Quackenbush v. Danks

1 Denio 128 | Court for the Trial of Impeachments and Correction of Errors | 1845

By the Court, Bronson, Ch. J.

It is insisted by the plaintiff below that the exemption law of 1842 applies to executions for debts which were contracted before the law was passed. This is denied by the defendant. But if the plaintiff prevails upon that point, the defendant then insists that the statute is unconstitutional, on the ground that it is a “ law impairing the obligation óf contracts.”

Under the old law, many enumerated articles of property, when owned by a householder, were exempt from sale on execution, and from distress for rent. (2 R. S. 367, § 22, and p. 501, § 10.) Then came the law of 1842, which provides, that in addition to the articles now exempt by law from distress for rent, or levy and sale under execution, there shall be exempted from such distress, and levy and sale, necessary household furniture, and working tools, and team, owned by any person being a householder, or having a family for which he provides,' to the value of not exceeding one hundred and fifty dollars.” (Stat. 1842, p. 193, § 1.) There is a proviso to the section; but it has no bearing upon the present inquiry.

The plaintiff had no property which was not exempt by the *130old law, except the horse and harness in question; and that property was subject to -the levy and sale on execution at the time the debt to Fitch was contracted, and his judgment against the plaintiff was recovered. Upon the plaintiff’s construction, the effect of the law of 1842, in this particular case has been, to withdraw the whole of the debtor’s property from the reach of the creditor. That may not, however, affect the principle. If, after the debt has been contracted, any portion of the debtor’s property can be exempted from the creditor’s execution, I see no reason why the exemption may not be extended to the whole estate of the debtor, be it large or small.

Whatever may be thought of the expediency of pass ing exemption laws, if they are wholly prospective in their operation, no wrong is done to the creditor. - He has the law before him when he parts with his money or his property ; and it will not be -the fault of the government if the debt is lost. But when such laws are made to act upon past transactions, they cannot fail to work injustice.. They take the property which in honesty and fair dealing belongs to the creditor, and, without his consent, transfer it to the debtor. The least that can be said of such laws is, that they prove the existence of a bad state of public morals. There is nothing in the statute under consideration which, either in terms or by necessary implication, makes it applicable to the case in hand; and we ought in decency to conclude that the legislature did not intend it should have the retrospective and unjust effect which is claimed for it by the plaintiff. I will not deny that the general words in rvhich the law is framed are broad enough to include contracts already in existence, as well as those which should afterwards be made. But it is a well established rule that a statute shall not be so construed as to give it a retrospect beyond the time of its commencement; and there are many cases in the books where general words, as comprehensive as those under consideration, have been restricted in their,influence so as not to reach past transactions. This is but a branch of that great principle which requires that every law should, if possible, be so interpreted and carried into effect that no wrong *131will be done to any one. I bad, occasion to examine this doctrine, and to refer to authorities in support of it, in Sackett v. Andross, (5 Hill, 334—7, and 362—5.) and will not, therefore, enter upon a more extended discussion of it on the present occasion. Although the decision in that case was not in accordance with my views—my brethren thinking that the words of the bankrupt law were too strong.to admit the application of the rule of justice and honesty for which I contended-—yet the case may be referred to for reasons and authorities which touch the matter in hand. I feel the Ifiss disposition to pursue this branch of the case, where there is room for a difference of opinion, because I think it clear that the court below was wrong on the question which remains to be noticed.

Granting that this statute is broad enough to cover the plaintiff’s case, the question then arises whether it is not a “ law impairing the obligation of contracts.” Imprisonment as a means of enforcing the payment of debts no longer exists. The creditor can look to nothing but the property of the debtor. If the legislature can deprive him of the right to reach the property— a right which existéd at the time the contract was made—it is evident that nothing will then remain of the obligation of the contract beyond an empty name. It may be the moral, but it is no longer the legal duty of the debtor to pay. For all honest and practical purposes, the legislature might just as well say that the debt shall be blotted out, as to deny to the creditor all means of enforcing payment. I have not overlooked the distinction which often exists between the obligation of the contract, and the remedy to enforce performance. In many cases this distinction is of a substantial nature, and must have a controlling influence. But experience has proved, that laws which in form go only to the remedy, may have the practical effect of nullifying the contract. This has been seen by the federal courts, and they have recently laid down some very important qualifications to the general doctrine that the states have unlimited power over the remedy. I shall not enter at large into the discussion of this question, f&r the reason that I think it virtually settled by the late decisions of the supreme court of the *132United States in the cases arising under the valuation laws of the state of Illinois. (Bronson v. Kinzie, 1 Howard, 311; McCracken v. Hayward, 2 id. 608.) I allude more particularly to the last of those cases, which arose upon a statute touching sales on execution. The law provided, that when execution should be levied on any property, real or personal, it should be the duty of the officer to summon three householders, who, after being duly sworn, should “fairly and impartially value the propertyand when offered for sale, it should not be struck off unless two-thirds of the amount of such valuation should be bid therefor. This law, which was passed after the creditor had obtained a judgment, was held to be unconstitutional and void. If a law which only prohibits the creditor from taking the property at less than two-thirds of its sworn value cannot be supported, it needs no argument to prove that a law cannot be upheld which wholly withdraws the property from the reach of the creditor. As the question arises under the constitution of the United States, we must regard the decision as one of binding authority.

We are referred to a dictum of Chief Justice Taney in Bronson v. Kinzie which favors the opinion that “ the necessary implements of agriculture, or the tools of the mechanic, or articles of necessity in household furniture” may, “like wearing apparel,” be exempted from sale on execution. This is not going far enough to include the plaintiff’s horse and harness : but I shall lay no stress upon that consideration. If the question turns on what is “ necessary” for the debtor and his family, the learned chief justice will find it impossible to stop with the articles he has mentioned. The husbandman stands in as much need of a farm, as he does of the “ implements of agriculture and “ household furniture” is not more essential to the head of a family, than a house to live in. The mechanic wants & workshop, as well as the “tools” of his trade: the lawyer must have a library; and to all classes, money or property with which to purchase food and raiment, is as needful as any thing else. And besides, what would be sufficient for one man, would be little better than nothing to another. The “ necessity” of *133one may be satisfied by the exemption of property to the value of one hundred and fifty dollars, while ten times that amount would not satisfy the urgent wants of another. There is, I think, no well defined middle ground between holding that none of the debtor’s property can, by a subsequent law, be withdrawn from the reach of the creditor, or else admitting that the whole of his estate may be exempted from sale on execution. In the case before us, the exemption law saves all to the debtor; but my opinion would be the same if it had only saved a part. Such property as was subject to execution at the time the debt was contracted, must remain subject to execution until the debt is paid. As to future obligations, the legislature may make the exemption as broad as it pleases. It may abolish credit altogether. But it cannot legislate backward, and annul the force of prior obligations.

In relation to the dictum which has been mentioned, I will only add, that it was virtually overruled by the decision in McCracken v. Hayward. So long as that case stands, the exemption law of 1842) when applied to past transactions, cannot be supported.

Judgment reversed.