86 P. 150 | Kan. | 1906
The opinion of the court was delivered by
The validity of chapter 487 of the Laws of 1903, relating to stock-yards, is the principal question raised by the pleadings and the decision of the trial court. That act declares and defines what shall constitute public stock-yards, the duties of those operating them, and prescribes maximum charges for the use of the yards and for the facilities and services furnished, viz.: For cattle fifteen cents per head, calves eight cents per head, hogs six cents per head, and sheep four cents per head. There is also contained in the act a regulation of the sale of dead animals, and it finally provides that a violation of its provisions shall be deemed a misdemeanor, the penalties prescribed being a fine of not more than $100 for the first conviction; for a second conviction a fine of not less than $100 nor more than $200; for a third conviction a fine of not less than $200 nor more than $500 and imprisonment in the county jail for not more than six months; and for each subsequent offense there is imposed a fine, of not less than '$1000 and imprisonment in the county jail not less than six months.
The first and main contention is that the Wichita stock-yards company is strictly a private corporation, engaged in a purely private business, with full liberty of contract, and is therefore not subject to legislative regulation and control. The state has conferred on the defendant the right to exist as a corporation and to exercise the chartered privileges which ordinarily go with incorporation, but no special franchises or rights have been conferred upon it by'either the state or the city of Wichita.
As to corporations which are gwsi-public in character and in behalf of which the power of eminent domain is exercised — those .upon which special privileges have been conferred — there is no dispute. It is conceded by all that these are so far affected with a public interest as to be subj ect to reasonable regulation and control by the state. But is the enjoyment of special rights and powers conferred by the public the test as to whether a business is impressed with a public interest? Many kinds of business carried on without special franchises or privileges are treated as- public in character, and have therefore been subjected to legislative regulation and control. The nature and extent of the business, the fact that it closely touches a great many people, and.that it may afford opportunities for imposition and oppression, as in' cases of monopoly and the like, are circumstances affecting property with a public interest. Police regulations of the business of dealing in patent-rights have been
Public necessity and the public welfare are the broad general grounds upon which the right of legislative control is based, rather than that a special privilege has been conferred in consideration of which public control is conceded or required. In Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113, 24 L. Ed. 77, Chief Justice Waite, referring to the right to regulate business under the police power, said: “The government regulates the conduct of its citizens one toward another, .and the manner in which each shall use his own property, whén such regulation becomes necessary for the public good.” (Page 125.) Upon these considerations the business of banking has been subjected to control, and the right to regulate the interest which may be charged for the use of money is now unquestioned. The police power is exercised in controlling the business of insurance, the operation of mills, hotels, theaters, wharves, markets, warehouses for the storage of grain and tobacco, common carriers, the collection and distribution of news, and the business of supplying and distributing water and gas. Some of these rest upon considerations of health, or the safety or the convenience of the people, but all fall within the general grounds of public necessity and public welfare. •
In LaHarpe v. Gas Co., 69 Kan. 97, 76 Pac. 448, it was declared that “the production and distribution of natural gas for light, fuel and power affect the people generally to such an extent that the business may be regarded as one of a public nature, and is almost, if not quite, a public necessity, the control of which belongs to the state.” (Page 100.) That business has the element of transportation, although it includes other elements which affect it with a public interest. The supreme court of the United States has also said, with reference to the regulation of a water company: “That
Since the decision of the public-elevator cases by the supreme court of the United States there is little room for contention that the business of operating stockyards like those at the city of Wichita is not affected with a public interest, nor within the scope of legislative regulation. In Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113, 24 L. Ed. 77, it was expressly decided that a warehouseman who receives and stores grain for compensation is engaged in a business of a public nature; that the public has an interest in the use to which he devotes his property; and that for the public good he must submit to public control. Although this decision met with a strong dissent and much protest, it has been affirmed and reaffirmed by the same court, and the principle upon which it rests has been recognized in a multitude of that court’s decisions. (Budd v. New York, 143 U. S. 517, 12 Sup. Ct. 468, 36 L. Ed. 247; Brass v. Stoeser, 153 U. S. 391, 14 Sup. Ct. 857, 38 L. Ed. 757; W. W. Cargill Co. v. Minnesota, 180 U. S. 452, 21 Sup. Ct. 423, 45 L. Ed. 619; Cotting v. Kansas City Stock-yards Co., &c., 183 U. S. 79, 22 Sup. Ct. 30, 46 L. Ed. 92.) These decisions are conclusive authority upon the questions arising under the federal constitution, and following them it must be held that the stock-yards business, as conducted at Wichita, is impressed with a public interest, and therefore subject to reasonable statutory control.
