196 F. 800 | N.D. Ala. | 1912
(after stating the facts as above). As appears from the statement of facts and the master’s reports in these
Classification of the Roads.
The complainants insist that the classification of the railroads for rate-making purposes under the statutes referred to is arbitrary, and upjustly discriminatory, and is not based on any just relation between the railroads of Alabama which could fairly and honestly justify the. classification, whereby complainants are denied the rates accorded to other roads of the same or a higher class. It is difficult to understand the theory upon which the conclusion was reached that a .railroad p.ut, say in class 4 by the ‘ statute because of its bad loca
Ownership of stock can, of course, have no relation to the quality of a road or the cost of transportation, or change or affect in any way the elements of the cost of the services rendered in the transportation of passengers or freight, and any classification on a basis of stock ownership is inherently and obviously wrong. But section 2 of the act is now a matter of secondary importance. The original classification embraces by name the various railroads of the state, and the witnesses examined, all of whom were familiar with the characteristics of all of the roads, were unable to discover any basis whatever, having a relation to differences between their conditions, which could have been adopted by the Legislature for its classification. They testify that there does not exist any facts or fact in the nature, condition, or history of complainants’ roads which could justify the classification of the statute. They show that the Louisville & Nashville in Alabama consists largely of branch lines which are unproductive as compared to other roads allowed to charge from 15 per cent, to 45 per cent, more than it; that it ranks fourth in net earnings per mile on all business and is classed “1” by the statute, while other roads, such as the Alabama Great Southern, ranking third in net earnings per mile, is classed “2.” It is further shown that the net earning basis is not a rational one for classification, since it offers a premium for bad management. Roads may he alike in all particulars, and yet the management may make one prosperous and the other insolvent. Good management, therefore, should not cause a difference in the rates allowed. And, besides, the net earnings per mile of all business includes interstate commerce, which may create all the difference in that regard between the roads, and, of course, such differences thus arising cannot be the basis of classification for intrastate rates. And the same argument applies to classification on gross earnings per mile. It is shown, too, that the difference of the cost of construction and of maintenance cannot have been the basis of classification, since other roads costing less to construct and maintain than complainants’ are put in classes 2 and 3 and allowed to charge from 15 per cent, to 25 per cent, more than complainants’ which are put in class 1. It is shown that the Louisville & Nashville and South & North Alabama railroads
Andi the administration of these rate statutes, after their passage by the Regislature and by its consent under the direction of the Governor and through the orders of the Railroad Commission of Alabama acting in conjunction as the. administrative officers of. the state, has been unjustly discriminatory against complainants. A number of the railroads in the state filed similar bills to those of complainants attacking said rate statutes on the same grounds as complainants’ bills. After-wards such roads entered into agreements with the Governor of the state that, upon the dismissal of the bills of such complaining roads, they should be put in classes more favorable for charging rates. These agreements were carried out, and under them roads possessing equal or superior qualities to complainants’ in all characteristics upon which roads might be reasonably classified for rate making, such as cost of construction, cost of maintenance, earnings gross, and net per mile, were further classified more favorably for rate charges on freight business than they were in the statutes themselves, and were allowed! to charge 2^4 cents per mile for passengers, while complainants, having the characteristics as to such matters inferior to the favored roads, were forced to charge only 2cents per mile for passengers, and freight rates from 15 per cent, to 25 per cent, lower than such roads. These agreements were made in consideration of the abandonment by the roa'ds having the benefit of them of the right to litigate in the courts of the country the constitutionality of said rate státutes. There was and could be no legitimate reason or consideration moving between the favored roads and the state or its officials which could justify a classification for rate making to the prejudice of the complainants. Complainants being competing carriers, any classification which places equal roads in unequal positions, or unequal roads in equal positions, as to freights or reverses the natural relation of roads to the disadvantage of complainants, infringes their constitutional right to the equal protection of the laws. All this was done in these cases to the prejudice of the complainants by the classification of the rate statutes andl the administrative application of the policy of the statutes through the Governor and the Railroad Commission of the state of Alabama, contrary to the Constitution that neither enactment nor administration shall infringe on the right and privilege of equality before the law. No sufficient reason or excuse for these discriminations against complainants is shown, while the reasons against the same are cogent and apparent. It cannot be gainsaid, therefore, that no reason exists except that founded on want of information or other insufficient moving cause, not recognized in dealing with constitutional rights. Yick Wo v. Hopkins, 118 U. S. 356, 6 Sup. Ct. 1064, 30 L. Ed. 220.
