571 F.2d 1162 | Ct. Cl. | 1978
delivered the opinion of the court:
These renegotiation cases, in which plaintiffs profits for its fiscal years 1967, 1968 and 1969, are at issue, come before the court on defendant’s exceptions to findings of fact and recommended decision by Trial Judge Harkins. The Renegotiation Board determined that plaintiff had realized excessive profits in the amount of $500,000 for its fiscal year 1967, $550,000 for 1968, and $150,000 for 1969. Plaintiff petitioned the United States Tax Court for a redetermination of the board’s orders for 1967 and 1968, on May 16, 1969 and August 24, 1970, respectively. Pursuant to the extension of the Renegotiation Act of 1951, Pub. L. No. 92-41 § 3, 85 Stat. 97 (1971), these cases were transferred to the Court of Claims on July 29, 1971 for 1968, and August 2, 1971, for 1967. Plaintiff petitioned the Court of Claims for a de novo redetermination of the board’s order for 1969 on August 25, 1971. 50 U.S.C. app. § 1218 (1970) & (Supp. V1975). On March 29,1974, the cases were consolidated. Contrary to the board, the trial judge concluded that the Government had not met its burden of proof and that consequently Mills deserved a clearance for each of the years under review. We cannot completely agree and find that Mills earned excessive profits in the amount of $425,000 for 1967, and $350,000 for 1968. For 1969, however, we affirm the clearance given by the Trial Division.
I.
Since the Korean War, Mills Manufacturing Corp., has been engaged exclusively in the manufacture of various
All of plaintiffs contracts for the production of these items were obtained as a result of competitive bidding on advertised procurements and were on a firm, fixed price basis. The company was also responsible for all costs of manufacture, receiving no loans, advance payments, or government furnished materials from defendant. Plaintiff was, however, eligible for both small business and labor surplus "set-aside” awards through which it would be allowed to accept a portion of a procurement order (up to 50%) at the lowest bid price, even though plaintiff had. originally submitted a higher bid. Approximately one third of Mills’ total review period sales resulted from acceptance of set-aside portions.
[[Image here]]
Profits, sales, equity and their ratios made increases in this three year period. Mills also increased the number of its employees; shifted the mix of parachutes it made— increasing flare parachute production, decreasing personnel parachute production, and decreasing, then increasing, its production of cargo parachutes; and increased the proportion of its contracts performed as subcontracts.
II.
The parties have spent a great deal of time briefing and arguing the role of competition and market analysis in; renegotiation. The difficulty does not lie in recognition that contracts awarded in a truly competitive market produce reasonable profits. The ultimate purpose of renegotiation is to approximate that competitive norm, and the statutory factors and regulations attempt to insure that the proper considerations are taken into account in attempting to fill in the gaps wartime procurement may make in the competitive process. Major Coat Co. v. United States, 211 Ct. Cl. 1, 23, 543 F. 2d 97, 110 (1976); Mason & Hanger-Silas Mason Co. v. United States, 207 Ct. Cl. 106, 115-17, 518 F.2d 1341, 1346-48 (1975). The difference between the parties lies in deciding how the presence of a competitive market is to be determined and who has the burden of such proof. Mills’ argument is essentially one based upon its burden of proof in renegotiation. Lykes Bros. S.S. Co. v. United States, 198 Ct. Cl. 312, 459 F.2d 1393 (1972). Relying upon its evidence of the number of contractors in the parachute market and the number of contractors actually bidding against plaintiff during the review years, plaintiff asserts that it has met its burden of going forward as to the existence of competition in the parachute market, and that a presumption is thus raised that its profits were reasonable.
