27 N.Y. 364 | NY | 1863
Lead Opinion
[EDITORS' NOTE: THIS PAGE CONTAINS HEADNOTES. HEADNOTES ARE NOT AN OFFICIAL PRODUCT OF THE COURT, THEREFORE THEY ARE NOT DISPLAYED.] *366
[EDITORS' NOTE: THIS PAGE CONTAINS HEADNOTES. HEADNOTES ARE NOT AN OFFICIAL PRODUCT OF THE COURT, THEREFORE THEY ARE NOT DISPLAYED.] *367
[EDITORS' NOTE: THIS PAGE CONTAINS HEADNOTES. HEADNOTES ARE NOT AN OFFICIAL PRODUCT OF THE COURT, THEREFORE THEY ARE NOT DISPLAYED.] *368 This seems to be a plain case. In the early part of November, 1860, the plaintiff, who was the owner of 130 bales of cotton, applied to the defendant's testator for a loan or advance thereon of $7,000, which, as the plaintiff estimated the weight of the cotton, was equal to 10 3/8 cents per pound, and according to its actual weight, 11¼ cents per pound. The advance was made upon conditions specially agreed on, and without which it is reasonable to assume it would not have been made. The plaintiff was to consign or pledge to Dehon the cotton, which was an article of fluctuating value in the market, the plaintiff agreeing to repay the advance on the 4th January following. Special authority was given to Dehon to sell the cotton "at public or private sale, or otherwise, at his option, for the most that it would bring," in two contingencies: 1st. If a decline should occur in the market value, and the plaintiff failed, whenever demanded, to deposit, in cash, sufficient to cover such decline, so that Dehon should at all times have in his hands a margin of 1¼ cents per pound; and 2d. If the plaintiff should make default in the payment of the advance, in cash, on the 4th January, 1861, less five days' interest, with one per cent commission. This was something more than a mere pledge, where *369 the pledgor would be entitled to notice to redeem, and also notice of the time and place that the pledged article would be publicly exposed to sale. Indeed, it is doubtful whether, in a legal sense, a pledge of the cotton was made at all, or that, strictly, the relation of pledgor and pledgee was created. A pledge is defined to be "delivery of goods by a debtor to his creditor, to be kept till the debt be discharged." (Jones' Bail., 117; 2 Kent's Com., 577.) Here there was a constructive delivery of the cotton before any relation of debtor or creditor existed, and not by way of bailment, but as a consignment. It was a peculiar contract between the parties, and is to be construed according to its own language and circumstances; and I apprehend that any apparent difficulty grows out of a perversion of it by a nice adhesion to rules at best only applicable to relations of strict and simple pledgor and pledgee.
It was certainly competent for the plaintiff to contract (with the view of fully securing the advance) that Dehon should hold the cotton, and if its value declined in market, he would deposit a sum in cash equal to such decline, so that the consignee or pledgee would at all times have in his hands a margin of 1¼ cents per pound; that is, a cash deposit which would increase the value of the cotton 1¼ cents per pound beyond the current market price; and it was equally competent for the plaintiff to agree that, failing to do so, whenever demanded, Dehon should have the right to dispose of the cotton "at public or private sale, or otherwise, at his option, for the most that it would bring." The plaintiff cannot legally insist that he should have notice of the time and place of sale, that he had expressly agreed might be public or private, or otherwise, as the consignee or pledgee should determine. In case of a simple pledge with a mere right of sale, the sale must be public, and notice given of the time and place. But here the right of sale is enlarged by expressly yielding the privilege of claiming a public sale, and authorizing the party to sell at private sale. The private sale spoken of in the contract, and which was within the intention of the parties, was clearly a private sale, to be made in the ordinary way, without notice *370 of time or place, and known and made public to the parties thereto alone. Under the clause allowing a sale for a fall below the margin agreed to be kept up, no prompt sale, adequate to protect the pledgee from loss, and such as was evidently contemplated, could be made, if it was necessary to serve a notice of time and place of sale on the plaintiff. The whole proceeding would be ridiculous and impracticable. It is impossible to raise from the language of this contract, as the Court below attempted to do, an implied obligation to give notice to the plaintiff of the time and place where the cotton would be sold for his default. The parties did not intend it; and, ordinarily, it would be impracticable to affect a private sale of a lot of cotton, in the way such sales are usually made, if such notice was required to be given.
