487 F.3d 261 | 5th Cir. | 2007
Lead Opinion
This is a permissible interlocutory appeal from an order certifying a securities-fraud class action. Plaintiffs allege violations of section 10(b) and 20(a) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 and Rule 10b-5 of the Securities Exchange Commission. Relying on the fraud-on-the-market theory, the district court certified the class. We vacate the certification order and remand, persuaded that the class certified fails for wont of any showing that the market reacted to the corrective disclosure. Given the lethal force of certifying a class of purchasers of securities enabled by the fraud-on-the-market doctrine, we now in fairness insist that such a certification be supported by a showing of loss causation that targets the corrective disclosure appearing among other negative disclosures made at the same time.
I
The class included all investors who purchased the common stock of Allegiance Telecom between April 24, 2001 and February 19, 2002. Three investors bring this suit, Oscar Private Equity Investments, its managing partner, Brett Messing, and his wife, Marla Messing. They sue Royce Holland, former chairman and CEO of Allegiance, and Anthony Parella, former executive vice president for sales. Allegiance Telecom was named in the suit, but filed for bankruptcy and is not now a party.
Allegiance was a national telecommunications provider based in Dallas, Texas. It sold local telephone service, long distance, broadband access, web hosting, and telecom equipment with maintenance to small and medium sized businesses. Founded in 1997, by February 2002 it was providing service in thirty-six U.S. markets. At the beginning of the class period,
Plaintiffs allege that Holland and Par-ella fraudulently misrepresented Allegiance’s line-installation count in the company’s first three quarterly announcements of 2001, and that Allegiance’s stock dropped after Holland and Parella ultimately restated the count in the 4Q01 announcement. Defendants explain that the restatement occurred because Allegiance installed a new billing system in 2001 and reported line-count information from the new billing system instead of from the order management system which it replaced. Defendants further argue that the 4Q01 restatement did not cause the stock price to drop.
The relevant announcement history is as follows. Allegiance’s stock, like that of the rest of the telecom industry, was plunging during what is now the class period, losing nearly 90% of its value during 2001. On April 24, 2001, the first day of the class period, Allegiance announced its 1Q01 results, including (1) 126,200 new lines installed; (2) revenues of $105.9 million, an 11% increase over 4Q00; (3) positive sales force growth; and (4) improved gross margin. The following trading day Allegiance’s stock rose 9%, from $14.90 to $16.20, but soon declined again.
On July 24, 2001, Allegiance announced its 2Q01 results, including (1) 135,800 new lines installed; (2) revenues of $124.1 million; (3) an earnings loss of $0.92 per share, $0.03 better than the analysts’ consensus estimate; and (4) positive EBIT-DA
On October 23, 2001, Allegiance announced its 3Q01 results, including (1) the installation of its one-millionth line; (2) revenues of $135 million; and (3) an earnings loss of $0.94 per share, $0.03 better than the analysts’ consensus estimate. The next trading day Allegiance’s stock rose 29%, from $5.21 to $6.74 per share, but remained volatile, falling to $3.70 per share by February 18, 2002, the day before the curative statements of the 4Q01 announcement.
On February 19, 2002, Allegiance announced its 4Q01 results, including (1) a restatement of the total installed-line count from 1,140,000 to 1,015,000, a difference of 125,000; (2) missed analysts’ expectations on 4Q01 and 2001 earnings per share; (3) greater EBITDA loss than some analysts expected; and (4) a very thin margin of error for meeting revenue covenants for 2002. The next trading day Allegiance’s stock continued its downward move, falling 28%, from $3.70 to $2.65 per share. Less than 90 days later, Allegiance missed its covenants putting its credit lines in default and on May 14, 2003, filed for bankruptcy.
Six months after Allegiance’s bankruptcy, plaintiffs filed this class action, alleging that Allegiance’s officers misrepresented the number of installed lines in their 1Q01, 2Q01, and 3Q01 announcements. Plaintiffs moved for class certification, relying on the fraud-on-the-market presumption for evidence of class-wide reliance. The district court certified the class,
The class certification determination rests within the sound discretion of the trial court, exercised within the constraints of Rule 23.
III
This dispute turns on whether the certification order properly relied upon the fraud-on-the-market theory. This theory permits a trial court to presume that each class member has satisfied the reliance element of their 10b-5 claim.
The Supreme Court in Basic adopted this presumption of reliance with respect to materially misleading statements or omissions concerning companies whose shares are traded in an efficient market.