The operation of stock-yards has more of the characteristics of a public business than the carrying on of an elevator or a warehouse. It possesses the market features, including considerations of sanitation and health, and it also has more of the monopolistic features. The stock-yards in question are situated in a commercial center, and constitute the public live-stock
In Cotting v. Kansas City Stock-yards Co., 82 Fed. 850, it was held that “a stock-yard business, located in a large city, at the junction of many railroad lines, which furnishes the only proper facilities for the unloading, resting and feeding of live stock in transit, and for the sale of cattle within said city, is affected with a public use, so as to be subject to legislative control, and the proper legislative body may prescribe a maximum rate of compensation for the care and handling of stock thereat.” (Syllabus.) This case was taken to the supreme court of the United States, where it was reversed because of a discriminatory provision of the statute under consideration. ■ In determining
“Tested by the rule laid down in Mwnn v. Illinois, it may be conceded that the state has the power to make reasonable regulation of the charges for services rendered by the stock-yards company. Its stock-yards are situated in one of the gateways of commerce, and so located that they furnish important facilities to all seeking transportation of cattle. While not a common carrier, nor engaged in any distinctively public employment, it is doing a work in which the public has an interest, and, therefore, must be considered as subject to governmental regulation.” (Cotting v. Kansas City Stock-yards Co., &c., 183 U. S. 79, 85, 22 Sup. Ct. 30, 46 L. Ed. 92.)
In Delaware, &c., R. R. Co. v. The Central Stockyard Co., 45 N. J. Eq. 50, 17 Atl. 146, 6 L. R. A. 855, the court discussed the nature of-the business, and held that the business of maintaining stock-yards corresponds with that of warehousemen, and therefore is subject to the same general principles of law. It was held, however, that in the absence of a statute a court of chancery could not impose regulations upon those engaged in the business without usurping legislative power.
In Stock Exchange v. Board of Trade et al., 127 Ill. 153, 19 N. E. 855, 2 L. R. A. 411, 11 Am. St. Rep. 107, it was held that the market quotations and reports of the board of trade of Chicago had become affected with a public interest, and so long as it continued in business it must furnish reports and quotations to all who may desire them for lawful purposes, • and upon the same terms. In a later case before the same court it . was held that the Chicago Live Stock Exchange could not be treated as a public market in the ordinary sense, but in the course of the decision it was said that the character and magnitude of its business was such as “to warrant the legislature, in the exercise of its legis
We conclude that the stock-yards business as conducted in Wichita is clothed with a public interest, and that the state in the exercise of its police power may, within constitutional limitations, subject it to regulation and control.
Having determined that it is competent for the legislature to regulate the business of maintaining stockyards, there is little left of this controversy. It is conceded that the power of prescribing maximum charges for the use of property, including the things and services furnished by the company, is not without limit. While the fixing of rates in such cases is a legislative function, the regulation must be reasonable, and so it has been held that those‘carrying on a business aifeeted with a public interest cannot be required to give the use of their property or to perform services without reward, nor to suffer that which would amount to the taking of private property without just compensation or due process of law. It has been said that the court will grant relief against legislation fixing rates for a public-service corporation which are so unreasonable as practically to destroy the value of the property used in the business. (St. L. & San Francisco Railway
“It is unnecessary to decide, and we do not wish to be understood as laying down as an absolute rule, that in every case a failure to produce some profit to those who have invested their money in the building of a road is conclusive that the tariff is unjust and unreasonable. And yet justice demands that every one should receive some compensation for the use of his money or property, if it be possible without prejudice to the rights of others.” (Reagan v. Farmers’ Loan & Trust Co., 154 U. S. 362, 412, 14 Sup. Ct. 1047, 38 L. Ed. 1014.)
Again, it has been held that when the question arises it is the duty of'the courts to take into consideration the interests of both the public and the owner of the property devoted to a public use, and determine whether the legislative rates as an entirety are so unjust as practically to destroy the value of the property for all the purposes for which it was acquired. (Covington, &c., Turnpike Co. v. Sandford, 164 U. S. 578, 17 Sup. Ct. 198, 41 L. Ed. 560.) It has been often declared that the basis for testing reasonableness of rates charged under legislative sanction must be the fair value of the property in use. (Smyth v. Ames, 169 U. S. 466, 546, 18 Sup. Ct. 418, 42 L. Ed. 819; San Diego Land Company v. National City, 174 U. S. 739, 757, 19 Sup. Ct. 804, 43 L. Ed. 1154; Cotting v. Kansas City Stock-yards Co., &c., 183 U. S. 79, 22 Sup. Ct. 30, 46 L. Ed. 92.)
The extent to which the courts may interfere with rates established by the legislature is a subject upon which there is a diversity of opinion, and which has not been definitely settled by the supreme court of the United States. In one of the later cases it was said:
“But it should also be remembered that the judiciary ought not to interfere with the collection of rates established under legislative sanction unless they are so plainly and palpably unreasonable as to make their enforcement equivalent to the taking of property for public usé without such compensation as under all the cir*13 cumstances is just both to the owner and to the public; that is, judicial interference should never occur unless the case presents, clearly and beyond all doubt, such a flagrant attack upon the rights of property under the guise of regulations as to compel the court to say that the rates prescribed will necessarily have the effect to deny just compensation for private property taken for the public use.” (San Diego Land Company v. National City, 174 U. S. 739, 754, 19 Sup. Ct. 804, 43 L. Ed. 1154.)