With this view of the law, the only question in the case was one of fact, viz., whether the plaintiff had made default in keeping up the margin, at the time of the sale of the cotton by Dehon. If he had, then Dehon was justified in selling. If he had not, the sale was wrongful. Two things must have concurred to put the plaintiff in default — a decline in the market value of cotton below the margin stipulated in the contract, and a demand, by Dehon, that the plaintiff should make such margin good. The jury were substantially so instructed by the judge at the trial; and the findings of the jury upon these questions of fact were, in effect, against the plaintiff. After a charge, in which they were distinctly instructed that, before Dehon could sell the cotton, the price must have fallen below the amount specified in the contract, and he must also have demanded of the plaintiff that the margin should be made good by him, they found for the defendant.
The judge was requested to instruct the jury that Dehon had no right to sell the pledged property, until he had first caused a demand of payment of the margin, to be made personally of the plaintiff. If by this was meant that there should be an actual, instead of a constructive, demand and notice, the request was unobjectionable. But this was not the meaning. The loan had been negotiated through one Dougloss, *371 lass, a clerk of the plaintiff, who sometimes did out-door business for him; and the proof tended conclusively to show that he acted as the plaintiff's agent in the particular transaction. Douglass had several interviews with Dehon in the month of December, while samples were in the hands of the cotton broker, in relation to the threatened sale of the cotton. He knew of the decline, and that the margin was deficient, and in these interviews, urged that the sale should be delayed. He was told, that if the plaintiff did not pay the margin within a day or two, the cotton would be sold; that Dehon had already borne with the plaintiff for some time, and could not longer take the risk; and when requesting delay, represented that it was inconvenient, or indeed quite impossible, for the plaintiff to pay up his margins. This evidence showed that the demand was made to Douglass, and not to the plaintiff in person. Accordingly, the judge charged the jury that if they found that a demand was made on Douglass to make the margin good, it would be necessary to determine whether Douglass was authorized by the plaintiff to receive a notice of that kind, and that would depend entirely upon the question whether Douglass was the agent of the plaintiff or not. If Douglass was the agent of the plaintiff in the transaction of the business, and notice was given to him requiring that the margin should be made good within one or two days, as testified to by some of the witnesses, then such notice was sufficient to the plaintiff. It was to the proposition in the charge, that demand and notice to the agent transacting the business was sufficient notice to the principal, that the plaintiff's counsel took exception, insisting that to authorize a sale, the demand should have been made personally on the plaintiff. But, clearly, this was unnecessary to put the latter in default, if Douglass was authorized to receive the notice for him. The evidence tended to the conclusion that he had such authority.
Questions were put to the plaintiff, as a witness, with the view of showing that no demand had been made on him personally, and excluded. This exclusion had no important bearing on the rights of the parties. It was not pretended *372 that any demand had ever been made upon the plaintiff, individually; and if the law required such a demand, it was conceded that the sale was without authority. It was quite unnecessary that the plaintiff should testify to the fact, to enable his counsel to raise the question of law. I think no error was committed at the circuit, and that the order for a new trial should be reversed, and judgment rendered on the verdict for the defendant.
Concurrence Opinion
It is very properly conceded, in the opinion of the general term, that any or all of the pawnor's rights can be waived or modified by consent, including notice of time and place of sale. But it is said that there is no express waiver of such notice in this case, and that none should be implied.