We have observed that Basic “allows each of the circuits room to develop its own fraud-on-the-market rules.”
This requirement was not plucked from the air. Basic plainly states that the presumption of reliance may be rebutted by “[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged misrepresentation and ... the price received (or paid) by the plaintiff.”
Quoting this very language, plaintiffs argue that our requirement improperly shifts the burden, from a defendant’s right of rebuttal to a plaintiffs burden of proof. We disagree. As a matter of practice, the oft-chosen defensive move is to make “any showing that severs the link” between the misrepresentation and the plaintiffs loss; to do so rebuts on arrival the plaintiffs fraud-on-the-market theory. In Nathen-son, the link was severed by publicly available information that the misrepresentation didn’t move the stock price.
Neither party disputes Greenberg’s relevance. Instead, this appeal raises the question of whether we ought to apply Greenberg’s loss-causation requirement at the class-certification stage, as well as the subsidiary question of the sufficiency of the evidence to establish the requirement. On the first question, defendants urge that the district court must consider all evidence, both for and against loss causation, at the class certification stage. On the second question, defendants argue that the district court abused its discretion in finding that plaintiffs made a showing sufficient to establish loss causation. We agree with both contentions.
A
First we address the question of whether loss causation — a fraud on the market prerequisite — should properly be addressed at the class certification stage. The district court ruled that “the class certification stage is not the proper time for defendants to rebut lead Plaintiffs’ fraud-on-the-market presumption,” and suggested that Basic “held that the presumption of reliance was rebuttable, but only as related to a summary judgment motion.” Plaintiffs defend the court’s ruling, noting that Greenberg was a summary-judgment case and urging that proof of loss causation at this stage “improperly combines the market efficiency standard with actual proof of loss causation.”
There is widespread confusion on this point. As we will explain, the confusion arises from an outdated view that fails to accord this signal event of the case its due. Under this earlier view, class certification was to be made “as soon as practicable after the commencement of the action,” mindful that the decision was tentative. It could be tailored to facts emerging in discovery, and with subclasses built around awkward difficulties of showings that cut across only part of the class first certified. In short, class certification was a light step along the way, divorced from the merits of the claim. Whatever reality this treatment was responsive to, it is not that of a class exceeding purchasers of millions of shares in a volatile and downward-turning market over a ten-month period, claiming injury from one of several simultaneous disclosures of negative information.
The power of the fraud-on-the-market doctrine is on display here. With proof that these securities were being traded in an efficient market, the district court effec
These concerns have shaped the evolution of class certification and Rule 23. Rule 23(c)(1)(A) no longer demands that the district court rule on class certification “as soon as practicable,”
Relatedly, Rule 23’s requirements must be given their full weight independent of the merits. District courts often tread too lightly on Rule 23 requirements that overlap with the 10b-5 merits, out of a mistaken belief that merits questions may never be addressed at the class certification stage.
Eisen did not drain Rule 23 of all rigor. A district court still must give full and independent weight to each Rule 23 requirement, regardless of whether that requirement overlaps with the merits.
resolve[ ] factual disputes relevant to each Rule 23 requirement and find[] that whatever underlying facts are relevant to a particular Rule 23 requirement have been established.... [T]he obligation to make such determinations is not lessened by overlap between a Rule 23 requirement and a merits issue, even a merits issue that is identical with a Rule 23 requirement.39
The answer to our first question, then, lies at the intersection of Greenberg and Unger. Greenberg holds that loss causation is a fraud-on-the-market prerequisite.
Plaintiffs respond that the question of loss causation requires only a generalized inquiry into whether the misrepresentation moved the stock, an inquiry common to all members of the class. Pressing this point at oral argument, plaintiffs urged that it was inappropriate to address loss causation at the class-certification stage because loss causation necessarily predominates, unlike individualized questions of reliance.
We might agree, if loss causation were only empirical proof of materiality, unm-oored from the question of classwide reliance. Yet we have explained that the refutation of loss causation “more appropriately relates to the element of reliance.”
The assumption that every material misrepresentation will move a stock in an efficient market is unfounded, at least as market efficiency is presently measured. There are two additional explanations, besides immateriality, for why a misrepresentation might fail to effect the stock price, both relevant to classwide reliance. First, it might be that even though the market for the defendant’s shares has been demonstrated efficient by the usual indicia,
B
The legal error immediately identified, however, does not alone dictate vacatur in this case, as the trial court, out of caution perhaps, did not premise its analysis on its misunderstanding of the law. Indeed, the trial court’s memorandum opinion applies Greenberg and weighs all evidence, both for and against loss causation, in concluding that “it is more likely than not that a significant part of the stock decline causing the putative Class’s loss is attributable to the line count corrective disclosure.” We vacate because this factual conclusion is untenable. The plaintiffs expert report did not establish loss causation, and the district court abused its discretion in certifying the class.