In Cotting v. Kansas City Stock-yards Co., &c., 183 U. S. 79, 22 Sup. Ct. 30, 46 L. Ed. 92, it was said:
“What shall be the test of reasonableness in those charges is absolutely undisclosed. As to parties engaged in performing a public service, while the power to regulate has been sustained, negatively the court has held that the legislature may not prescribe rates which, if enforced, would amount to a confiscation of property. But it has not held affirmatively that the legislature may enforce rates which stop only this side of confiscation and leave the property in the hands and under the care of the owners without any remuneration for its use. It has declared that the present value of the property is the basis by which the test of reasonableness is to be determined, although the actual cost is to be considered, and that the value of the services rendered to each individual is also to be considered. It has also ruled that the determination of the legislature is to be presumed to be just, and must be upheld unless it clearly appears to result in enforcing unreasonable and unjust rates.” (Page 91.)
In this case it was suggested in the argument that the rates are such as to warrant judicial interference. The answer of the defendant, however, does not fairly raise the question, and the pleader appears to have carefully avoided the making of allegations which would bring the case within the rule of the federal decisions. It is -averred that the charges imposed are the customary charges at other stock-yards; that they are no more than a just, fair and reasonable compensation for the facilities and labor furnished and for the services rendered; and that any less charges would be
“Defendant therefore avers that whether the intrinsic value and worth of the services rendered by it for its aforesaid charges are considered, or whether those charges are compared with the charges made for services rendered by others in connection with such live stock, or for services somewhat similar rendered to other animals, its aforesaid charges are reasonable and fair in themselves, no more than made for similar services at other yards, and are the usual and customary charges everywhere; and that any less charges will be inadequate and insufficient compensation lor the facilities and service furnished and rendered, md would not afford defendant any compensation -whatever for some of such facilities and services.”
But these averments fall short of alleging that the rates imposed by the legislature are so unreasonable and unjust as to amount to the taking of property without jus.t compensation. It does not' allege and show, as Mr. Justice Harlan remarked, “clearly and beyond all doubt, such a flagrant attack upon the rights of property under the guise of regulations as to compel the court to say that the rates prescribed will necessarily have the effect to deny just compensation for private property taken for the public use.” (San Diego Land Company v. National City, 174 U. S. 739, 754, 19 Sup. Ct. 804, 43 L. Ed. 1154.) The fact that the legislative rates for some services and facilities or for all services and facilities furnished are unreasonable is not enough. The rates prescribed by law, as well as those charged by defendant, are so much per animal handled, and this includes the use of the property devoted to the purpose as well as the services and facilities furnished. The question is, as was said in Covington, &c., Turnpike Co. v. Sandford, 164 U. S. 578, 17 Sup. Ct. 198, 41 L. Ed. 560, whether the legislative rates are, as an entirety, so unreasonable and unjust as to destroy the value of the property devoted to the public use, or to deprive the
“It is sufficient, however, for the purpose of this case to say that the action of the commission in fixing the rate complained of as to this particular class of freight has not been shown to be so unjust or unreasonable as to amount to a taking of property without due process of law, and we therefore conclude • that the judgment of the supreme court must be affirmed.” (Minneapolis & St. Louis Rld. Co. v. Minnesota, 186 U. S. 257, 268, 22 Sup. Ct. 900, 46 L. Ed. 1151.)
The statement that the company is only charging, such rates as are customary in other stock-yards is certainly not the equivalent of allegations to the effect that a less charge would practically destroy the property and money employed in the business, or deprive the owner of it without due process of law.
How far the .legislature may go in limiting compensation which corporations engaged in a business clothed with a public interest may charge before it may be regarded as the taking of property without just compensation or due process of law is an important question. May the courts interfere if there is just some reward on the value of the property in use? Or are the owners of the property entitled to a substantial reward — such returns as are ordinarily received on property devoted to a private use, or upon ordinary private investments? Is the corporation entitled to the current rate of interest on the present value of the property devoted to the use? Will less than that be a fair and reasonable return? And if it is not reasonable, measured by the earnings on ordinary invest
The averments of the answer do not show that the act of the legislature regulating stock-yards violates any of the provisions of the federal constitution mentioned. Nor do we find anything substantial in the claim that the act conflicts with the state constitution, in that the power to pass the act is not expressly delegated to the legislature. In section 1 of article. 2 of that ihstrument (Gen. Stat. 1901, § 119) the people expressly vested full legislative .power in the house of representatives and senate. The legislature represents the people of the state, and there are no limits upon the power which that body may exercise, except such as may be found in the constitution itself, or in the federal constitution.
Nor do we see any merit in the contention that the penalties imposed in the act constitute cruel and unusual punishments, and are so excessive as to render it invalid.
The judgment is therefore reversed, and the cause remanded for further proceedings.