It is next insisted that net intrastate earnings might have been the basis of classification, and that there is no evidence on this as to the several roads classified, but there is no bookkeeping by the roads or other persons or proof showing net intrastate earnings. There is no bookkeeping which could show net intrastate earnings of a railroad engaged in both interstate and intrastate commerce. The separation of the cost of interstate and intrastate service is an impossible problem.' The counsel for respondents say:
“If there^ is any accurate method of ascertaining the value of the property devoted to intrastate business, we have never heard of it, and do not know what it is.”
The net intrastate basis of revenue could not have been the basis of classification, and, if it was, the proof shows that the complainants
It does not require as strong a measure of proof to set aside legislative action where it is, as here, strictly speaking, administrative in its nature, and hinges upon ex parte inventories and calculations of the value of property upon which the lawmaking body without any hearing of the owner determines the reasonableness of a rate against him, as when the lawmaking body decides questions of policy in the other fields committed! to the legislative power. Constitutional rights are not to be enforced or denied upon technical grounds of pleading or views of the burden of proof. The courts in the adjustment of rights are often compelled to ascertain the existence of many things which are not capable of proof by mathematical demonstration, and, in ascertaining the adjustment of rights and: the remedying of wrongs, all that is possible or requisite is to get the best possible proof of which the nature of the inquiry is susceptible, and that, having been done, to determine the right accordingly, though it cannot be proved to a mathematical certainty, if it produces the requisite measure of conviction.
Rates Confiscatory.
The question of confiscation — the denial of that just measure of compensation the Constitution secures — depends on the value of th,e property devoted to intrastate business and the return the proposed rates will yield on such value.
As to this point, we may dismiss from consideration the case of the Nashville, Chattanooga & St. Louis Railway Company with a few words. The complainant has made its proof and submitted its case on the concession that interstate and intrastate business cost the same, while every one who has studied the matter knows that it costs at least 25 cents more to earn a dollar in intrastate than in interstate
South & North Alabama Railroad and Louisville & Nashville Railroad.
The South & North Alabama Railroad runs across the mountain ridges and streams of the slate, and extends from Montgomery to Decatur, a distance of 192.90 miles. The building of it involved deep cuts, high fills, extensive tunneling, and the construction' of costly bridges over large streams, one over the Alabama river at Montgomery, others over the forks of the Warrior river, besides across many creeks. For some distance above Birmingham to Decatur, and some 20 miles below Birmingham, the line is one of the most difficult of construction and maintenance, if not the most difficult of any road in the state. A considerable part of the road is double-tracked.
The Louisville & Nashville Railroad, which operates the South & North Alabama Railroad as one of its divisions, has, independent of the South & North, a mileage of 1,064.24 in the state and altogether in this and other states 4,306.62 miles of road constituting one great system. The road of the Louisville & Nashville in Alabama, however, consists in large part of branch lines doing mostly a local business, which, in so far as it is intrastate, is unremunerative. A large part of its tonnage is of raw materials for iron furnaces, and is carried at
The market value of bonds and stocks, while shedding in some cases light on the question of present value, cannot except in a very siight measure indicate what that value is as a matter of fact. The markei value of stocks and bonds merely shows the public estimate of the value of the whole property contributing to the income, v/hich may, as in the case of the Louisville & Nashville Railroad, embrace millions of dollars of property not used have as a common carrier. And this public opinion is also open to the influences of stock jobbing'manipulation and artificial bookkeeping, without the advantages óf sworn inven
Under inquiry 18 in the South & North Case the special master reports at page 72 et seq. the cost of reproducing the railroad and other properties, after deducting $328,419 from complainants’ figures, for the years named, as follows:
Tear ending .Tune SO, 1900. $20,01-3,714 84
Year ending June 30, 3907. 21,077,210 17
Year ending June 30, 3908..... 22,077,003 12
Year ending June 30, 3909. 22,151,800 36
Year ending June 30, 3910..... 23,372,752 27
Under the same special inquiry 18 at page 112 et seq., in the Louisville & Nashville Case, the master reports the cost of reproducing the railroad and other properties, including equipment used as a common carrier, after making deductions from complainants’ estimates of 8674,673.92, for the years named, as follows:
Year ending June 30, 1906. $41,258,565 60
Year ending June 30, 3907. 43,039.940 60
Year ending June 30, 3908. 40,800,319 22
Year ending June 30, 1909. 41,194,712 68
Year ending June 30, 193.0. 31,443,462 39
The respondents urged before the master all the objections now set up in the exceptions filed to his reports as to these values, and they were noticed seriatim, discussed, and disposed of by the master as shown in his "reports. After considering the exceptions, I approve and confirm the findings of the master on the questions of values and cost of reproduction, and overrule the exceptions in that regaid of respondents and complainants, and approve and confirm the master's reports thereon.