Let us turn to the contract between the parties. Should a decline occur in the market value of said merchandise, and I fail, whenever demanded, to deposit in cash sufficient to cover such decline, c., then "the right is hereby given you to sell this merchandise at public or private sale, or otherwise, at your option, for the most it will bring." The merchandise was cotton. It was stored in two warehouses in New York. The mode of selling cotton in New York is by sample, exhibited by a broker, employed for such purpose. The usual course was adopted in this case, and the plaintiff, by his agent, knew that the samples were with the broker. He knew that the defendant intended to sell the cotton, unless the margin was made good, and he wanted the defendant to abstain from selling, if possible, and the defendant refused, unless the margin should be made good the next day, the witness thinks, or he would sell. This was some days before the sale. The cotton was on sale for more than two weeks, and the plaintiff, by his agent, knew the fact, and at one time expressed the hope to the brokers that they would not sell it, but hold it a few days longer, and use their influence with Dehon. It was proved that the cotton was sold in the usual way; that there was no other way of selling cotton, except *373 by samples. Can it be said, in the light of these facts, that it was necessary that notice of the precise time and place where the sale would be made should be given? This is the position assumed, and it must be fully sustained to justify a new trial. All contracts should receive a fair and reasonable construction, having regard to the subject matter of the contract.
The general rule, in the absence of a contract affecting the question, is, that the pledgor must have notice of the time and the place of sale; and the principal reason assigned for the rule is, that he may have an opportunity to attend the sale, and see that it is fairly conducted; that he may exert himself in procuring buyers, and thus enhance the price; that he has, in fact, the right to redeem the pledge at any moment before the sale shall be actually made. These rules should be carefully adhered to, in all cases in which they are applicable. They may be modified or waived by agreement; and in case a special agreement has been made between the parties, controlling their rights, it is subjected, like other agreements, to the well-settled rules of construction. In the present case, the agreement was, upon the happening of a specified contingency, that the pledgee should have the right to sell the pledge, at public or private sale or otherwise, at his option, for the most it would bring. The pledge was cotton, in certain warehouses in the city of New York. Cotton, under such circumstances, is usually sold by brokers, employed for such purposes, and always, or at any rate usually, by samples. The broker offers the cotton for sale, and those persons who desire to purchase examine the samples and make offers, or a price is proposed by one of the parties, and it is accepted or declined, as the case may be; and this course is proceeded in until a sale is effected. It may be said that the sale is private; and yet it may have partaken largely of a public character, the samples having been exhibited to many persons, for days in succession, attended by negotiations for sale and purchase, as in the present case. The cotton being on sale, and the broker, being instructed to sell "for the most it will bring," is ready to close the bargain whenever the largest price the cotton will bring is offered. He may *374 have such offer at any moment, or it may be days before a satisfactory offer is made. How is it practicable to give notice to the pledgor of the time and place of sale? Any offer made may be withdrawn, unless accepted at once, and thus a desirable sale may be lost. It is not denied that the defendant had the right to make a private sale; but this, it is said, did not give him the right to sell without notice to the pledgor of the time and place; and I concede that notice may be necessary in some cases where the authority is to sell at private sale, as will be noticed hereafter. But was such notice required in this case? Did the parties to the agreement contemplate such notice? I think not. They knew the course of trade, the mode of selling cotton; and they contracted in reference to such mode. They knew that brokers were employed; that they made sales by sample; and that such samples were exhibited, sometimes for days and weeks, until a sale should be effected. The parties contemplated a fair sale, in the well understood mode of making such sales, and must have seen that a notice of the time and place of sale would be extremely inconvenient, if not impracticable; and, in my opinion, neither of the parties to the contract contemplated any such notice. The contract goes further. It authorizes a public sale, or a sale otherwise. But it is not necessary to remark upon the powers thus conferred, as the sale was fairly made in the only usual way.
If we again refer to the reasons of the rule requiring notice. of the time and place of sale, it will be seen that all the reasons were, in this case, fully satisfied. The cotton was "on sale" two or three weeks; the plaintiff, by his agent, knew the facts, had interviews with the brokers offering the cotton for sale, and had full and ample opportunity to procure friends, or persons dealing in cotton, to go and examine the samples, and purchase the cotton at the highest price; and, for aught we know, may have exerted himself to this end. It seems to me that he had all the notice which the reasons of the rule can require. There is no complaint of any secrecy or unfairness in the sale. *375
Let us examine the cases cited by the plaintiff's counsel. InStearns v. Marsh (4 Den., 227), there was no special agreement affecting the questions decided. There was no demand of the debt when due, nor was there any notice of the sale, except a notice of a sale of a large and general assortment of boots and shoes, by the autioneer, published in a daily paper. The boots and shoes, worth $520.32, were sold at the auction for $166.97. The notice was published in the paper before the debt was due. It was held that the debt should have been demanded, and if not paid, personal notice of the time and place of sale should have been given.
