45 Minn. 272 | Minn. | 1891
This appeal is from an order overruling a demurrer to the complaint, and the sole question is whether it appears that the contract declared on is void on grounds of public policy as being in restraint of trade. The plaintiff, an Illinois corporation, and the defendant, a Wisconsin corporation, were each organized for and engaged in the same business, to wit, “issuing and selling, to such persons as might desire to purchase the same, certificates entitling the holders thereof, when sick or injured, to maintenance and to medical and surgical care, attention, and treatment in any hospital provided by said corporation, and to such support during the time said holder might be confined in such hospitals; and to provide hospitals, infirmaries, and such other places as might be necessary for the reception of the holders of the certificates issued by it, without cost other than
Shortly stated, the legal effect of this contract was á sale by plaintiff, for a valuable consideration, to defendant, of its business and good-will within the territory mentioned, (except the right to sell certificates to railroad employes,) with a stipulation that it would refrain from engaging in such business within that territory for three years, and a like stipulation on part of defendant not to engage in the department of the business reserved by plaintiff. It will be observed that the restriction is not general, but limited both as to space and time, and is only co-extensive in space with the business transferred. Also, that the contract does not require either company to wholly refrain from engaging in the business for which it was organized, each remaining free to engage in it without restriction any
We feel safe in asserting that no modern decision can be found holding any such contract, under a similar state of facts, void because in restraint of trade. Formerly in England the courts frowned with great severity upon every contract of this kind. The reasons for this partly grew out of the English law of apprenticeship, by which,, in its original severity, no person could exercise any regular trade or handicraft except after having served a long apprenticeship. Hence, if a person was prevented from pursuing his particular trade, he was practically deprived of all means of earning a livelihood, and the state was deprived of his services. No such reason now obtains in this country, where every citizen is at liberty to change his occupation at will. Moreover, as cheaper and more rapid facilities for travel and transportation gradually changed the manner of doing business, so as to enable parties to conduct it over a vastly greater territory .than formerly, the courts were necessarily compelled to readjust the test or standard of the reasonableness of restrictions as to place. And again, modern investigations have much modified the views of courts as well as political economists as to the effect of contracts tending to reduce the number of competitors in any particular line of business. Excessive competition is not now-accepted as necessarily conducive to the public good. The fact is that the early common-law doctrine in regard to contracts in restraint of trade largely grew out of a state of society and of business which has ceased to exist,
The general consensus of all the authorities, at least the later ones, is that there is no hard and fast rule as to what contracts are void as being in restraint of trade, but.each case must be judged according t6 its own facts and circumstances; that a party may-legally purchase the business and trade of another for the very purpose of removing or'preventing competition, coupled with an undertaking on the part of the seller not to carry on the same business in the same place or within the same territory; and the question of the reasonableness of tne restraint of trade depends upon whether it is such only as to afford a fair protection to the party in whose favor it is made; and the limits of restraint as to space depend upon the kind of trade or business which is the subject of the contract. Tested by these rules we nnd nothing legally objectionable in the contract under consideration. In addition to eases cited above, see, also, Moore Hardware Co. v. Towers Hardware Co., 87 Ala. 206, (6 South. Rep. 41.) There are two classes of cases, some of which appellant has cited, which are’ often confounded with, but are clearly distinguishable- from, cases like the present, and stand upon an entirely different footing. The one is combinations between producers or dealers to limit the production or supply of an article, so as to acquire a monopoly of it and then unreasonably enhance prices. The other is where a corporation of a quasi public character, charged with a public duty, as
Order affirmed.
Vanderburgh, J., took no part in this case.