One of the objections of the respondents is that the estimates were based on the prices of 1907 when they were made, and that they were then unusually high. This is disposed of by the point that present values are required to be taken and used in determining present and prospective rates. Cotting v. Kansas, 183 U. S. 91, 22 Sup. Ct. 30, 46 L. Ed. 92; Willcox v. Consolidated Gas Co., 212 U. S. 19-52, 29 Sup. Ct. 192, 53 L. Ed. 382, 15 Ann. Cas. 1034; Stanislaus County v. J. C. & I. Co., 192 U. S. 215, 24 Sup. Ct. 241, 48 L. Ed. 406. And by the fact that the proof satisfactorily shows that the reconstruction could not have been effected from 1907 to 1910 at less than the estimates used. Record, S. & N. A. 116, 118, 368, 417, 430, 432, 497, 501; Record, L. & N., 365-367.
It is insisted that in reproduction estimates the enhanced value of property between the time of the original location of a railroad through
As to the amount of valuation, the undisputed proof is that it is the tax valuation at 60 per cent, of real value brought up to par or 100 per cent. This could not be excessive if the tax value was 60 per cent, of the real value, and the uncontradicted proof is to that effect, and the proof is that it is not excessive. As to the factum of evidence being in the record of the value, it is shown that the law charged the State Tax Commission with the duty of assessing the franchise for taxation, and they did so and fixed the value at 60 per cent, of the real value, and it is shown what these assessments were. Record, L. & N. Case, 1927, 1928-1960; Record, S. & N. Case, 1389, 1400, 1598, 1599, 2622-2627, 2628, 2629, 2644-2648.
The assessments relied on were state valuations by officers specially delegated to make them, and not merely to receive the returns of the taxpayer. They are therefore competent evidence of probative worth. Wigmore on Evid. § 1640; Elliott on Evidence, § 1312; Ronkendorff v. Taylor, 4 Pet. 349, 7 L. Ed. 882. As to the propriety of valuing the franchise on a rate question, the authorities clearly settle the point in the affirmative. I refer to the master’s report in the South & North Case, pp. 41-46, where he considers the question. in an able manner, and I concur thoroughly in his conclusion. I merely cite here the authorities. Willcox v. Con. Gas Co., 212 U. S.
“But when, in the case of the business of a railroad company, we seek to determine the value of that portion of the entire property which is devoted to intrastate traffic, separate from the value of that portion devoted to interstate traific, when precisely the same property is devoted to both classes of traffic jointly, and to determine the expense of doing the intrastate business, separate from the expense of doing the interstate business, when the expenses incurred and charged are incurred in doing both classes of business jointly, we are dealing in pure eonjectui-e — conjectures such as would not be received and made the basis of an injunction res!raining the operation of a statute in any kind of an issue other than a railroad rate issue. Not only is any known method of ascertaining those facts uncertain and conjectural, but they are facts which from their very nature are incapable of ascertainment even approximately. No two railroad accountants agree as to the proper method of ascertaining these facts, and all agree that they cannot be ascertained' accurately. We insist that they cannot be ascertained with even an approximate accuracy. It has been said that, notwithstanding the difficulty of ascertaining the value of property devoted to intrastate business and the amount of the expense incurred In doing the intrastate business, wo must do the best we can to that end, and then, however uncertain and speculative the result, a state statute establishing intraslate rates must stand or fall according to that result. A proposition or principle of law, the justice of the application of which is made to depend upon the proof of facts which are not susceptible of proof, or at least can only be guessed at or ascertained by arbitrary and conjectural methods, must be fallacious. * * * How is it possible for a court in the ordinary rate case to be convinced clearly and beyond all doubt that a particular schedule of rates necessarily denies just compensation for the use of the railroad company’s property, when the essential facts upon which the conviction must be based are from their very nature speculative and conjectural?’
