Lead Opinion
Suit by appellant, an abutting property owner, to enjoin the letting of a contract for a street improvement.
The complaint avers that tbe city’s board of public works adopted a resolution for the improvement of the street by paving with brick; that afterward, upon tbe petition of a majority of tbe resident freeholders on the street sought to be improved, tbe resolution, plans and specifications were modified so as to provide Warren’s patent bitulitbie pavement. Tbe resolution,, modification and detailed specifications are set out in tbe complaint. It is also' averred that all tbe steps preliminary to tbe letting of tbe contract have been duly taken; that tbe board advertised for bids, and threatens to and will, unless enjoined, let tbe contract and have tbe work done, to tbe irreparable injury of appellant. It is further averred that tbe pavement specified is a patented pavement covered by letters patent of tbe United States; that there can be no competition in such work, and that an unlawful monopoly is necessarily created by making such improvement with a patented pavement; that there was no necessity for its selection by tbe board, for tbe reason that there are many other as good and durable modern first-class accepted pavements not covered by patent, and not controlled by any monopoly; that tbe cost of tbe improvement will be greatly increased by tbe use of such patented pavement, and appellant’s property assessed for more than it will be if competition is bad.
Appellees answered, alleging that tbe resolution was modified upon tbe petition of a majority of tbe property owners; that tbe pavement in question is one of tbe accepted modern city pavements, and has been laid in many cities of this and other states; that its cost is approximately the same
Section ninety-five of the act of March 6, 1905 (Acts 1905, pp. 219, 281, §3519 Burns 1905), provides: “Such board shall * * * let such contract to the lowest and best bidder.” Section 107 of said act (Acts 1905, pp. 219,
(1) The question presented by the complaint may be briefly stated thus: Does an improvement which is covered by letters patent permit the competition provided for by section ninety-five, supra? If this question is answered in the affirmative, it is unnecessary to consider any question raised by the answer, for the reason that if there may be competitive bidding for a pavement covered by letters jDatent, the complaint is bad.
6. It must be admitted that the same reasoning that excludes a patented pavement would exclude a pavement not patented, but which is owned and controlled by a single individual. No logical reason can be given for saying that there could not be competitive bidding for a patented pavement, and that there could be competitive bidding for a pavement not patented, but monopolized by a company or individual. If the owner of the pavement sought to be used has and retains “the exclusive right and liberty to make and use and vend to others to be used” what is desired, what possible difference can it make, so far as it affects the question here considered, whether this exclusive privilege is because of a patent or because of circumstances ? And when it is said, as it is in the argument, that the rule deprives municipalities of the use of such patented articles, no difference how beneficial they may be to the public, and that where the best interests of the muncipality will be subserved by the use of a patented article the provision for competitive bidding has no application, then it must also be said that this provision has no application if the best interests of the municipality will be served by the use of an article controlled absolutely by a single individual. The result of this reasoning must necessarily be that in any case the provision for competitive bidding may be nullified or ignored if the best interests of the municipality in the particular case will be subserved by so doing.
Upon the question above considered, the courts are not agreed. The case of Hobart v. City of Detroit (1868), 17 Mich. *246, 97 Am. Dec. 185, decides the question in the affirmative, and the case of Dean v. Charlton (1869), 23 Wis. 590, 99 Am. Dec. 205, decides the same question in the negative. These two cases were the pioneer cases on the subject. Upon the precise question presented by the complaint in the case at bar neither of these cases has been disapproved or modified in the respective jurisdictions in which decided. In a subsequent case (Kilvington v. City of Superior [1892], 83 Wis. 222, 53 N. W. 487, 18 L. R. A. 45), the Wisconsin court did not disapprove Dean v. Charlton> supra, but declined “to extend the rule of that case beyond the particular point there decided.” The courts in other jurisdictions are not agreed upon the question, but the better reasoning will be found underlying the rule declared by the Wisconsin court.