Although we do not think that the trial judge created a de facto exemption for competitively bid fixed price contracts, we do disagree with giving it as much importance as he does in the renegotiation process. When the analysis over-stresses the presumed competitiveness of the particular market, the result is a by-passing of the required analysis under the statutory factors, 50 U.S.C. app. § 1213(e) (1970). As noted above, the ultimate objective of renegotiation is to approximate a competitive norm. Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 22-23, 543 F.2d at 110. If it is established: or "presumed” in advance that full competition exists in a particular market, consideration of the firm’s efficiency, risk, and other statutorily mandated factors would necessarily be much lessened. Use of such a single formula would thus be contrary to the flexibility of approach that has formed the very purpose of the statutory system. Mason & Hanger, 207 Ct. Cl, at 117, 518 F.2d at 1346; A.C. Ball Co. v. United States, 209 Ct. Cl. 223, 263, 531 F.2d 993, 1015-16 (1976). Furthermore, over-emphasis on the presence or absence of competition puts too great a strain upon the allocation of burden of proof in renegotiation cases. Those burdens were established with specific reference to the statutory factors, Lykes Bros., 198 Ct. Cl. at 326, 327, 459 F.2d at 1401, and to the existence and amount of excessive profits. There is no presumption that a particular form of contractual system, in and of itself, shows the absence of excessive profits. There must always be some further particularized inquiry. In Major Coat, for example, . the court found in the dislocations caused by the buildup of wartime production and the use of rated orders, evidencing pressure on productive capacity, an absence of competition sufficient to permit renegotiation and to preclude comparison with other manufacturers of the same product. Determinative for these two purposes was the existence of the potential for excessive profits, 211 Ct. Cl. at 27, 543 F.2d at 112; the problem was not analyzed simply in
That the Government, though it has the burden of showing excessive profits, does not also have the separate burden of showing absence of competition, on pain of a clearance for the contractor, also appears from others of our decisions. In Butkin Precision Mfg. Corp. v. United States, 211 Ct. Cl. 110, 544 F. 2d 499 (1976), an alternative basis for the clearance was the Government’s failure to "cap” a statutory factor conceded to be in the contractor’s favor; yet the court recognized that an uncapped factor could have inherent limits which would not produce an automatic clearance. Id. at 130-31, 544 F.2d at 510-11. Similarly, the highest profitability on the profit hierarchy, warranted if there is a failure in the Government’s proof, need not necessarily result in a clearance. Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 47, 543 F.2d at 123-24. See Camel Mfg Co. v. United States, ante at 460.
Overemphasis upon market structure as such is not only contrary to Congressional directives and to prior decisions of this court, but it also seems contrary to the overall scheme of renegotiation. The presence of market power by a contractor — that is, a market dislocation — does not necessarily indicate the presence of excessive profits. The contractor may not have used his market power to capture extra profits, Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 26, 543 F.2d at 111, or favorable consideration under a statutory factor such as contribution to the defense effort may warrant a greater than competitive return, id. at 41, 543 F.2d at 120.
Yet we do not wish to be seen as denying the relevance of indications of the presence or absence of competition in a particular market. A strong showing of effective competition by plaintiff, for example, might make us more inclined to credit ambiguous evidence of increased efficiency or to give greater credit for the reasonableness of costs. 50 U.S.C. app. 1213(e). In this case, however, there are enough difficulties with the evidence of full competition to preclude our giving it great weight in even this more restricted sense.
Our fundamental difficulty with the evidence of competition in the parachute procurement market, and one which every contractor making that claim must overcome, is that the premise of statutory renegotiation is that "accurate pricing and the control of contractors’ profits cannot be achieved during a build-up of production for defense of war.” Mason & Hanger, 207 Ct. Cl. at 115, 518 F.2d, 1346-47. The grossly increased demand, the requirement of unprecedented speed, and the predominant interest of procurement officials in volume of purchases all preclude careful cost analysis and sound purchasing. Id at 115-16, 518 F.2d at 1347. And if the sudden large increase in demand does not create a loss of price competition, then "the knowledge that the demand is short-term and will just as suddenly fall off surely accomplishes the task.” Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 23, 543 F.2d at 110. The whole process of renegotiation recognizes the danger that even normally competitive markets may not continue to be so during a wartime buildup. Indeed, in A.C. Ball, 209 Ct. Cl. at 263,
Other more specific considerations reinforce our belief that the parachute procurement market may have been less than fully competitive during the peak years of Vietnam procurement. Of particular interest is the number of parachute suppliers relied upon by Mills as part of its prima facie case. In 1965, there were 57 contractors providing $27.8 million worth of parachutes; by 1967, 88 suppliers sold $62.6 million worth of parachutes, with the number remaining approximately that high in the other two review years. On its face, so many suppliers might seem to be strong evidence of effective competition in the parachute market. Yet of those eighty-eight suppliers, only about fifteen were regularly active parachute manufacturers, of which nine or ten were recognized as established supply sources for military parachutes. During the three years under review, Mills in fact competed against only thirty-five of these firms, and on the average against only 5.95 qualified bidders for each separate procurement. While we in no way indicate the number of firms required before full competition can, if ever, be found, these figures indicate that the question is closer than plaintiff would have us believe.