As we explained above, when unrelated negative statements are announced contemporaneous of a corrective disclosure, the plaintiff must prove “that it is more probable than not that it was this negative statement, and not other unrelated negative statements, that caused a significant amount of the decline.”
Unfortunately, Bears will have additional fodder during 1Q02, as [Allegiance] scrubbed their databases and found some differences in line count between billing and order management platforms ... In light of “Enron-itis,” we believe an increasingly skeptical market will have a negative view of this adjustment ... Unfortunately, the line revision will cloud the company’s otherwise strong performance.
And at BB&T Capital Markets, an analyst groused,
The magnitude of this [line count] adjustment (12% of total) makes it difficult to swallow ... Given the issues surrounding accounting today, the timing of such an adjustment could not be worse.
Plaintiffs cite several other such reports— one calls the line-count restatement “a yellow flag,” and another suggests that “the Street is completely unwilling to listen to management explanations.”
Defendants respond in kind, with more analyst quotes, including one from lead plaintiff Brett Messing, who reported in a May 15, 2002 column for RealMoney.com that “Allegiance’s stocks and bonds are trading at distressed levels because of fears of a revenue covenant violation,
The plaintiffs have the better of this exchange, but nonetheless, their evidence is little more than well-informed speculation. To prove loss causation, and thereby trigger the presumption of rebanee, plaintiffs must do better. The plaintiffs’ expert does detail event studies supporting a finding that Allegiance’s stock reacted to the entire bundle of negative information contained in the 4Q01 announcement, but this reaction suggests only market efficiency, not loss causation, for there is no evidence linking the culpable disclosure to the stock-price movement. When multiple negative items are announced contemporaneously, mere proximity between the announcement and the stock loss is insufficient to establish loss causation.
Plaintiffs expert, in her rebuttal, disagrees, but offers as evidence only the raw opinion of analysts, without supporting study of the market at issue — such as now common use of basic principles of econometrics. The expert’s own concluding paragraph advised that her work was incomplete: “It is possible with further anal-yses to quantify the portion of the decline caused by the restated line count. However, Counsel has advised me that the quantification of damages is not appropriate at this stage of the litigation.” So this is less of a dispute over what showing must be made, and more a dispute over when.
Something like the expert’s “further analyses” is what is missing. While counsel is correct that quantification of damages is presently unnecessary — ie. proof that some percentage of the drop was attributable to the corrective disclosure — the plaintiffs must, in order to establish loss causation at this stage, offer some empirically-based showing that the corrective disclosure was more than just present at the scene.
Because plaintiffs have failed to trigger the presumption of rebanee provided by the fraud-on-the-market theory, the class fails and we must vacate the order of certification.
We VACATE and REMAND for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
. EBITDA is an acronym for earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization. It is a measure of profitability.
. The district court certified the following class: "All persons, without geographical limitation, who purchased Allegiance common stock in the open market during the period
. Gulf Oil Co. v. Bernard, 452 U.S. 89, 100, 101 S.Ct. 2193, 68 L.Ed.2d 693 (1981).
. Feder v. Electronic Data Systems Corp., 429 F.3d 125, 129 (5th Cir.2005).
. The elements of a 10b-5 action include:
(1) a material misrepresentation (or omission);
(2) scienter, i.e., a wrongful state of mind;
(3) a connection with the purchase or sale of a security;
(4) reliance, often referred to in cases involving public securities markets (fraud-on-the-market cases) as "transaction causation,”;
(5) economic loss; and
(6) “loss causation,” i.e., a causal connection between the material misrepresentation and the loss. Dura Pharms., Inc. v. Broudo, 544 U.S. 336, 125 S.Ct. 1627, 161 L.Ed.2d 577 (2005).
. Fed.R.Civ.Pro. 23(b)(3).
. In re LTV Securities Litigation, 88 F.R.D. 134, 143 (N.D.Tex.1980); Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224, 244, 108 S.Ct. 978, 99 L.Ed.2d 194 (1988).
. Greenberg v. Crossroads Systems, Inc., 364 F.3d 657, 661 (5th Cir.2004).
