55 W. Va. 642 | W. Va. | 1904
On the first day of May, 1895, there were four coal companies, ■corporations, operating in what is known as The Thacker Coal Yein in Mingo County. They were The Thacker Coal and Coke Company, The Lynn Coal and Coke Company, The Logan Consolidated Coal Company and the Maritime Coal Company. On said date another corporation was organized, called The Thacker Coal Company. Its capital stock paid in was $640.00, and the principal stockholders were the Presidents of The Thacker Coal and Coke Company, The Lynn Coal and Coke Company and
On said first day of May, 1895, said agent corporation entered into a contract with The Thacker Coal and Coke Co. whereby it' agreed to sell for said company, for the period of five years, not less than 20,000 tons of coal each year, or, in default thereof, to pay The Thacker Coal and Coke Co. twenty cents per ton for so much coal as it should fail to sell, in case it did fail to sell the amount stipulated. From the proceeds the agent company was to deduct and retain as compensation ten cents per ton. The Thacker Coal and Coke Co. covenanted to deliver to the agent company as much coal as it could sell, not exceeding, however, 84,000 tons each year. It was further agreed that, if the mining ■company should fail to deliver coal according to the agreement, it should pay the agent company ten cents per ton for coal not delivered, as compensation or liquidated damages. It was further provided that either party might terminate the agreement at the end of any year by giving sixty days notice prior thereto, April 1st being the beginning of the year fixed in the contract. The prices at which the coal was to be sold were fixed in the agreement and it was further provided that they should be adhered to by the agent company unless departure therefrom should be authorized by a minute signed by all parties producing coal from said vein for whom the said agent company should act as agent. The agent company was réquired to account for, and pay over, the proceeds of sales on or before the 15th day of each month. The general nature of the agent company’s business, as set forth in the’contract, was the! selling, advertising and introducing of Thacker coal, and it had authority to adjust and settle complaints made by consumers and to select and appoint all sub-agents for the sale of said coal.
Under this contract the agent company sold for the three pro
The agent company continued until the 31st day of July, 1896 •to handle the coal of the other two companies. On that date, The Thacker Coal and Coke Co., or Moore, with the aid of parties representing The Lynn Coal and Coke Company interest or having purchased that interest, at a meeting after due notice, -passed a resolution dissolving the agent corporation and appointing a trustee to wind up the business. This was followed by a chancery suit in which the assets of the defunct corporation were 'collected by W. P. Slaughter, special receiver and paid out pro rata on its indebtedness, the amount realized by the corporations being fifty-four cents on the dollar. The heavy creditors •were the three producing coal companies, the amounts due them 'having been as follows: The Thacker Coal and Coke Co., $2,702.-34, for coal sold prior to May 22d; The Lynn Coal and Coke Co., ’$977.38, for-coal sold probably in June and July; The Logan Consolidatel Coal Company, $1,166.89, for coal probably sold in July. The other indebtedness consisted of small amounts due to various persons, making the total indebtedness $5,164.14, while •'the total assets amounted to- $3,951.71.
In said chancery suit, upon petition of the Logan Company, .an order was made directing Slaughter, special receiver, to use The Thacker Coal and Coke Company for the damages claimed on account of the breach of the contract. In pursuance thereof, -this action of assumpsit was,brought. In addition to the common counts the declaration contains a special count on the contract. A demurrer was interposed and overruled and there was a verdict and judgment for the defendant, and the plaintiff com- ■ plains of that judgment.
Under Pule 10 of this Court, the defendant cross-assigns error •in the overruling of the demurrer. I am of the opinion that this assigment is well taken. But for section 10 of chapter 99 of the • Code, an action of assumpsit would not lie upon any sealed instrument. Under it, such action does lie upon a promise, undertaking or obligation in such instrument for the payment of
For the plaintiff in error it is said there is no evidence against his right to recover, but it is insisted for the defendant in error that the judgment cannot be disturbed far two reasons. The first is, that the contract was entered into by the parties for the-purpose of destroying competition and is in restraint of trade, and, therefore, void as against public policy. In this connection it is shown that while the stock of the agent corporation stood ir. the name of Graham, Moore and Kirk, presidents of the three-producing companies, it was taken in their names for convenience and paid for by the coal companies, and further that an effort was made by these companies to get the Maritime Coall Co. to join them. Unless this contract is within the inhibition of the Act of Congress of July 2, 1890, declaring illegal every contract and combination in the form of trust or otherwise or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states or with foreign nations, it is not necessarily illegal. Although on its face it carries an apparent tendency to stifle competition and is, in that sense, in restraint of trade, it is not illegal by reason of that act unless it affects commerce among the-several states or with foreign nations. United States v. Freight Association, 166 U. S., 290, 325. This contract relates simply to the sale of the output of one mine, but it appears from the-evidence in the case that the agent corporation was organized for the purpose of handling the output of all the companies operating in a certain vein or seam of coal, and that two other companies had contracts with it like, or similar to, the contract with the defendant company. But it does not appear that this coal'