Further indication that the evidence does not compel the finding that plaintiffs market was fully competitive is found in the set-aside program of the Small Business Administration and the Labor Department. Under these programs, qualified firms have the opportunity to match the lowest bid for a contract, taking up to 50 percent of the contract at that price. Only one among Mills’ competitors, Automotive Textile Products, did not qualify under this program. Thus there may have been less incentive for each firm to submit the lowest possible price consistent with a reasonable profit because there always existed the possibility that they would be able to receive part of the contract as a set-aside. Indeed, acceptance of set aside awards would itself be evidence that the firm thought itself capable of making a profit at a price lower than it submitted in its bid. Mills accepted at least $3.2 million of such contracts over the review period. In short, the set-aside practice provides us with less than full faith in the assumption that each firm submitted fully competitive bids. Cf. Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 23, 543 F.2d at 110 (common knowledge of the short term nature of the wartime demand destroys competition in the market).
Finally, little weight can be given to the argument that since the government procurement officials utilized the competitively bid fixed price procurement method, they must, under the standards of the Armed Services Procurement Regulations, have known enough about the pricing of contracts in this market to insure, as in a competitive market, that no excessive profits would exist. 32 C.F.R. §§ 3-401(b)(6), 3-404.2(a) (b) (1975). Although use of this type of procurement under these standards is certainly a factor to be considered, administratively setting a felt "sound price” does not guarantee that excessive profits have not been earned. The argument is somewhat circular, for if these officials made a mistake in their judgment it would show up as excessive profits, whose existence is here at issue. Moreover, placing too much emphasis upon the decision to use competitively bid, fixed-price procurements may have the deleterious effect of decreasing the use of this type of procurement by procurement officials. See 32 C.F.R. §§ 3-401(b)(6), 3-404.2(a)(b) (1975).
Finding the evidence far less than conclusive that the military parachute market was perfectly competitive during the 1967-69 period, we come to consider the appropriate criteria for determining excessive profits in this case, including the specified statutory factors. 50 U.S.C. app. § 1213(e) (1970).
The foundation of the Government’s case is its comparison of Mills’ profits in the review years with the firm’s profits in an earlier period. Under the Government’s theory, the variance between the review and base years constitutes the amount of excessive profits earned by Mills, except for a 10% allowance whose rationale is not explained.
Defendant proposes a norm comprising Mills’ earnings from 1963-66. Traditional financial analysis normally permits a five year period, but defendant dropped 1962 because it was a "low” year.