The doctrine of Hobart v. City of Detroit, supra, is followed in Holmes v. Common Council (1899), 120 Mich. 226, 79 N. W. 200, 45 L. R. A. 121, 77 Am. St. 587; Barber Asphalt Pav. Co. v. Hunt (1889), 100 Mo. 22, 13 S. W. 98, 8 L. R. A. 110, 18 Am. St. 530; In re Petition of Dugro (1872), 50 N. Y. 513; Yarnold v. City of Lawrence (1875), 15 Kan. 126; Verdin v. City of St. Louis
The cases of Beazley v. Kennedy (1899), (Tenn.), 52 S. W. 791, Silsby Mfg. Co. v. Allentown (1893), 153 Pa. St. 319, 26 Atl. 646, and Baird v. Mayor, etc. (1884), 96 N. Y. 567, involved the right of the municipality to purchase patented or monopolized articles for municipal, uses.
In Hobart v. City of Detroit, supra, a lot owner sued to enjoin the collection of a tax levied to pay the expense of paving the street with the Nicolson pavement- — patented— alleging that the contract for the pavement was illegal. The city charter provided that no such contract should be let “except to and with the lowest responsible bidder.” The right to lay the pavement was owned exclusively by Smith, Oook & Co., the contractors, who alone, therefore, it is claimed, could and did bid for the contract, and, there being no possibility of a competitor, the contract was awarded to them on their own terms; and this exclusive right precluded the application of this charter provision. Upon the question of whether there should be competitive bidding in such a case the court said: “But it is not, I apprehend, strictly correct to say that because the patented invention which must be made use of is owned by one person exclusively, therefore, no one else can be a bidder. Every one has a right to bid, and to take upon himself the risk of being able to procure the right to make use of the invention.”
In Hobart v. City of Detroit, supra, it is further said: “If that firm held the privilege of putting down the pavement for sale at a regular price per square foot or yard, the opportunity to bid for a public contract would be as much open to public competition as for any other work requiring skilled labor. For aught we know, this was the case; and we may well take notice of the fact that it is frequently by thus selling the ‘royalty’ that the owners of new inventions expect to obtain their reward.”
In Hastings v. Columbus (1885), 42 Ohio St. 585, suit was brought against the city and certain lot owners seeking to charge the lot owners with the cost of a patented pavement. The court said: “Objection is made that each of these improvements required a species of pavement which was patented; that the contractors, in each case, owned the patent; and hence that there was no competition, and defendants can not be assessed. But in each case, before there was any letting, the city had acquired the right to secure, at a reasonable cost, the right of such patent, with respect to this improvement, for any successful bidder for the work, and the bidders were placed by the city, in this respect, substantially on equal terms. We think the objection untenable.” The character of the agreement with the city referred to in this case does not appear, but it would not be material whether the city purchased the right to use
The question decided in Kilvington v. City of Superior (1892), 83 Wis. 222, 53 N. W. 487, 18 L. R. A. 45, is unlike the question presented by the answer in the case at bar in two respects: (a) The improvement was made at the expense of the municipality; and (h) the patentee, without any reservation, relinquished to any contractor who took the contract the right to use the patent at a fixed sum.
We think the rule should be that where the patentee retains the exclusive right to use and to sell to he used ,by others the patented pavement, and he has this right as ■ a patentee, a contract for such pavement to be paid for by abutting property owners cannot be entered into, for the reason that in such case competitive bidding within the plain intent and meaning of the statute cannot be had. But this rule should not and does not exclude the use of a patented pavement. We are not required in this case to indicate the manner in which it may be done, but upon the showing made by the answer, for the reasons given, there could not be the competitive bidding the statute requires. The demurrer to the answer should have been sustained.
Judgment reversed.
Dissenting Opinion
Dissenting Opinion.
I can not concur in the conclusion announced in the prevailing opinion, nor in the reasoning leading to that conclusion. The rights of the parties must be determined by applying the law to the facts as they are exhibited by the pleadings in this particular case. I am unable to assent to the doctrine that because the process for paving Northwestern avenue, adopted by the board upon the petition of a majority of the property owners, happens
The conclusion reached in the prevailing opinion involves and decides two important propositions: (1) That a patented pavement may be contracted for and used, and abutting property assessed in payment thereof. (2) That where the patentee retains the exclusive right to use and to sell, to be used by others, the patented process, a contract for such pavement, to be paid for by assessments against the abutting property, cannot be entered into, because in such case competitive bidding, within the plain intent and meaning of the statutes governing the city of Indianapolis, can not be had.