In Skrainke v. Scharringhausen, 8 Mo. App., 522, the contract under consideration, very much like this one, was held goad. 'The owners of certain stone quarries entered into an agreement to secure "a fair, proportionate sale of the product of all quarries at uniform prices and living rates.” the terms of the agreement restricting the production of stone witbin certain territory, putting the sales in the hands of an agent for the interest of ail parties, appointing a committee of five persons to modify prices and settle complaints, and imposing a penalty for every sale made in violation of the agreement. It is not intended here to affirm the correctness of the decision, but it illustrates the view taken by certain courts and shows that much latitude is allowed to manufacturers and producers of commodities in arrangments for facilitating production and sale. In Diamond Match Co. v. Roeber, 106 N. Y. 473, Andrews, Judge, said: "In the present state of the authorities, we think it cannot be said that the early doctrine that contracts in general restraint of trade are void, without regard to circumstances, has been abrogated. But it is manifest that it has been much weakened, and that the foundation upon which it was originally placed has, to a considerable extent at least, by the change of circumstances, been removed.” Another interesting case is that of Central Shade Roller Co. v. Cushman, 143 Mass. 353. In that case the contract was one made by three manufacturers of a certain kind of curtain fixtures, under 'different letters patent, owned by them severally, for the purpose of avoiding competition. It was held valid. In Cohen v. Berlin-Jones Envelope Co., 59 N. Y. S. 588; manufacturers of envelopes, made a contract with another envelope manufacturer by which they agreed to purchase from him, at prices to be fixed from time to time by the former, a stated quantity of goods manufactured by him during a stated period, and he agreed that, during such time, he would not sell to others at a less price. Nineteen other concerns throughout the country, engaged in
In Horner v. Graves, 7 Bing. 735, Tindall, C. J., said: “We do not see how a better test can be applied to the question, whether reasonable or not, than by considering whether the restraint is •.such only as to afford a fair protection to the interest of the party in favor of whom it is given, and not so large as to interfere with the interest of the public. Whatever restraint is larger than the necessary protection of the party, can be of no benefit to either. It can only be oppressive, and if oppressive, -.it is, in the eye of the law, unreasonable. Whatever is injurious to the interests of the public, is void, on the ground of public ■policy.”
Applying here this test and the general principles recognized in Cohen v. Berlin-Jones Envelope Co., it is impossible'to see how the public was? or could have been, injured by this contract. Three small companies, out of the vast number of coal producing - companies in this State, entered into it. The quantity of coal put upon the market by them is an utterly insignificant portion of the vast quantities thrown upon the market by the numerous ■competing producers.:. In the absence of some great combination, j virtually controlling the production and price of a commodity in ' . - the country, the price is regulated and determined by tbe law of \ supply and demand, r It is manifest that, by this agreement, the • production of these three mines was facilitated and increased rather than stifled or curtailed. If their operation can be said ■ to have affected the price of coal to the consumer, it is perfectly ■ clear that the tendency was' to reduce instead of increase it, be- • cause that advantageous arrangement for the sale of their output - enabled them to put upon the market increased quantities of ■ coal. The validity of this contract must be determined by its
Upon this view of the contract, my inclination is to hold it • legal, but my associates are of a different opinion. Applying the- - principles hereinafter stated, they consider it void, as against ..public policy.
“By the weight of recent authority the character of the article - or legitimate trade sought to be monopolized is immaterial, the true test of the illegality of the combination being the injury to' ■ the public, and whether its necessary consequence is to control prices, limit production, or suppress competition in such a way as to restrain trade and create a monopoly. To render the combination illegal on this ground, it is not necessary that evil intent ■ or actual injury be shown, but it is sufficient to know that the inevitable tendency of the act is injurious to the public. The fact: that the immediate result of the combination has been temporarily to reduce prices, or that it may reduce them, is immaterial in determining the legality of the combination, the court not being • governed by the temporary effect upon the prices, but by the - power of the combination to control them.” SO Am. & Eng. . Ency. Law (Sd Ed.) 849, 850.
Discussing the rule stated by Tindal, C. J., in Horner v. Graves, 7 Bing. 735, and hereinbefore quoted, Judge Taft said,in United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 Fed. Rep.. 271: “This very statement of the rule implies that the contract must be one in which there is a main purpose, to which the covenant in restraint of trade is merely ancillary. The covenant is-inserted only to protect one of the parties from the injury which,, in the execution of the contract or enjoyment of its fruits, he-may suffer from the unrestrained competition of the other. The-main purpose of the contract suggests the measure of protection! needed, and furnishes a sufficiently uniform standard by which the validity of such restraints may be judicially determined. In' such a case, if the restraint exceeds the necessity presented by the main purpose of the contract, it is void for two reasons: First, because it oppreses the covenantor, without any corresponding benefit to the covenantee; and, second, because it tends to a monopoly. But where the sole object of both parties in making the contract as expressed therein is merely to restrain competition, and enhance or maintain prices, it would seem that there was nothing to justify or excuse the restraint, that it would necessarily have a tendency to monopoly, and therefore would be void. In such a case there is no measure of what is necessary to the protection of either party except the vague and varying opinion of judges as to how much, on principles of political economy, men ought to be allowed to restrain competition. There is in such contracts no main lawful purpose to subserve which partial restraint is permitted, and by which its reasonableness is measured, but the sole object is to restrain trade in order to avoid the competition which it has always been the policy of the common law to foster.”
Affirmed.