101 Mass. 575 | Mass. | 1869
By the terms of the act of congress of June 30 1864, (U. S. St. 1864, c. 106,) under which the national bank» nave come into existence, all the shares in each of said banks
If the St. of 1868, c. 349, is to be interpreted as providing for the imposition of an excise, in the proper sense of that term and as distinguished from a tax, it would be liable to all the
The objection that it conflicts with the restrictions expressly provided for by the two acts of congress is one which meets us at the threshold of the inquiry, and may very properly be considered first. The power of the state to tax the shares is subject to the restriction that the tax shall not be “ at a greater rate than is assessed upon any other moneyed capital in the hands of individual citizens of the state.” We think that this clause was obviously intended to preclude the possibility that property of that description should be singled out for special and pecular taxation. Its operation would be, to prevent oppressive and hostile discriminations unfavorable to the banks. A state, if there were no such restrictions, might so arrange its method of taxation as substantially to expel the national banks from its
Is the tax on bank stock throughout the Commonwealth to be determined, and absolutely controlled, by the decision of some small country village, in which there happens to be no bank, and in which the municipal wants and expenses are slight and insignificant? Yet the literal construction of the words “ at a rate no greater than is assessed upon any other moneyed capital in the hands of individual citizens of the state ” would lead to precisely this result. It is impossible to believe that such was the purpose of the act, or that such would be a reasonable and fair interpretation of its meaning. In our judgment, it satisfies the meaning of the restriction, if the rate upon bank shares is the same as the rate upon moneyed capital in the hands of individual citizens in the town or city w'here the bank is located.
Another objection, which is the one principally urged in the argument, is, that the tax in controversy is not proportional. If this objection should prove to be well taken, the tax is illegal and void. It is not in the power of congress to authorize the
If our St. of 1868, c. 349, had simply provided that the tax on bank shares belonging to persons not residing within the state should be paid into the treasury of the town or city where the bank is, and should make a part of the funds of such tow»
As we understand the argument in behalf of the plaintiffs, it may be illustrated in this manner: Suppose the whole amount of the property, which, by the terms of the statute, is to be omitted from the general valuation forming the basis of taxation, to be sufficiently large for its omission to diminish that valuation to such an extent that, in order to raise the whole amount of the taxes, it should become necessary to increase the rate of taxation from four cents on each hundred dollars to five cents. Of course these figures are here taken arbitrarily, merely for the purpose of illustration, and without any attempt to approximate to the exact state of the facts. Assuming these figures, we should have the taxes upon property included in the valuation apparently twenty-five per cent, higher than they would be under a system requiring the whole of the taxable property to pay the whole of the property tax. This same rate, made by the operation of the statute, as the plaintiffs insist, to stand at
It is quite apparent that this objection, if well founded, is very far from being peculiarly applicable to the case of nonresident owners of bank stock. If the fact that the whole amount of the property taxes is levied upon less than the whole amount of the taxable property is a valid objection, it is sufficient to vitiate the whole tax. The owners of bank stock, moneyed capital, or in fact of any other description of taxable property included in the valuation, would apparently have as much reason to complain of the disproportion, as the nonresident owners of bank stock. If the principle of assessment should prove to be erroneous and vicious, and prohibited by the terms of the Constitution, the tax is all wrong, from beginning to end, and cannot be enforced against owners of bank stock, whether resident or not resident in the state, nor in fact against any owners of property whatever.
It is true that, under the operation of the statute, a part only of the taxable property of the Commonwealth is made to pay the whole of the county tax, the city and town tax, and also the whole amount of what is annually voted by the legislature specifically as the state tax, so far as these three descriptions of tax are assessed upon property and not upon polls. The money obtained from the assessment of bank stock belonging to nonresident owners does not make any part of either one of these three descriptions of tax. But, although not known as the state tax eo nomine, it is nevertheless a tax for the use and benefit of the state. It goes into the public treasury, and makes a part of the annual ways and means of the state. The effect of the statute, if carried out, would be to furnish the Commonwealth with a regular source of income capable of making a valuable addition to the public revenue, varying perhaps somewhat from year te
We do not understand the plaintiffs to deny that their shares are proper subjects of taxation in Boston, or to complain that there is any disproportion in the taxation of resident and nonresident shareholders in the same place, as compared with each other. The objection is, that by the operation of the statute they are made taxable at a higher rate, and so for a larger amount, than they would be if they were included in the valuation upon which the rate is to depend. Is this complaint well founded ? It is to be remembered that whatever amount may be added to the public revenue by the operation of the statute diminishes to exactly the same extent the amount necessary to
There is a provision in the statute, that, in assessing such shares, there shall be a deduction of a proportionate part of the value of the real estate belonging to the bank. To that
The conclusion, then, at which we arrive, is, that the St. of 1868, c. 349, does not transcend, or conflict with, the limitations expressly set forth in the acts of congress; that practically it produces no appreciable disproportion among taxpayers as compared with each other; that the omission of the shares of nonresidents from the town valuations produces no actual want of due proportion, for the reason that the general result of the taxation, supposing the statute to be held valid, is substantially identical, to each taxpayer, with what it would be if the shares of nonresidents were included in those valuations and taxed in the same manner in all respects as the real estate of nonresident owners is taxed; and that, although in one mode of proceeding the sum total of the valuations is less than in the other, yet the aggregate of the amount to be raised under the heads of county, municipal and state taxes is diminished in exactly the same proportion.
As to the objection that it is retrospective in its operation, it seems to be enough to say that, under the acts of congress, the property was certainly taxable in such lawful manner as the legislature of the Commonwealth should direct. Whoever, then, on the first day of May 1868 held such property knew, or was bound to know, that it was taxable like other moneyed capital as of that day, in such manner as by law might be provided.
We do not find, in the various objections taken on behalf of the plaintiffs, and so ably and forcibly urged by their learned counsel, anything that convinces us that the statute ought to be pronounced unconstitutional, or that the tax imposed in pursuance of it is unlawful and void. And according to the terms of the agreement there must be, in each case,
Judgment for the defendant.