284 F. 287 | S.D.N.Y. | 1922
(after stating the facts as above).
This is a bill in equity, based upon the rights of property of the members of pool 1, whom the plaintiff seeks to represent. It must therefore depend upon some common interest of all the members of that pool in property which has come to the hands of the defendants. These have only cash and no coal, so that the question is irrelevant whether the members of a pool were originally, and indeed always remained, co-owners of all the coal in that pool, or whether they or the exchange had title to it. The collections here in suit arose out of loans or sales of coal made by the commissioner, with the con
It will first be necessary to analyze the rules of the exchange, so as to learn under what right these collections arose and whether they are the proceeds of coal tortiously converted. If so, the plaintiff’s right to treat them in equity as still their own would seem to follow, and the equity of the bill to be established. And indeed it would not follow that the bill must fail, even if the collections are not the proceeds of converted coal; that is a quite independent question, depending upon what intent one must spell out of the general structure of the association. It is essential to the solution of both these questions that the plan should be exposed so far as it is relevant to the overdrawing of coal. I think that it appears beyond controversy that the members always intended- on occasion to loan or sell to pool members a part of the pool coal.
The rules (old rule 9 and new rule 22) from the outset gave power to the commissioner to allow single members of any pool to overdraw. Indeed, new rule 22 allowed him to authorize a member to assign to another more than he had in the pool, thus extending his original authority. This, of course, must always have resulted in making the pool insolvent in coal and dependent for its ultimate liquidation upon the responsibility of the withdrawing member. Old rule 12 enacted that a member’s overdrafts in any pool might not be made up by his surpluses in other pools, and until its amendment by the promulgation of new rule 23 it might any way be argued that it forbade a hotchpot of all his holdings in all pools, even upon final liquidation of his accounts. But new rule 23 was especially limited in its application to the period during which a member should not neglect to make up his shortages, here referring I think to rule 28, and the inference is inevitable that, if he did so neglect, his account in one pool should have some “bearing” upon that in others.
To learn what in that event the “bearing” of his account in other pools should be, we should look to new rule 28, which is old rule 10, somewhat clarified, but not in my judgment really changed. At any rate it is the new rules which govern this case, because at the end of February, 1920, the plaintiff had itself overdrawn about 1,000 tons of coal, and the new rules went into effect on April 24, 1919. Now new rule 28 provides for the closing of members’ accounts, when there are unadjusted “differences” between the amount of coal shipped by a member and ,that delivered under his orders. If these are not “adjusted,” either by shipping more coal or getting assignments from other members, the executive committee shall “name a price * * * for the tonnage involved.” Nothing is said as to what shall be done to collect, although the means adopted, in which Carpenter concurred, was to threaten suit; but it is provided that, “after settlement has been
If one follows out this language in its necessary application, it will appear that the accounts of the delinquent members, who fail to restore in kind or by assignment (as primarily they are bound to do), must be liquidated on a hotchpot of all their accounts, the rule thus fitting in with the addition made to rule 12, when new rule 23 was drafted. For example, if a member has deficiencies in pools 1, 2, and 3, and surpluses in pools 4, 5, and 6, it would be his duty under new rule 23 to restore his position in pools 1, 2, and 3, regardless of his surpluses. But when he neglects “to make up existing shortages,” and so ignores his primary obligation, new rule 23 ceases to apply, and his account in one pool begins to have a “bearing” on his accounts in others. Thereupon the time arrives to “close” his account, and the executive committee must name prices at which both deficiencies and surpluses can be commuted into money. After he has “settled” on these prices, the commissioner must enter the propeí debits and credits. The “settlement” cannot mean the payment into pools 1, 2, and 3 of his deficiencies: First, because new rule 23 has ceased to apply; and, second, because that could never require the commissioner to enter any “debits.” Each payment would be a credit to the member in that pool in which it was made, and would balance his account in that pool. If, however, he paid only his net balance in all the pools, it would become necessary for the commissioner to debit his account in pools 4, 5, and 6 with the commuted value of his surplus, and credit his accounts in pools 1, 2, and 3, not only with the cash actually paid, but with the same commuted value of the surpluses which were debited in pools 4, S, and 6.
There seems to me no doubt that this is what new rule 28 means, and that the total result of all three rules, taken as a part of the general plan of the exchange, was therefore as follows: The members primarily meant to organize an association which should merely classify and mingle their coal into separate masses, of which they were presumptively to remain co-owners. There is no sufficient reason to suppose that they intended the title to pass to the exchange. So, far, their purposes were the same as in the Take Erie pool, which had served in general as a model for the exchange.
Such was the plant or structure, and it is entirely irrelevant that all the accounts were kept in coal up to the time of closing. They could not have been kept in anything else until that time came, under new rules 23 and 28. If so, it makes no difference, as I have already said, whether or not the coal in the pool continued to be a mass of fungible9 held in common, and the authorities on that question need not be considered. The only relevant question is whether, after a delinquent member had “settled” and paid, and after the proper debits and credits had been entered, the property so obtained was owned by the several pools in the proportions of their credits, or whether it was general assets of the exchange. The property, it will be observed, is cash paid in and surpluses cff coal in other pools. The alternatives are these: Either to regard the money and the surplus as owned by the exchange as a unit, or as shared in by the several creditor pools in the proportions of their credits.