Mills’ conception of the historical norm cannot be accepted. As noted by the trial judge, plaintiffs inclusion of the review years in its computation of the historical norm, results in an analytical anomaly — use of the review years in the calculation of the average against which those years are to be compared reduces the discrepancy between the review and base years, thereby defeating the very purpose of the comparison. Adjustments to the historical norm, as advocated by plaintiff, might also be counterproductive in that they could serve to justify giving greater weight to the base period ratios than they merit. Prevention of use of such an historical norm as a ceiling is best attained through proper adjustments to the norm under the statutory factors — not through attempts to second-guess the procéss by adjusting the calculation of the norm itself. Finally, to the extent plaintiffs position is based upon the "cyclical” nature of its business, it is misplaced. If by cyclical plaintiff means that the volume of its production in the wartime
The trial judge, however, refused to find and compare a base period with the review period. Rather, he limited the use of historical norm analyses to situations where the company either converted from a commercial product to the military product subject to renegotiation or produced a product with both war and peacetime uses. See Mason & Hanger, 207 Ct. Cl. at 151, 518 F.2d at 1367-68 (dissenting opinion). Since the type and volume of parachutes sold by Mills were determined by the military uses to which they were put, the trial judge ruled that military parachutes could not be. divided into wartime and peacetime products. Because Mills had never had a commercial line of business, he concluded that the earnings of the company in prior years could not be compared to the earnings of the review years.
Use of the historical norm need not be so restricted. In Gibraltar, plaintiff was also a single product manufacturer selling exclusively to the military. That fact did not preclude recovery of excessive profits even though the Government relied principally upon an historical norm analysis. The court there specifically endorsed the use of an historical norm. Gibraltar, 212 Ct. Cl. 235, 546 F.2d at 391. The difficulty of finding other companies similar enough to be accurately compared with the company being reviewed also makes comparisons with the company’s prior history particularly valuable. This is especially true where, as here, the contractor’s operations during the review years are distinguishable from those of its prior history primarily through substantial differences in volume. Cf. Gibraltar, id at 235, 546 F.2d at 391. Instead of referring to the time during which the product was sold as being one of wartime or peacetime, the trial judge found determinative the party to whom the product was sold. Although Mills’ demand for its product was dictated by the use to which it was put by the military, that peacetime demand was sufficient enough, and profitable enough, to induce Mills to
Use of a profit-to-sales ratio and of a profit-to-net-worth ratio
[[Image here]]
[Footnote 11 appears on p. 555.]
Both of these ratios serve different functions and obviously they can lead to differing results. The profit-to-sales ratio shows profitability in relation to the dollar volume of business done. As an analytical tool, it is especially useful in those types of businesses that are not capital intensive, where there is a rapid turnover of expensive retail inventory, or where a significant portion of the facilities or materials are furnished by the Government or the customer. Contrarily, rates of return on net worth and on capital employed relate profits to the value of total assets and investments employed in the business and
While both ratios are to be considered, these considerations require our giving slightly greater weight in this instance to the profit-to-sales ratio.
IV.
Of the statutory factors, 50 U.S.C. app. § 1213(e), the most important in this case is the one concerning efficiency. Were we to find that Mills did not warrant favorable consideration for efficiency due to its control of variable costs during the review years, our decision would be much simpler. In Gibraltar Mfg. Co. v. United States, 212 Ct.Cl. 226, 546 F. 2d 386 (1976), the Government principally relied on an historical norm analysis to carry its burden of proof.
Thus it becomes crucial whether Mills’ increásed profitability during the review years can be attributed largely or
We have often noted the essentially comparative nature of the renegotiation process. See, e.g., Major Coat, 211 Ct.Cl. at 9, 543 F.2d at 102. Comparisons are of two types — those made with the firm’s own prior history and those made with other outfits within the industry, adjustments being made for both qualitative and quantitative differences. 32 C.F.R. § 1460.10(b)(1) (1976). When we compare Mills’ review year profitability with its prior profitability we are concerned, under the statutory factor of efficiency, with increases in its efficiency during the review period. To the extent the firm is equally efficient, however measured, in the base and review years, we would expect the profitability of the base years to incorporate an adequate return for
The first asserted basis for crediting Mills with increased efficiency, is the more intense utilization of plant through use of multiple shifts. By itself, increased utilization of plant is not an increase in efficiency. Although the Board’s regulations under this factor indicate favorable consideration is due for "exceptional effort,” 32 C.F.R. § 1460.10(b)(3)