. Abell v. Potomac Ins. Co., 858 F.2d 1104, 1117-18 (5th Cir.1988), vacated on other grounds sub. nom. Fryar v. Abell, 492 U.S. 914, 109 S.Ct. 3236, 106 L.Ed.2d 584 (1989); Nathenson v. Zonagen Inc., 267 F.3d 400, 414 (5th Cir.2001).
. Finkel v. Docutel/Olivetti Corp., 817 F.2d 356, 364 (5th Cir.1987), cert. denied, 485 U.S. 959, 108 S.Ct. 1220, 99 L.Ed.2d 421 (1988).
. Abell, 858 F.2d at 1120-21 (stating in dicta that a plaintiff may recover under the fraud-on-the-market theory “if he could prove that the defendant’s non-disclosures materially affected the market price of the security”).
. Nathenson, 267 F.3d at 414 ("It is clear that a fraud-on-the-market theory may not be the basis for recovery in respect to an alleged misrepresentation which does not affect the market price of the security in question.”).
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 662, 665-66.
. Cf. In re Burlington Coat Factory Securities Litigation, 114 F.3d 1410 (3d Cir.1997). ("In the context of an 'efficient' market, the concept of materiality translates into information that alters the price of the firm’s stock.”).
. Nathenson, 267 F.3d at 414 (quoting Abell, 858 F.2d 1104, 1120-21).
. Our approach is unaffected by the Supreme Court's recent and very narrow decision in Dura Pharms., 125 S.Ct. at 1627.
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 665.
. 485 U.S. at 245, 108 S.Ct. 978. The Basic Court continues, "For example, if [defendants] could show that the 'market makers’ were privy to the truth about the merger discusses here with Combustion, and thus that the market price would not have been affected by their misrepresentations, the causal connection could be broken.” Id. (emphasis added). Drawing on Abell and Nathenson, the Green-berg court added a showing to this list of "examples.”
. Nathenson, 267 F.3d at 414.
. Id. at 414.
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 665.
. Our able brother frames our differences well, but is a bit enthusiastic in our holding. We address here only the simultaneous disclosure of multiple negatives, not all of which are alleged culpable. Indeed, applying the fraud-on-the-market theory to such complex circumstances by rote would yield a victory of habit over reason. With multiple negatives, our usual approach to gauging efficiency and presuming reliance fails because we cannot know that the culpable information was priced, even if objectively material. Proof that the culpable disclosure moved the market addresses this failure. The dissent is troubled that we have not suggested what form such
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 666.
. Fed.R.Civ.P. 23(c)(l)(A)(2003).
. Fed.R.Civ.P. 23(c)(l)(A)(revised 2003).
. Id. at 23(c)(1)(C); see id. Advisory Committee Notes to the 2003 Amendments C'[I]t is appropriate to conduct controlled discovery into the 'merits,' limited to those aspects relevant to making the certification decision on an informed basis.”).
. This word has been demoted to the comments section.
. See Fed.R.Civ.P. 23 Advisory Committee Notes to the 2003 Amendments.
. Unger v. Amedisys Inc., 401 F.3d 316, 321 (5th Cir.2005).
. Unger, 401 F.3d at 321.
. Unger, 401 F.3d at 325.
. See, e.g., Barrie v. Intervoice-Brite, 2006 WL 2792199, *10 (N.D.Tex.,2006) (“Although Basic and Greenberg (the cases relied upon by Defendants) both held the presumption to be rebuttable at the summary judgment stage, such a finding by the court here, where the issue is class certification, would be premature, since the court cannot delve into the actual merits of Lead Plaintiffs’ claims.”).
. Bell v. Ascendant Solutions, Inc., 422 F.3d 307, 311-14 (5th Cir.2005).
. Eisen v. Carlisle & Jacquelin, 417 U.S. 156, 177-78, 94 S.Ct. 2140, 40 L.Ed.2d 732 (1974).
. Miles v. Merrill Lynch, 471 F.3d 24, 27 (2d Cir.2006).
. See General Telephone Company of the Southwest v. Falcon, 457 U.S. 147, 160, 102 S.Ct. 2364, 72 L.Ed.2d 740 (1982) (acknowledging that "class determination generally involves considerations that are enmeshed in the factual and legal issues comprising the plaintiffs’ cause of action,” and concluding that a class “may only be certified if the trial court is satisfied, after a rigorous analysis, that the prerequisites of Rule 23(a) have been satisfied.”).