Eet me assume the second and try to work out the resulting situation. Suppose, for example, that an accounting member was a debtor to pool 1 for $5,000, to pool 2 for $10,000, to pool 3 for $15,000, and had credits in pool 4 for $4;000, in pool 5 for $5,000, and in pool 6 for $6,000. He would pay $15,000 to the Exchange, which would be deposited in a bank. If the plaintiff is right, pools, 1, 2, and 3 would be co-owners of this $15,000 in proportions of one-sixth, one-third, and one-half, and of the member’s coal surpluses in pools 4, 5, and 6. But if the matter is to be treated in this way a further complication presents itself: The surplus of the supposed member in pools 4, 5, and 6 would be wholly a coal surplus only in case those pools were themselves solvent in coal. Suppose, however, that overdrafts had been allowed to members in those pools also. Then obviously the surpluses of the accounting member would in part be themselves made up of the claims against withdrawing members of pools 4, 5, and 6. But the withdrawing members of pools 4, 5, and 6 might in turn have surpluses in pools 1, 2, and 3, which must, upon settling their accounts, be credited to pools 4, 5, and 6, and debited against pools 1, 2, and 3. Therefore, if the property were to be treated as divided between the pools, each pool sharing in some ascertainable proportion in the collections, it might, and probably would, happen that part of the property which pools 1, 2, and 3 would hold as co-owners would be coal held in those pools themselves, but in progressively complicated proportions. It is obvious that further complications would arise in carrying out this theory, which would end in a maze of bewildering cross-allocations.
The resources and ingenuity of accountants are large, and I will not say that it is impossible to figure exactly in what proportions the several pools would become co-owners in the balances received and in the surpluses in the several pools after the members had all accounted. Yet in interpreting the intention of men of affairs we must, of course, assume that their purposes are practical, and do not gratuitously in
In the case at bar it seems to me extremely unreal to impute to the members of this exchange a purpose so difficult of realization, and one which, if realizable at all, could be fulfilled only by the most complicated calculations. Rather I think one should assume that, when the commissioner allowed a member to withdraw coal from a pool, it was expected that although, if the member restored in coal, it would of course go back into the pool, if he defaulted, his monetary obligations were between him and the exchange as a whole. While for many purposes the pools were separate, it must always be remembered that the exchange was a single association, governed by one executive committee and by one commissioner, with his deputies, who had general supervision over all pools. I find it very hard to suppose that in the face of rule 10 (new rule 28), and especially of the amendment of rule 12 (new rule 23), the settlement of his accounts was to be on any other basis than as a creditor to the whole exchange. Certainly in form the settlement was meant to be just that, and the imposition upon that form of the pattern of a number of mutually independent co-owning pools should be supported by convincing proof, which I do not find either in the rules or in the practice under them.
There does not seem to me any inherent improbability that the members should have been willing to accept jointly the risk of the financial responsibility of those who might not restore in kind — rather the contrary. No one could be sure that he would be a net creditor in any single pool, presumably all would have transactions in more than one. The plaintiff’s change in two months from a deficiency of 1,000 tons to a surplus of over 2,000 is a glaring instance of what might happen. Indeed, owing to the constant reclassification of the pools, a member who shipped the product of only one mine or one vein might find his shipments, this month in one pool, and the next in another. Nor was it conceivably possible to know in advance what the standing of any member in his several pools would be when his account was closed. It would therefore be altogether erroneous to look at the creditor members of any given pool on April 30, 1920, as a separate class, who had all along been the creditors in that pool and that alone. They were in no sense a group of persons dealing only among themselves, and not coincident in any way with the members of other pools. On.the contrary, they were all members of the exchange, always, or at least often, in several pools at the same time, as debtors in one and creditors in the other, with their rights dependent upon their own several surpluses and deficiencies, and upon the uncertain and variable surpluses and
In view of these shifting and interconnected relations there is no reason to suppose that the members intended the risk of insolvency of an overdrawing member to be borne by the pool members of the par- • ticular pool from which he drew. Being presumptively members of some other pools, they were in one aspect his creditors, and in another debtors to themselves for his surpluses, and the amount of each item would remain variable and indeterminate. The more reasonable interpretation is, I think, to regard each withdrawing member as an eventual debtor of the whole group, which must collectively bear the losses arising from his insolvency.
Although the consequences of this feature of the plant were not before him, Carpenter, the plaintiff’s vice president, certainly understood that in his own dealings with the exchange all accounts were to be brought into hotchpot, and he settled on that basis. -The plaintiff can now scarcely take a different position; but, if it can, it is certainly not a negligible consideration that, when the matter came up, it assumed, and acted on the assumption, that the liquidation was to be- conducted with the Exchange as a whole. Furthermore Carpenter took part without dissent in the proceedings of the executive committee, either in person or by a proxy whose doings were afterwards brought to his notice, under which the settlements were liquidated in the same way.
¡None of the authorities cited touch the only questions which I deem material. I have assumed that the pool members retained their interests in the coal shipped to the separate pools. The plaintiff may be right as to that; it is not necessary to consider whether the mere right of the commissioner to permit withdrawals affected their title. But we are dealing with coal which the commissioner did sell or loan, and sell or loan with authority. There can be no question as to the title of that coal; it passed to the withdrawing- members. No case that I know throws any light on the question whether the resulting chose in action belonged to a separate pool, or to the exchange as a whole. For the reasons already given, I conclude that the final money payment did not.
The bill will be dismissed, with costs.
It. is, however, to be observed, that even tbe Lake Erie pool had a rule (rule 4), which provided for the fixing of prices when a member was overdrawn. The possible application of that rale is not apparent, but it shows at least that even in that pool overdrafts were in contemplation.