The latter proposition is inconsistent with the former, for the reason that the value of a patent is the exclusive right which the patentee or owner possesses to use and control it. If he yields that right the value of his patent is destroyed.
The two propositions are inconsistent for another reason, which is apparent from a statement in the opinion. It is said “that if there may be competitive bidding for a pavement covered by letters patent, the complaint is bad.”
The ruling that a patented pavement may be used includes the primary rule which requires competitive bidding, for it is upon that rule that a valid contract may be entered into. If my associates are right, there can be no competitive bidding where the patentee owns and controls the patent, even though he yields to all bidders the right to use it upon equal terms. So the vital question here is: Do the facts pleaded preclude competition in bidding for the proposed improvement ? If they do, then the judgment pronounced on appeal is correct. I affirm, however, that this inquiry should be answered in the negative.
Upon the former hearing of this case the' sufficiency of the complaint was not considered. As it is now ruled by the majority opinion that a patented pavement may be used, the complaint in this case is fatally defective, unless it affirmatively appears from the facts pleaded that there can be no competition in bidding for the work. The holding that a valid contract for the construction of a pavement covered by a patent may be made embraces the concession that competitive bidding may be had. Therefore, under the rule declared, it necessarily, reasonably and logically follows that because a patented pavement is adopted competitive bidding may be had. What is there in the complaint upon which the court can declare as a rule of law that competitive bidding is stifled, and enjoin the board of public works from proceeding to let the contract ? It must affirmatively appear from the complaint that there can be no competition, or the complaint is bad. The only averment I can find that pertains to this particular question is the following: “That said bitulithic pavement provided for in said resolution, for' which said contract will be let, and with which said improvement will be made, unless an injunction is granted, is a patented pavement covered by letters patent of the United States; that there is no authority for improving streets in said city with a patented pavement, and that there can be no competition in such work, and an unlawful monopoly is necessarily created by making such improvement with a patented pavement.”
It is conceded that there must be competition, and it is also conceded that a valid contract for improving a street with a patented pavement may be made. This being true, I am unable to see how my associates arrived at the conclusion that from the facts stated in the complaint there could be no competition, and hence the complaint held good.
With the concession that the mere fact that the proposed improvement was covered by a patent does not prevent competition, and indulging the presumption that the board of public works would discharge its duty according to law, there can be no presumption that a contract would have been let without competition. Under the reasoning in the case of Hobart v. City of Detroit (1868), 17 Mich. *246, 97 Am. Dec. 185, and all the cases following the rule there declared (I will advert to them later), it should be presumed that the patented pavement can be procured in the open market, or that the patentee will grant to any sue
In legal effect, as touching the question of competition, there can be no difference between a patent and a natural monopoly. Neither of them is illegal, as I will attempt to show later in' this opinion. If the .presumption is that a patented article or a natural monopoly may- be obtained from the owner so there may be competition in bidding, and I think this is a reasonable presumption, then the complaint is bad, because there are no affirmative allegations showing that there can be no competition. A single illustration will demonstrate the force of the proposition.
Suppose a gravel road is to be constructed. There is but one gravel bed within reasonable contiguity to the road, and such gravel bed is owned and controlled by one man. There is a fixed and known price at which the gravel may be purchased, and without it can be procured the improvement can not be made. Suppose the petition for the improvement has been granted, the specifications have been adopted, and advertisement made for bids. A property owner whose land is liable to assessment brings a suit to enjoin the letting of a contract, and bases his right for equitable relief upon the fact that the gravel is owned by one man; that it can only be procured from him; that it is a natural monopoly; and avers that “there can be no competition for such work.” Under such facts would any court hold his complaint good, and grant him the relief asked ? I think not, and yet the illustration presents the same case in principle as the complaint at bar.