. Miller v. Mackey Int’l, 452 F.2d 424, 427 (5th Cir.1971).
. Castano v. American Tobacco Co., 84 F.3d 734, 744 (5th Cir.1996).
. Miles, 471 F.3d at 41.
. This is not to say that loss causation, as an element of a 10b-5 claim, cannot be reexamined at summary judgment.
. Nathenson, 267 F.3d at 415. This relationship is foremost an artifact of the common law's influence on 10b-5 actions, yet it persists for good reason. See Schlick v. Penn-Dixie, 507 F.2d 374 (2d Cir.1974); Huddleston v. Herman & MacLean, 640 F.2d 534, 549 (5th Cir.1981), reversed in part Herman & MacLean v. Huddleston, 459 U.S. 375, 103 S.Ct. 683, 74 L.Ed.2d 548 (1983).
. These include "(1) the average weekly trading volume expressed as a percentage of total outstanding shares; (2) the number of securities analysts following and reporting on the stock; (3) the extent to which market makers and arbitrage! ]rs trade in the stock; (4) the company’s eligibility to file SEC registration Form S-3; (5) the existence of empirical facts showing a cause and effect relationship between unexpected corporate events or financial releases and an immediate response in the stock price; (6) the company’s market capitalization; (7) the bid-ask spread for stock sales; and (8) float, the stock's trading volume without counting insider-owned stock.” Bell v. Ascendant Solutions, Inc., 422 F.3d 307, 313 (5th Cir.2005).
.See, e.g., Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Good Finance, Bad Economics: An Analysis of the Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 42 Stan. L.Rev. 1059, 1083 (1990).
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 666.
. A prescient observation indeed.
. Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 666.
. Unger, 401 F.3d at 320-21.
Dissenting Opinion
dissenting:
I respectfully dissent.
I also respectfully dissent from the majority’s conclusion that the district court abused its discretion in certifying this class action. The majority found that the plaintiffs’ evidence was insufficient to establish that the decline in Allegiance’s share price was related to Allegiance’s disclosure that it had overstated its line count figures, but the majority conducted what appears to have been a de novo, rather an abuse of discretion, review of the evidence in order to make that determination. In my opinion, the district court did not abuse its discretion in making the factual findings necessary to its certification of the case.
I.
The majority opinion relies heavily on this court’s earlier decision in Greenberg v. Crossroads Systems, Inc., 364 F.3d 657 (5th Cir.2004), which, the majority urges, establishes that “we require plaintiffs to establish loss causation in order to trigger the fraud-on-the-market presumption.” Supra at 265; see also supra at 268. As I discuss in greater detail below, Greenberg says no such thing. Neither Greenberg nor any other decision of this court holds that proof of loss causation is part of the fraud-on-the-market presumption. The majority’s holding to the contrary amounts to a profound modification of Greenberg. See infra Part II.
Moreover, by its decision today the majority aggravates the already serious and unwarranted departure that Greenberg made from both Basic&nd prior circuit precedent.
The Basic court also held that the fraud-on-the-market presumption is rebuttable, but it made it plain that the defendant bears the burden of establishing that the presumption should not apply:
[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged misrepresentation and either the price received (or paid) by the plaintiff, or his decision to trade at a fair market price, will be sufficient to rebut the presumption of reliance. For example, if [defendants] could show that the “market makers” were privy to the truth about the merger discussions here with Combustion, and thus that the market price would not have been affected by their misrepresentations, the causal connection could be broken: the basis for finding that the fraud had been transmitted through market price would be gone.
Id. at 248 (emphasis added).
Up until our decision in Greenberg in 2004, this court consistently recognized Basic’s holding that the defendant has the burden of rebutting the fraud-on-the-market presumption. See Nathenson v. Zonagen Inc., 267 F.3d 400, 413 (5th Cir.2001); Fine v. Am. Solar King Corp., 919 F.2d 290, 299 (5th Cir.1990); see also Lehocky v. Tidel Techs., Inc., 220 F.R.D. 491, 505 (S.D.Tex.2004). Two years after Basic, this court held that there are three ways in which a defendant can rebut the presumption: by showing “(1) that the nondisclo-sures did not affect the market price, or (2) that the Plaintiffs would have purchased the stock at the same price had they known the information that was not disclosed; or (3) that the Plaintiffs actually knew the information that was not disclosed to the market.” Fine, 919 F.2d at 299.
The Greenberg panel itself began by correctly describing Basic’s presumption of reliance in favor of the plaintiff and recognizing that Basic places the burden of rebutting the presumption on the defendant.
