting on the same, ” is invalid, for the reason that it impairs the obligation of those bonds; second, that the act of March 2, 1881, is unconstitutional and void, because it delegates legislative power to the tribunal created by it; third, that a writ of prohibition should issue.
Let the writ of prohibition absolute issue, and be served by any elector of the state on or before the 18th day of September, 1881.