Intensive asset utilization, however, does evoke increased efficiency if the contractor is able to control diseconomies resulting from the attempt to produce more volume from a fixed asset base; this is the second of the asserted bases for finding increased efficiency. The ability to decrease controllable costs, or to even maintain them at an absolute or relative level of stability as production increases may very well indicate increased efficiency. See Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl. at 35-36, 543 F.2d at 117. The contractor’s ability to control costs will be best measured by comparisons with the firm’s prior history or with the contemporaneous experience of comparable firms. The failure of Mills during the base period to increase its sales so greatly or to sell at a volume as high as that reached during the review period limits our ability to make meaningful comparisons with its prior history. Comparison of Mills’ overhead as a percentage of sales with that of Mills’ competitors, however, indicates a probable increase in efficiency by plaintiff during the review years. Specifically, the trial judge found that controllable expenses included in Mills’ "other costs” were kept at lower levels than by other parachute manufacturers producing comparable volumes:
The relevant comparison, we note, is not with the absolute values of the above percentages, but with their change from the base period. Thus in 1965, a year of less than average profitability for Mills, its cost remainder was a full 32% less than the nearest competitor here shown. To the extent that this differential is due to tighter control of variable costs, the profits of that concededly normal year should take this into account. In 1967 and 1968, the differential between these two companies remained about the same; indeed in 1968, plaintiffs ability to control these costs vis-a-vis this competitor declined relatively by 8% over the 1965 period. But by 1969, the review year of least profitability, Mills was able to control its variable "other costs” so that they were only about 50%, as a percentage of its sales, of its nearest competitor’s (here shown).
Conspicuous among the firms not shown in the above table, are two that provide significant intra-industry comparisons: Automotive Textile Products and Security Parachute. They show the following:
As compared to Mills in both absolute and relative terms,
There are, of course, difficulties with this analysis which tend to be stressed by the party feeling most harmed by the data. The data is unaudited. Only one base year was involved and individual companies are being compared. "Other costs” include fixed costs which do not change as the production volume varies and which, not being continuously controllable, are not as indicative of efficiency. The percentages do not account for variances in the sales volumes of the companies or the rate of increase of the volumes on the fixed asset base. For example, Mills’ ability to keep costs as a percentage of sales at 9.6% might be more significant if its sales had doubled on a fixed asset base while other firms attempting to so double their
Defendant, having the ultimate burden of proof in renegotiation, must bear the adverse implications of the thinness of the comparative data, unless , the absence of data were the contractor’s responsibility. The above data is less conclusive than we would desire; it certainly does not establish that Mills does not merit favorable consideration for increased efficiency during the review years. On the whole we are favorably impressed by Mills’ ability to control its costs when compared with several members of its industry, and we are sensitive to the Renegotiation Act’s emphasis on the control of these costs. But we conclude, nevertheless, that the Government has established that Mills’ increased profits were not entirely the result of its increased efficiency. Thus, we find that Mills merits favorable consideration for efficiency but are not persuaded that its efficiency precludes the possibility of its having earned excessive profits in the circumstances of this case.
V.
Defendant undertook a profit-use analysis in order to verify its conclusion that the bulk of plaintiffs increased profits was due to economies of scale rather than considerations meriting credit under the statutory factors. It is not 'disputed that Mills’ gross nonparachute business investments grew substantially during the review years. They were $20,444 in 1966; in 1967, they increased to $660,044, and by 1969 they were $1,055,651. When Mills’ cash on hand is also considered, the results are even more dramatic:
In the review period, Mills also retained from its earnings and added to its parachute business a total of $2,157,000. Additions to Mills’ beginning net worth in the parachute business averaged 27.9 percent annually in each of the review years.
Although such evidence does not establish in itself that Mills fails to merit favorable consideration under the statutory factors, the sheer magnitude of the cash on hand, the annual increases in net worth, and the external investments during wartime procurement, all cause us to (1) be less certain of the extent of favorable consideration given under the particular statutory factors, and (2) be more hospitable to the idea that plaintiffs profits during the review years arose, not from factors for which it was responsible, but from wartime conditions which tend to enhance its gain.
VI.