Confronted with the argument that Greenberg improperly shifts the Basic burden, changing it from a defendant’s right of rebuttal to a plaintiffs burden of proof, the majority makes a meager effort to claim that both Greenberg and today’s decision are somehow compatible with Basic’s command that it falls to the defendant to rebut the presumption of reliance. The majority attempts to recharacterize the Basic presumption as a sort of “bursting bubble” presumption, e.g., one that “disappears if anything to the contrary is placed before the court.” United States v. Zavala, 443 F.3d 1165, 1169 (9th Cir.2006); cf. Black’s Law Dictionary 211 (8th ed.2004) (defining the “bursting bubble theory” as “[t]he principle that a presumption disappears once the presumed facts have been contradicted by credible evidence”). The majority posits that “[a]s a matter of practice, the oft-chosen defensive move is to make ‘any showing that severs the link’ between the misrepresentation and the plaintiffs loss; to do so rebuts on arrival the plaintiffs fraud-on-the-market theory.” Supra at 265. Although the majority conspicuously neglects to explain what type of evidence a defendant would have to produce to meet its standard, the clear implication is that, in the majority’s view, the Basic presumption evaporates as soon as a defendant simply introduces a mere possibility the defendant’s material misrepresentation might not have affected the market price.
The majority cannot outflank Basic so easily, however. As noted above, Basic expressly states that the defendants can rebut the presumption only if they “could show ... that the market price would not have been affected by their misrepresentations.” Basic, 485 U.S. at 248, 108 S.Ct. 978 (emphasis added). Basic thus clearly places the burdens of both producing evidence and persuasion on the defendant and requires an actual showing that the defendant’s misrepresentation did not, or could not have, affected the market price of the stock. Id.; Fine, 919 F.2d at 299 (“The presumption of reliance can be rebutted by showing ... that the nondisclo-sures did not affect the market price .... ”); see also Abell v. Potomac Ins. Co., 858 F.2d 1104, 1120 (5th Cir.1988) (stating that Basic “shift[s] the burden of persuasion, as to reliance, onto securities fraud defendants”), vacated on other grounds sub nom., Fryar v. Abell, 492 U.S. 914, 109 S.Ct. 3236, 106 L.Ed.2d 584 (1989). Under no reasonable reading can that standard be met, as the majority suggests, by simply asserting that a particular change in the market price could have been related
For the reasons stated above, I continue to believe that Greenberg conflicts with binding precedents of both the Supreme Court and this court, and I do not therefore regard that case as binding or persuasive on the point at issue. See Modica v. Taylor, 465 F.3d 174, 183 (5th Cir.2006) (“ ‘When panel opinions appear to conflict, we are bound to follow the earlier opinion.’ ”) (quoting H&D Tire & Auto.-Hardware, Inc. v. Pitney Bowes Inc., 227 F.3d 326, 330 (5th Cir.2001)). Consequently, the majority was not bound to repeat the Greenberg panel’s error. Instead, it should have adhered to Basic and this court’s pre-Greenberg jurisprudence, rather than repeating and — as I discuss next— exacerbating Greenberg’s flaws.
II.
Even setting aside the preceding discussion of Greenberg’s conflict with Basic, Greenberg simply does not stand for the principle the majority purports to draw from it, i.e., that “we require plaintiffs to establish loss causation in order to trigger the fraud-on-the-market presumption.” Supra at 265.
In Greenberg, the court stated that in order to merit a presumption of reliance under the fraud-on-the-market theory,
[a] causal relationship between the statement and actual movement of the stock price is still required.... It is this actual movement of stock price which must be shown by fraud-on-the-market plaintiffs....
Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 663.
the main concern when determining whether a plaintiff is entitled to the presumption of reliance is the causal connection between the allegedly false statement and its effect on a company’s stock price. Nathenson makes it clear that to establish this nexus the plaintiffs must be able to show that the stock price was actually affected. This is ordinarily shown by an increase in stock price immediately following the release of positive information. We read Nath-enson to also allow plaintiffs to make this showing by reference to actual negative movement in stock price following the release of the alleged “truth” of the earlier misrepresentation.
Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 665. Assuming for the sake of argument that Greenberg is correct, then, a plaintiff could satisfy Greenberg in the typical securities fraud case involving allegations that the defendant’s misrepresentations artificially inflated the issuer’s stock price by showing that the market price of the stock moved either upward at the time of the defendant’s alleged misrepresentation or downward at the time that the truth was disclosed.