Here it is sought to enjoin the use of a patented process because there can be no competition, while in the illustra
In view of the fact that the legislature has conferred upon property owners the right to designate, by petition, the kind of pavement they desire, provided it is of the modern, accepted kind, and in view of the fact that the board of public works is prohibited from proceeding with the improvement by the construction of any other kind of a pavement, it occurs to me that the prevailing opinion establishes a precedent, by which all street improvements could be blocked.
The statute declares that the contract for the improvement must be let to the lowest and best bidder. As to who is the lowest and best bidder is a question for the board of public works, and not a question for the courts. Its determination of that question, in the absence of fraud, is final, and such letting presupposes that there will be competitive bidding.
Eor the reasons stated, I think the complaint is bad. This being true, if the answer is bad, as declared in the majority opinion, it is good enough for a bad complaint, and the demurrer to it should have been carried back and sustained to the complaint. In my judgment the facts pleaded in the answer constitute a complete defense in bar to the complaint, and my associates have not correctly construed all of the terms and conditions of the agreement of the owners of the patented process, filed with the board, and upon which the answer is partly based. The facts pleaded, both in the complaint and answer, are so fully stated in the majority opinion that it is unnecessary for me to restate them here.
In the improvement of a public street there are elements of labor, skill, etc., which enter into it, other than the material with which it is finished and surfaced. It is conceded in this case that any bidder who may procure the contract for the improvement of the street in question can obtain from the patentee the right to use the patented process, at a fixed price per square yard. This opens the door to all bidders, and they stand upon an equality in that regard, The work of grading the street and preparing it for the patented process, as well as all incidental work, is open to all bidders. The work, labor and skill required to place the patented process upon the prepared grade is also open to competition. Every step in the progress of the work,
The standard cements used in the construction of sidewalks, asphalt pavements, etc., have a fixed commercial value that can be procured alike by all purchasers. Tet, because of such fact, competition is not destroyed, where such products are used in public works and enterprises. The elements of labor, conditions, facilities, etc., must all be considered, for they all enter into the question under consideration.
I am firmly convinced that where a street is to be improved, and the proper authority, as in this case, decides, upon the petition of the majority in number of the abutting property owners, the kind of improvement to be made, and though the improvement provides for a pavement which
It is averred in the answer that the pavement ordered by the modification of the original resolution is an accepted
Another element brought into this case by the statute, which was not present in any of the decided cases, is that when the original resolution shall have been confirmed or modified, “it shall be final and conclusive on all persons, unless, within ten days thereafter, a majority of the resident freeholders on such street * * * remonstrate against such improvement.” The statute confers upon the majority of the resident lot owners the right to select the kind of a pavement to be used, and for which their property is to be assessed for payment. When they have exercised that right, as provided by statute, the board of public works is shorn of its power to order any other kind of an improvement. The legislature certainly had the right to let the resident freeholders have a patented pavement, if they wanted it, if they should bring themselves within the provisions of the statute. Certain it is that there is nothing in the statute which even remotely or impliedly excludes such pavement.
All that is required by the statute is that after the resident freeholders have made their selection, the board must, upon proper notice, invite bids. If there is more than one bidder, then there is competition, except in the case of fraud
The statute safeguards the property owners and municipality in various ways. Thus it is provided that no contract shall be let which shall be more than ten per cent in excess of the estimate of the engineer, nor where the total cost of the improvement shall exceed fifty per cent of the aggregate value of the property to be assessed. Also that the board may, and in this case does, reserve the right to reject any and all bids. The statute also provides that each bidder shall file with his bid an affidavit of noncollusion.
Again, it is provided that “such board shall, if a satisfactory bid be received, let such contract to the lowest and best bidder.” §3519 Burns 1905. See §§95, 107, Acts 1905, supra.
It will be presumed that public officers will do their duty, and in a case of this character it will be presumed that the board would not let the contract except to the lowest and best bidder, and in the event the bid was satisfactory.