As we have pointed out, the Government’s case rests principally upon its historical norm analysis. Two other tests were used by the Government to buttress its claim that excessive profits had been earned — a break even analysis and a product mix analysis. The trial judge rejected both of these analyses, and we shall mention them but briefly.
The data is simply too sparse to support this theory. Similar data from comparable firms is lacking, precluding appraisal of Mills’ relative risks; earlier break-even points in 1967 and 1968 than in 1965 and 1966 may be more the result of Mills’ ability to control variable costs, other than direct costs for material and labor, over a vastly expanded volume of production; the earlier points may simply be the result of an expanded volume, or of changes in Mills’ product mix, with some types of parachutes contributing more to profits and overhead; or they may be the result of any combination of these factors. The trial judge rejected the analysis because there also was no evidence that Mills was either cognizant of or utilized the flexibility claimed by
The defendant’s product-mix analysis also fails in this instance to provide adequate support for its claim that Mills earned excessive profits in the review years. In that analysis defendant’s expert contended that the increase over previous years in the percentage rate of Mills’ contribution to profit and overhead for the years 1967-69
Our finding that Mills in fact increased its efficiency casts much doubt on the validity of the analysis. Furthermore, a proper analysis would determine the unit costs of the various categories of parachutes so that the effect on costs and profits of varying the product mixes could be measured. Were this test more central to our decision, we might consider the Government’s asserted inability to perform a proper analysis because Mills did not keep detailed cost accounting data.
VII
Initially, plaintiff sought to evaluate Mills’ performance through comparisons with commercial textile fabricators, relying upon Board Regulations 32 C.F.R. §§ 1460.2(c) and 1460.10(b)(1) (1976). The trial judge found differences with these companies significant enough to preclude their comparison with Mills’ operations for the purposes of renegotiation. Mills does not dispute this decision, nor do we. The trial judge’s comparison was limited to other government parachute suppliers, and it was discovered that the post-renegotiation returns on net worth and capital of two competitors exceeded the pre-renegotiation ratios of Mills for the review years. Specifically, in 1967, Mills had a return on beginning net worth of 116.9 percent and on average net worth of 91.6%. In that year, Automotive Textile Products Co., Inc., had its initial return on net worth of 350 percent reduced to 188 percent after renegotiation; Security Parachute Company had its return on net worth of 264 percent reduced to 219 percent. (Comparable information is not available for any other parachute manufacturers.)
Defendant’s response is an elaborate argument to the effect that comparisons cannot be made with other members of the parachute industry because that data reflects the noncompetitive conditions in the entire market brought about by the increased wartime demand. As proof that noncompetitive conditions existed, defendant presented evidence of a higher profit ratio on an expanded sales volume for the entire industry, and relied upon a statement in Major Coat, id at 23, 543 F.2d at 110, that such a rise may show the absence of competition.
The Government’s argument misses the full significance of the comparisons made by the trial judge.
When we compare the post-renegotiation profit-to-sales ratios, which we have found to be the more significant ratio in this case, of these two competitors with Mills’ sales ratio, the results differ from those previously noted. Automotive Textile had its pre-renegotiation profit to sales ratio of 16.2 reduced to 9.4; Security Parachute’s ratio was reduced from | 16.4 to 14.0. Mills’ pre-renegotiation ratios for the 1967-69! review period are 13.7, 14.4 and 10.8 respectively. Were we merely to average the after-renegotiation ratios of these
VIII
The Government has persuaded us that Mills earned profits during the review years that were excessive. Evidence of wartime market imperfections has precluded our accepting the reasonableness of Mills’ profits from the competitively bid nature of its procurement. The historical norm analysis, whose base period was essentially conceded to be one of relative normalcy by Mills, provides our starting point. From there we assessed whether consideration under the various statutory factors was already encompassed within that norm or whether additional consideration was merited. Mills’ risks were found to be already adequately compensated through use of the historical norm and through intra-industry comparisons, but some additional favorable consideration was found due for Mills’ increased efficiency in cost control. But we noted also, that a comparable firm found to be equally efficient was held to have earned $400,000 in excessive profits for 1967. We have considered all the remaining statutory factors and find them to be either adequately compensated by application of the historical norm and intra-industry comparisons, or not claimed here, or not pertinent to the facts of this case. As we see it, economies of scale caused by the increased volume of production during wartime competitive dislocations, changes for which Mills was not
CONCLUSION OF LAW
The court concludes as a matter of law that for the 1967 and 1968 fiscal years plaintiff realized excessive profits in the gross amount of $425,000 and $350,000 respectively, from contracts and subcontracts subject to renegotiation under the Renegotiation Act of 1951, as amended. For those years, judgment is hereby entered on defendant’s counterclaim in the sum of seven hundred seventy-five thousand dollars ($775,000) less appropriate state and federal tax credits, plus interest thereon as provided by
The necessary findings of fact are contained in this opinion.