The majority, however, disregards the part of Greenberg that states that the actual price movement component of its version of the fraud-on-the-market theory can be satisfied by showing an increase in the
Accordingly, because the rule that the majority purports to derive from Green-berg has no basis in that case, I could not join the majority’s opinion even were I not convinced that Greenberg conflicts with Basic and this circuit’s precedent.
III.
Whatever the merits of the majority’s belief that private securities class action procedure is in need of drastic change and revision, today’s judicially-enacted reform is, in my opinion, ill-advised and cannot be justified under current law.
Under the majority’s approach, Basic’s fraud on the market presumption is essentially a dead letter, little more than a quaint reminder of earlier times, and its primary holding is supplanted by extensions of the policy considerations that the majority sees reflected in the enactment of the PSLRA and in recent amendments to Rule 23 (neither of which actually purports to alter Basic or to speak directly to the issue in this case). Such policy considerations, however, no matter how sincerely interpreted or applied, do not give this court the authority to overrule the Supreme Court’s decisions or to change the recognized elements of a Section 10(b) claim, both of which the majority effectively does today. See Unger v. Amedisys, 401 F.3d 316, 322 n. 4 (5th Cir.2005) (“[I]t is the Supreme Court’s job to overrule Basic, in the absence of outright conflict with the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act.”)
The majority states that its “approach is unaffected by the Supreme Court’s recent and very narrow decision in Dura Pharms.[, Inc. v. Broudo, 544 U.S. 336, 125 S.Ct. 1627, 161 L.Ed.2d 577 (2005) ].” See supra at 265 n. 16. Although Dura was indeed a narrow decision, it nevertheless undercuts the majority’s position in several respects. The Dura court reaffirmed Basic, repeatedly citing it with approval, and it expressly recognized that reliance and loss causation are separate and distinct elements of the Section 10(b) cause of action,
The majority’s approach simply disregards this distinction and takes the novel step of making proof of loss causation a prerequisite to the establishment of reliance through the fraud-on-the-market presumption for purposes of certification. As neither Basic nor any authority supports the majority’s decision to conflate these two elements, I cannot subscribe to the majority’s unwarranted realignment of securities class action procedure.
IV.
Because, as the above sections demonstrate, plaintiffs are not required to prove loss causation as part of the fraud-on-the-market presumption (and because defendants make no other plausible arguments for why plaintiffs should be required to prove loss causation at the class certification stage), the majority’s decision dramatically expands the scope of class certification review in this circuit to effectively require a mini-trial on the merits of plaintiffs’ claims at the certification stage. In so doing, the decision contradicts both this circuit’s Rule 23 case law and the decisions of other circuits concerning the scope of the class certification inquiry.
Before certifying a class action, the district court must ensure that the proposed class satisfies all of the requirements of Rule 23. See, e.g., Unger, 401 F.3d at 320 (“[T]he Supreme Court requires district courts to conduct a rigorous analysis of Rule 23 prerequisites.”). We must be ever mindful, however, that class certification hearings “should not be mini-trials on the merits of the class or individual claims.” Id. at 321 (citing Eisen v. Carlisle & Jacquelin, 417 U.S. 156, 177-78, 94 S.Ct. 2140, 40 L.Ed.2d 732 (1974)). A court must conduct an “intense factual investigation,” Robinson v. Texas Automobile Dealers Association, 387 F.3d 416, 420 (5th Cir.2004), yes, and in doing so the district court must often go “beyond the pleadings” and “understand the claims, defenses, relevant facts, and applicable substantive law in order to make a meaningful determination of the certification issues.” Castano v. Am. Tobacco Co., 84 F.3d 734, 744 (5th Cir.1996). The district court cannot, however, go beyond those issues necessary to decide whether the requirements of Rule 23 are satisfied and rule on merits issues that are unrelated to Rule 23. See In re Initial Pub. Offering Sec. Litig., 471 F.3d 24, 41 (2d Cir.2006) (“[A] district judge should not assess any aspect of the merits unrelated to a Rule 23 requirement.”) (emphasis added); see also Szabo v. Bridgeport Mach., Inc., 249 F.3d 672, 677 (7th Cir.2001) (“A court may not say something like ‘let’s resolve the merits first and worry about the class later’ ... or ‘I’m not going to certify a class unless I think that the plaintiffs will prevail.’ ”).