The statute (§107, supra) further provides that upon confirmation of the resolution, or upon its modification, “it shall be final and conclusive upon all persons, unless within ten days thereafter, a majority of the resident freeholders * * * remonstrate against such improvement.” In this ease there was no remonstrap.ee. The action of the board being final, the query suggests itself: Has not appellant slept on his rights, there being no fraud or collusion charged? I shall not pause to discuss this feature of the case, but merely say that it appeals to me with some force.
As above stated, the authorities upon the question for decision are not in accord.
In the more recent case of Holmes v. Common Council (1899), 120 Mich. 226, 79 N. W. 200, 45 L. R. A. 121, 77 Am. St. 587, the supreme court of Michigan had before it the same question in principle. I quote from the opinion as follows: “Complainants’ proposition seems to be that, under the charter, no paving contract shall be let which involves the use of any material which, by reason of its exclusive production, is not subject to competition, or perhaps, more accurately, complainants’ claim is that such contract can not be made for the use of such material except when it had been subjected to a competition.with some other material. This would result in some serious consequences. If such is the rule, the city may be denied the right to have the pavement that it wants, because some one is willing to furnish something else, that may be thought equally good, for a less price. One or two blocks of a street may be paved with Eelsonville brick, but, when it is desired to extend the pavement, they can not take bids, and proceed to pave with the same, if some other brick can be obtained cheaper. It may be that the cheaper price is made by interested parties, at a loss, to injure a rival, or for some other ulterior purpose, or because of insolvency, or it may be untried brick, or it may happen that the competing brick is not likely to be thereafter obtainable for repairs. Bxit this would make no difference; the city must be subjected to these dangers and inconveniences, because it can obtain a lower bid: Thus, a pavement would be likely to be of a variegated pattern. This doctrine, carried out to its logical
In Swift v. City of St. Louis (1904), 180 Mo. 80, 79 S. W. 172, the right to contract for paving a street with “Warren’s Puritan Brand” of cement (being same here involved) was under consideration, and it was held that when at the
In Barber Asphalt Pav. Co. v. Hunt (1889), 100 Mo. 22, 13 S. W. 98, 8 L. R. A. 110, 18 Am. St. 530, it was held that the city of St. Louis was not prohibited from letting a contract to pave a street with material covered by letters patent. In that case it was further held that to rule otherwise would be to deprive the city of the right to enjoy the benefits of modern invention.
The same question was again before the court in the case of Verdin v. City of St. Louis (1895), 131 Mo. 26, 33 S. W. 480, 36 S. W. 52, and the holding in the case of Barber Asphalt Pav. Co. v. Hunt, supra, was reaffirmed, and the doctrine as to a patented material was even extended to a material whereof the owner had a monopoly by reason of his exclusive ownership of such material.
A case possibly most directly in point is that of Hastings v. Columbus (1885), 42 Ohio St. 585. There the city let a contract to pave a street with a patented pavement. It was urged that the contractors owned the patent, and for that reason there could be no competition in bidding, and hence no valid assessment could be made against abutting lots. Before the contract was let, however, the city had acquired the right to secure, at a reasonable cost, the right of such patent, with respect to the improvement, for any successful bidder for the work. It was held that under such facts bidders were placed by the city, in this respect,
Field v. Barber Asphalt Pav. Co. (1902), 117 Fed. 925, is in point. There the city of Westport, Missouri, let a contract to pave a street, and the contract called for “Lake Trinidad Asphalt.” In the course of the opinion Mr. Justice McPherson said: “There is evidence tending to show that good asphalt, and quite as good as Trinidad, can be obtained from Bermuda, Mexico, and from places in the United States. On such facts it is contended that the city had no right to limit the contract to Trinidad, and that in so doing the commerce clause of the Constitution was violated, and that the federal anti-trust statutes were likewise violated. And this argument is emphasized by complainant’s counsel, because, as he contends, the defendant has a monopoly of Trinidad asphalt. The evidence does not show this to be so. But, if it does have the monopoly, I do not believe the point is well taken. Any individual certainly has the right, in the erection of an improvement, to get that which he believes the best, and that which he prefers, regardless of the reason; and he should not defeat a recovery by showing that in fact something else was as good or better, or that the vender had a monopoly. And why should not the same holding be made as to a city? Can it be so that because the city concludes, although wrongly, that Trinidad is the best asphalt, that its contract must be canceled on a showing that the Trinidad is not the best, and that it is the subject of a monopoly? Why limit the evidence to other asphalts ? Why not receive
In Newark v. Bonnell (1894), 57 N. J. L. 424, 31 Atl. 408, 51 Am. St. 609, it was held that where the proper municipal board advertises in good faith for proposals for paving streets, and specifies the employment of the material deemed to be for the best interests of the municipality, the city is not debarred by any rule of law from contracting for what it wants, merely because the desired material is the subject of private ownership or the product of exclusive manufacture.