In Wilson v. Little (2 Comst., 443), railroad stock was pledged to secure the payment of a note presently due, with authority to sell the stock at the broker's board, or at public auction or at private sale, at option, on the non-performance of the promise, without notice. The defendant sold the stock without demanding the debt or giving notice of the sale. It was held that he was bound to demand the debt before resorting to the sale. In the opinion it is said: "In every contract of pledge there is a right of redemption on the part of the debtor; but in this case that right was illusory and of no value if the creditor could instantly, without demand of payment and without notice, sell the thing pledged. We are not required to give the transaction so unreasonable a construction. The borrower agreed that the lender might sell without notice, but not that he might sell without demand of payment, which is a different thing."
In Wheeler v. Newbold (
In Allen v. Dykers (3 Hill, 593; S.C., 7 Hill, 497), the promise was to pay money sixty days after date, and stocks were pledged as collateral security, with authority to sell on the non-performance of the promise; the sale to be made at the *376 board of brokers; notice waived, if not paid at maturity. The stock was sold by the pledgees before the loan became due, and I infer, though it does not so expressly appear, that the sale was private and secret. The Reporter's syllabus of what Chancellor WALWORTH said as to the power to sell, is that "the contract did not give the right to sell the stock secretly at the board of brokers, in any event, but he was bound to put it up openly, and offer it to the highest bidder, stating that it was pledged to secure the note, with authority to sell." I have no objections to the remarks of the Chancellor, as indicating what should be done under such a power, in order to release a sale from any suspicion of unfairness or collusion. He cites no authority, and the remarks were quite unnecessary in the case, though, I think, well enough, under the general rule that the sale must be fair and open. They have no application to the present case, unless it be as an illustration of the construction put upon a power to sell at the board of brokers.
Wilson v. Little, 1 Sandf., 351, is the same case in 2 Comst. (supra). There is nothing in these cases in conflict with the view I have taken of the contract in this case. Considering the property, and the manner of selling such property, in connection with the authority to sell at private sale, or otherwise, in my opinion, a fair construction of the contract will exclude the necessity of giving notice of the precise time and place of sale.
It is also insisted that the defendant was bound to make a demand of payment of the margin personally of the pledgor; and that notice to redeem should have been given personally; and so as to the time and place of sale. No demand of the money loaned was made upon the borrower or his agent; and, in my opinion, this was not necessary in this case. The general rule is, that a demand of the debt must be made after it is due, before the pledgee can resort to his remedy by sale. In this case the money loaned was not due, and the parties had expressly agreed that, in case the stipulated margin should not be kept good "whenever demanded," then the authority to sell should arise. The demand to make the margin good *377
was made, and this was all the demand that the pledgee had at the time, a right to make. This demand was made upon Douglass, who as the jury have found, was the agent of Milliken in the transaction of the business, authorized to receive a notice of the kind. In my opinion this was a sufficient demand upon the general law of agency. If Douglass was the agent of Milliken in the transaction of the business, a demand made upon him was equivalent to a demand upon Milliken; and so, I think, as to a notice of sale in case any notice was necessary. I am aware that some of the judges speak of personal demands and notices. Thus, Judge BROWN, inWheeler v. Newbold (
There are some other exceptions, none of which were, in my opinion, well taken, and I think the case was properly tried, and that the defendant was entitled to judgment upon the verdict. The order granting a new trial should be reversed.
DENIO, Ch. J., and ROSEKRANS, J., took no part in the decision; all the other judges concurring,
Order reversed, and judgment absolute for defendant. *378