Like the district court, we must restrict our review of the merits to encompass only those issues necessary to determining
Proof of loss causation is not related to the Rule 23 inquiry through the fraud-on-the-market presumption, and it will not, in the ordinary case, be otherwise relevant to the district court’s Rule 23 inquiry.
CONCLUSION
In my opinion, the new rule applied by the majority is an unjustified revision of securities class action procedure, based in large part upon the majority’s dramatic remolding of this court’s already problematic decision in Greenberg. In essence, the majority’s revised standard both ineor-rectly deprives plaintiffs of the benefit of the fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance afforded them by Basic and inexplicably requires them to prove the separate element of loss causation at the class certification stage.
Regardless, however, the majority does not, and cannot, show that the district court abused its discretion in certifying the class in this case, even under the majority’s novel rules. The district court carefully considered the evidence before it and concluded that the plaintiffs had established that it was more likely than not that Allegiance’s restatement of its line-count numbers caused a significant portion of the subsequent decline in Allegiance’s share price. The majority nevertheless finds the district court’s decision “untenable,” and reverses simply because it is not in keeping with the majority’s de novo assessment of the conflicting evidence.
Because I disagree with both the substance of the majority’s new rule and the legal reasoning by which it was derived, and because I can discern no abuse of discretion in the district court’s decision, I respectfully dissent.
. I have recently argued at length that Green-berg irreconcilably conflicts with both Basic and this court's prior fraud-on-the-market case law. See Regents of the Univ. of Cal. v. Credit Suisse First Boston (USA), Inc., 482 F.3d 372, 401-03 (5th Cir.2007) (Dennis, J„ concurring in the judgment).
. Unlike this case, Greenberg did not involve a motion for class certification, but was instead an appeal from a grant of summary judgment. See Greenberg, 364 F.3d at 661.
. In Regents of the University of California, I explained why Greenberg is not a correct interpretation of this court's precedent. See 482 F.3d at 401-03 (Dennis, J., concurring in the judgment).
. Greenberg purported to find that requirement in this court’s earlier decision in Nath-enson, which, on a motion to dismiss, held that "where the facts properly considered by the district court reflect that the information in question did not affect the price of the stock then the district court may properly deny fraud-on-the-market based recovery.” Nathenson, 267 F.3d at 415. As I explained in Regents of the University of California, Nathenson does not actually support the Greenberg panel's decision to give plaintiffs the affirmative burden of showing that the misrepresentation moved the market price. See 482 F.3d at 402 (Dennis, J., concurring in the judgment).
. Incidentally, it is undisputed, as the majority acknowledges, that Allegiance's share price increased substantially immediately after each of defendants’ allegedly false statements about the company's line count. See supra at 263. The majority fails utterly to explain why that price movement is insufficient to trigger the fraud-on-the-market presumption under Greenberg.
. See Dura, 544 U.S. at 341-42, 125 S.Ct. 1627 ("In cases involving publicly traded securities and purchases or sales in public securities markets, the action's basic elements include .... (4) reliance, often referred to in cases involving public securities markets (fraud-on-the-market cases) as 'transaction causation,' see Basic, supra, at 248-49, 485 U.S. 224, 108 S.Ct. 978, 99 L.Ed.2d 194 (non-conclusively presuming that the price of a publicly traded share reflects a material misrepresentation and that plaintiffs have relied upon that misrepresentation as long as they would not have bought the share in its absence); .... and (6) ‘loss, causation,' i.e., a causal connection between the misrepresentation and the loss.”).
. Moreover, I further disagree with the majority to the extent that its opinion can be read to suggest that loss causation can be established only by showing a drop in the market price of the security in response to an explicit corrective disclosure. Although this will frequently be the method through which plaintiffs attempt to prove loss causation, the Dura court specifically refrained from setting rigid requirements as to how plaintiffs might prove loss causation. See Dura, 544 U.S. at 346, 125 S.Ct. 1627 ("[W]e find the Ninth Circuit’s approach inconsistent with the law’s requirement that a plaintiff prove that the defendant's misrepresentation (or other fraudulent conduct) proximately caused the plaintiff’s economic loss. We need not, and do not, consider other proximate cause or loss-related questions.”).
. Even in cases where the defendant asserts that loss causation is an individual issue, peculiar to each plaintiff, that defeats the Rule 23 requirements of commonality or predominance, the district court need not require plaintiffs to actually prove loss causation at the class certification stage. Rather, the district court must only find either that all of the plaintiffs can prove loss causation in the same way or that any individual issues do not defeat commonality or predominance.