To the same effect is the case of Ryan v. Patterson (1901), 66 N. J. L. 533, 49 Atl. 587. The pavement there ordered was to be of the standard of Trinidad lake asphalt. The court said: “If it appears that the action of the city •authorities was taken in an honest belief that to award the contract as they did was for the best interests of the public, it will not be disturbed, even though the court, on a review of the same facts, may think that another conclusion would have been justified. The law places the obligation upon the municipal authorities, and not upon the court, and where there are facts which show their action to be consistent with an honest judgment the court should not interfere. Van Reipen v. Jersey City [1895], 58 N. J. L. 262, 268, 33 Atl. 740; Findley v. City of Pittsburg [1876], 82 Pa. St. 351; Ferguson v. Passaic [1897], 60 N. J. L. 404, 38 Atl. 676. In Oakley v. Allantic City [1899], 63 N. J. L. 127, 44 Atl. 651, Mr. Justice Lippincott stated the mile in this wise: Tn the absence of fraud or palpable abuse of discretion on the part of the municipal authorities in the exercise of the power granted by the legislature, the only question for judicial cognizance is whether there has been any violation of legal principles or neglect of prescribed formalities in entering into the engagement which is the subject of the controversy.’ ”
The following New York cases, it seems to me, are in substantial harmony with those I have cited: Baird v. Mayor, etc. (1884), 96 N. Y. 567, 582, 583; In re Petition of Dugro (1872), 50 N. Y. 513 ; Harlem Gas Light Co. v. Mayor, etc. (1865), 33 N. Y. 309; People, ex rel., v. Van Nort (1872), 64 Barb. 205; People, ex rel., v. Flagg (1858), 17 N. Y. 584.
In Dolan v. Mayor, etc. (1868), 4 Abb. Prac. (N. S.) 397, it was held in the special term of the supreme court that a patented pavement could not be used. On appeal to the general term, reported in the New York Daily Transcript of February 8, 1869, the decision of the special term was reversed, the court holding upon the authority of the ease of In re Petition of Dugro, supra, that a patented pavement could be used. The cause was appealed to the court of appeals, and was affirmed per curiam, with an opinion. Dolan v. Mayor, etc. (1876), 67 N. Y. 609.
The decision of the general term reversing the decision of the special term has some pertinent observations, which I desire here to quote: “In the former of these cases a resolution and ordinance had been passed to pave Thirty-third street with Nicolson pavement, and an injunction was granted to prevent such pavement. In the second case a similar ordinance had been passed to pave Seventh avenue with Stafford pavement, and an injunction was granted to prevent the same. The injunction on argument before the
The question of the right of a city to improve its streets with a patented pavement is reviewed by an able author (Mr. A. R. Watson), in 20 Am. and Eng. Ency. Law (2d ed.), 1166. I quote as follows therefrom: “Two views have been taken of the effect of a provision requiring advertisements and bids for patented articles or articles or materials controlled by a monopoly. One is that municipal corporations are thereby precluded from requiring articles or materials with reference to which there can not be free competition in the bidding! The other and far more preferable view is that where the best interests of the city will be subserved by the use of a patented article or an article controlled by a monopoly, procurable from only one source, the provision in question has no application whatever, the case being without its spirit and intention. Another doctrine seems to require advertisements for bids,
The New York street-improvement case, to which I have referred, directly involving the right to use a patented pavement, is in harmony with the above quotation. McQuillin, Mun. Ordinances, §554.