Mills does not, however, rely exclusively on this argument. Elsewhere it argues that its entitlement to favorable consideration under several statutory factors warrants its clearance for the years under review.
Indeed, we note that in Butkin, the contractor also worked under firm, fixed price contracts awarded on the basis of competitive bidding in a market consisting of 25-30 "exceptional” competitors. Yet the court never said the contractor’s profits were reasonable because it was the lowest bidder on the contracts it performed; nor did it say the Government failed in its burden because it failed to prove market dislocations.
The absence of data from either side precludes our putting too much weight on this aspect.
Before the trial judge, defendant’s expert could not give a precise breakdown of claimed excessive profits for each of the review years, but determined excessive profits on an accumulative basis for the three review years. This attempt to compute excessive profits for the combined three-year review period is .contrary to the fiscal year basis of the Renegotiation Act. See A.C. Ball Co. v. United States, 209 Ct. Cl. 223, 258, 531 F.2d 993, 1012 (1976); 50 U.S.C. app. § 1215(a) (Supp. V, 1975); 32 C.F.R. § 1457.1(b)(1976); 32 C.F.R. § 1459.9(a)-(f) (1976). Defendant attempted to remedy this shortcoming by calculating the difference between the historical return on sales and the actual profit for each of the review years and labelling 90% of such difference as excessive. Mills, aside from its basic objection to use of the historical norm as a ceiling, finds the 10% allowance arbitrary and objects to the lack of opportunity for cross-examination on this approach. To the extent that the 10% allowance is arbitrary, it is an allowance contrary to defendant’s theory and works to the plaintiffs favor. As to the second objection, the calculations are so consistent with defendant’s theory of the case that recalculation on a yearly basis in accord with that theory does not seem to constitute an unfair surprise for Mills. Certainly such error under these circumstances cannot mandate a clearance for the entire review period.
' In 1962, Mills’ sales, its profit to sales ratio, and its profit to owners’ equity ratio were substantially below the corresponding figures for the three years prior to 1962 and for the four years following 1962.
The trial judge seemed to feel that Mills’ 1963-66 period was tainted because Mills in each of those years was subject to renegotiation. By adopting an historical norm, we do not imply that the clearance given those years indicates necessarily that only a reasonable, or competitive, profit was earned by plaintiff. Indeed, to the extent profits during those years exceeded the level necessary to prevent Mills from entering other markets, and, as such, arguably exceeded the competitive level, such excess would be continued in the review years.
It is unnecessary to decide the binding nature of these regulations in a de novo proceeding in this court. See Mason & Hanger, 207 Ct. Cl. at 122, n. 13, 518 F.2d at 1351, n. 13. Cf. Camel Mfg. Co v. United States, ante at 460. (Renegotiation Board ruling, even if reasonable, held not conclusive upon court).
The longer period is more akin to the period accepted in traditional financial analyses. We also take note that there were no years, prior to the review years, that were better than these, and that 1966 seems to be particularly favorable to Mills.
The second numbered statutory factor specifically requires profits to be considered in relation to net worth. 50 U.S.C. app. § 1213(e)(2).