It is stated that the tendency of the courts favors the adoption of the Michigan rather than the Wisconsin rule. The opinion of Justice Brewer in Yarnold v. City of Lawrence (1875), 15 Kan. 126, expressly approves the Michigan case (Hobart v. City of Detroit [1868], 17 Mich. *246, 97 Am. Dec. 185) and disapproves the ’ Wisconsin case. (Dean v. Charlton [1869], 23 Wis. 590, 99 Am. Dec. 205). I find, therefore, that there are at least eight jurisdictions in which the old Wisconsin rule is disapproved and the Michigan rule is followed, in which jurisdictions it is now settled that a patented jaavement may be used, notwithstanding a statutory provision which requires competitive bidding. It will be thus observed that the Michigan rule has been adopted by a larger number of the courts of last resort in the United States than has the Wisconsin rule, and the cases which support the Michigan rule are far more numerous than the other. The supreme court of Michigan still follows the case of Hobart v. City of Detroit, supra. See Attorney-General v. Detroit (1872), 26 Mich. 263; Holmes v. Common Council (1899), 120 Mich. 226, 79 N. W. 200, 45 L. R. A. 121, 77 Am. St. 587.
The latter case is a well-reasoned one, and is on all fours with the case in hand. The opinion in that case closes with the following: “We think the law is complied with, in the absence of actual fraud or corruption, when specifications are submitted to competitive bidding, although some article is specified which, by reason of a patent or circumstances, is in the hands or under the control of a single dealer.” It will be observed by a reference to the statute that it does not require competitive bidding at all as to
The improvement of a street must be considered as a whole, for it embraces everything that is necessary to complete the work. In competitive bidding, therefore, for such work it is not necessary for the bidder to submit his bid in piecemeal, to wit: so much for grading, so much for excavations, so much for drainage, if drainage is required, so much for materials, whether such materials be covered by patent or not, and so much for work and labor, but his bid may be submitted as a whole for the completed job.
The case of Dean v. Gharlton (1869), 23 Wis. 590, 99 Am. Dec. 205, so strongly relied upon by appellant, is shorn of much of its force by the later decision of that court in the case of Kilvington v. City of Superior (1892), 83 Wis. 222, 53 N. W. 487, 18 L. R. A. 45.
There the city of Superior contracted for the erection of a crematory to consume garbage, etc., and it was held that the fact that the mode of building the crematory was patented would not make the contract for its construction void, when the contract for performing the work and furnishing the materials is let to the lowest bidder, with the understanding that the patentee would allow the use of his patent and superintend its construction in consideration of a certain specified sum, to be paid to him by whoever secured the contract. That case is, in principle, exactly like this, and hence supportive of appellees’ contention. I quote from the opinion in that case the following: “In view of the legislation which followed Dean v. Charlton [(1869), 23 Wis. 590, 99 Am. Dec. 205], and the fact that it was decided by a divided court, and 'the general tenor of subsequent decisions, and the further fact that patented methods and processes now enter so largely into various classes and kinds of public work, we are not disposed to extend the rule of that case beyond the particular point there decided. In Hobart v. City of Detroit [1868], 17
The California, Louisiana and early Wisconsin cases, as they appear to me, are based upon a consideration or ground that does not exist here. And further than this, the supreme court of California has, it seems to me, receded from its earlier holding in the more recent case of Perine, etc., Pav. Co. v. Quackenbush (1894), 104 Cal. 684, 38 Pac. 533. I make the following quotation from that case, to show the force of the opinion,- to the end that it may be
The Kentucky case (Fineran v. Central, etc., Pav. Co. [1903], 116 Ky. 495, 76 S. W. 415), relied upon by appellant, is not of controlling influence, because the facts upon which the decision is based are so vitally different from those at bar. There the ordinance required the council to accept the bid of the lowest and best bidder. Here the board of public works has the right to reject any and all bids. The facts in that case also show that no one but the appellee, who owned and controlled the patent, could obtain the right to lay the pavement, or make a bona fide bid for the construction of the street with the material in question, and the council knew such to be the fact.
Here it is admitted that any one who desired to bid for the work under contemplation had a right to secure from the patentee, at a fixed and known price, the necessary materials, etc., with which to construct the pavement.
I do not deem it important to review the other authorities which have been cited. After a careful consideration of the question involved, and the authorities pro and con, I have reached the conclusion that the great weight of authority and the best-considered opinions abundantly support the contention of appellees. A patent right or a commercial product manufactured under a patent right does not constitute an unlawful monopoly. Such right is given by the laws of the United States as reward for inventive genius and for the benefit of the public. Personally, I do not know anything about the merits or demerits of the particular kind of pavement which the board of public works of the city of Indianapolis has ordered constructed in this case, but I do know that the public, as well as the individual, is entitled to the best that can be procured within reasonable restrictions, and should it transpire that this par
The facts pleaded in the answer make a much stronger case in favor of the rule first declared in the case of Hobart v. City of Detroit (1868), 17 Mich. *246, 97 Am. Dec. 185, than can be found in any of the decided cases. The answer proceeds upon the accepted theory that in the improvement of a street the work must be open to competition. In the agreement filed with the board by the owner of the patented process, with which it is proposed to improve the street, that feature is made prominent, and it is said that “inasmuch as in the construction of such pavement the use of certain compounds are necessary, and in the letting of contracts for all such street improvements competitive bidding is necessary, and for the purpose of permitting such competitive bidding,” etc., the patentee agrees that any bidder may have the right to use and purchase the patented processes and compounds upon certain terms.
By the agreement the patentee binds himself to furnish to any bidder to whom the contract may be awarded, “who is equipped or shall equip himself with the necessary appliances purchasable in the open market for preparing and laying such pavement,” all the necessary compounds, etc., for the sum of ninety cents per square yard for such pavement. It is further stipulated to allow the contractor to use the patented process and to furnish an expert who will advise in laying the pavement without extra charge. That part of the agreement which appears in quotation above seems to be the stumbling block which my associates have not been able to avoid. Without that clause in the agreement, it is held that the patentee could “absolutely control the bidding and that with such control there could be no competitive bidding except only in name.” Referring to
It is not a reasonable construction, nor one in accord with all the other conditions of the contract, to hold that under that particular provision the patentee reserved to himself the arbitrary right to say or determine whether or not the successful bidder “is equipped or shall equip himself with the necessary appliances,” etc. The necessary appliances, etc., to which reference is made, are no part of the patent, or covered by a patent, but are purchasable in the “open market” by any one. The patentee has no voice in the matter, unless it might be merely to indicate what tools, appliances, etc., were necessary properly to lay the pavement. Or we might reasonably presume that any one who desired to bid for the work would first acquaint himself with what was necessary successfully to perform his contract. •
But as to what are “necessary appliances,” etc., for laying the pavement, is not left to the arbitrary determination of the patentee, for the patentee agrees to furnish the compounds, etc., to any contractor to whom the city may let the contract, who has, or who will get, the necessary appliances. These conditions are open to all.
It is for the board of public works to determine, in its contract with the successful bidder, whether he has the necessary appliances with which to do the work. His con
Suppose, under the facts in this case, that the contract had been let, and the contractor was ready to proceed with the work; but the patentee refused to let him have the “necessary compounds” on the ground that he was not equipped with the “necessary appliances” to do the work. But suppose, as a matter of fact, he was so equipped, and could do the work successfully- — could it be reasonably contended that the patentee, upon such showing, would arbitrarily be allowed to say that he would not carry out his agreement? I think not. The very purpose of the agreement, specifically declared, was to pave the way to open and free competition, and yet in the very face of this fact it is construed by my associates as stifling competition. Such construction is, in my judgment, not warranted, under the provisions of the agreement.
Eor these reasons, and upon the authorities I have cited, I am constrained to disagree with my associates.- The demurrer to the answer was properly overruled by the trial court, and the judgment should be affirmed.