Renegotiation Board regulations provide that the amount of net worth employed, as a general rule,-will be that existing at the beginning of the fiscal year. Where there have been significant changes in any particular year, an average of the beginning and ending values may be more indicative of the amount of plaintiffs equity than the beginning value taken alone. Aero Spacelines, Inc. v. United States, 208 Ct. Cl. 704, 747, 530 F.2d 324, 350 (1976). Mills had considerable changes in net worth between the beginning and the end of 1967. Beginning net worth was $1,563,902 and ending net worth was $2,425,476. In view of the significant change in net worth during 1967, it may be appropriate that adjustments be made to reflect the amount employed during the year by adopting the average net worth for fiscal year 1967, or $1,994,675. This amount is largely, but not entirely, exclusive of nonbusiness related investments because it was agreed that the amounts and timing of nonbusiness related investments in 1967 necessitated special adjustments. As a result of these adjustments, the 1967 closing business related net worth was $2,425,476. Were we to ignore both these nonbusiness investments and the addition to net worth during 1967, beginning net worth would be $1,563,902, resulting in a variance of $898,380. The adjustments are favorable to Mills.
The trial judge, while agreeing that both ratios must be considered, adopted the profit-to-net worth ratios when making comparisons with other firms and never specified why the profit-to-sales ratio was unacceptable.
Our calculations from defendant’s table on use of profits, see infra, indicate that cash on hand constituted almost 38% of the net worth for 1967, 39.45% for 1968 and 26.8% for 1969.
In Gibraltar, the pre tax profit-to-sales ratio was 15.18%, while the average return during the historical norm was 6.01%; here the average historical return is 7.95%, while the review year returns are 13.7%, 14.3% and 10.5% respectively.
Indeed, application of the historical rate of return over a doubled volume of sales may provide an added recovery for Mills.
In 1966, other costs of Automotive were 10.2% less than Mills’ other costs. By 1967 this had increased to 14.9% and in 1968 it was still 11.5% less than Mills. We recognize that these percentages are of sales and that the two firms had different sales volumes through these years. As such we do not put great weight on the fineness of the differences in the above percentages. They do however provide valuable, but rough, insight into comparable efficiencies.
The base year here compared with is 1966 because Automotive Textile did not make sufficient sales in this market to be subject to the Renegotiation Act in 1965. Mills’ other costs as a percentage of sales were’identical to its 1965 figure of 8.8%. We recognize the difficulty in making the switch in base years and appropriately discount the weight we give these numbers.
The rates, calculated in defendant’s break-even analysis, were: 16.9% (1965); 18.4% (1966); 21.1% (1967); 23.6% (1968); 20.1% (1969).
Cf. Camel Mfg. Co. v. United States, (burden of proof, and thus the risk of non-persuasion, for. accounting data placed ante at 480, 484, upon contractor).
Earlier we argued that there may be strong indications of the absence of competition in the parachute market. Such arguments were presented in rebuttal to the proposition that the method of bidding for these contracts assured, at least presumptively, the presence of a reasonable profit. They fell far short of establishing the absence of competitive factors sufficient to preclude use of any intra-industry
This proceeding is de novo, and the prior decisions of the Renegotiation Board are not conclusive. The suggestive use of the Board’s judgment, however, is permitted and does not prejudice the de novo character of this proceeding. Gibraltar Mfg. Co. v. United States, 212 Ct. Cl. 226, 229, 546 F.2d 386, 388 (1976).
It should be remembered that (a) under the net-worth ratio 1969 would be a clearance year, (b) in 1969 Mills apparently controlled its costs better than in the other review years and better than its main competitor, and (c) under the profit-sales formula, Mills’ ratio for 1969 was less than that of the average of its two prime competitors.
In Major Coat, 211 Ct. Cl at 48, 543 F.2d at 124, we also indicated that, in a case like this, we would for a limited time not hold the defendant rigidly to the strict standards of proof theoretically called for by Lykes.
Years under review
Ratio after Renegotiation Board determinations of excessive profit.
Loss year
Year found to contain excessive profits.