This exposition by counsel, if accepted, would result in one of two propositions; One, that the state could fix rates for inter and intra
The difficulty of the problem arises from the fact that the cost of transportation involves an assessment on the subjects of commerce of charges to cover common, general, overhead, or nonhaulage expenses and also the haulage cost, and that there is no way of allocating such charges to the transportation items when the property is used in common as stated by counsel for the respondents. It cannot be said what share of these common expenses shall be apportioned to an intrastate ton or passenger being transported. It may be in the same train and car with interstate tons and passengers. The solution of the question has heretofore been made to rest entirely on the experience and testimony of experts as to the relative difference in cost of the two services, and in every case in which the question has arisen the witnesses have, while agreeing on the fact that local or intrastate business is more costly than through or interstate business, varied very widely as to the amount of such difference. The variation is from 10 per cent, to 500 per cent, against the intrastate business. Smyth v. Ames, supra. It was pointed out in Chicago, etc., v. Tompkins, 176 U. S. 179, 20 Sup. Ct. 336, 44 L. Ed. 417, that any solution of the question on a gross revenue basis without regard to the difference in the relative cost of the two services was an absurdity. And so the difficulty was attempted to be overcome by putting a load, as it is called, on the intrastate revenue to equalize it for the purposes of comparison with the interstate. And the amount of this load was determined by
Appreciating the unreliability of any solution of the question of difference on any revenue basis, the Louisville & Nashville Railroad Company undertook to ascertain the difference on the basis of the comparison of the actual cost of conducting each business, and at great expense took an accurate account of the cost of every particular item of transportation for a period of a week or more over their lines in Alabama, allocating such cost when possible and apportioning it when impossible of allocation between the interstate and intrastate business. It was shown that the period selected was a fair and average period of business. By this method, which is called the “unit of service basis,” the actual relative cost of doing the interstate and intrastate business was arrived at. The plan and method of the operation is explained in the report of the master in the Louisville & Nashville Case at pages 165 to 195. Of course, as pointed out in the report, the proportion of the actual cost of many of the accounts of expense allotted to the two services was necessarily based on the judgment or opinion of the officers in actual superintendence, as no allocation in such cases was possible. And for this reason there would necessarily be room for saying, as to the conclusion or result, that, however honest, it contained to that extent the inherent infirmity of opinion proof. But it happens that the results are confirmed in several ways which remove all uncertainty as to their accuracy and justness in these cases. The Louisville & Nashville has 13 divisions of its line in Alabama in which separate accounts are kept of the interstate and intrastate gross earnings, and of the actual expenses of such divisions without separation between interstate and intrastate traffic. These accounts are shown in Exhibit W. A. C; 67. In some of these divisions the interstate traffic predominated; in others the intrastate. An analysis and comparison of the earnings and expenses in the intrastate divisions, and of the earnings and expenses in the interstate divisions, reveals the fact that just in proportion as the intrastate traffic exceeds the interstate business in the divisions the cost of earning a dollar on all business increases, and that the difference between the -cost of earning a dollar in the interstate business is greater than that shown in the results of the application of the unit of service basis. Master’s Report, I,. & N. Case, pp. 161-165. By the unit of service basis the result is that it costs at least 25 per cent, of the revenue more to earn a dollar of intrastate revenue than it costs to earn a dollar from ail business. Record, L. & N. Case, 1600.
The complainants in the Louisville & Nashville Case and the South & North Case show, also, by algebraical calculations founded on equations taken from accurately kept accounts of the earnings and expenses of their roads, that the excess of earning a dollar in intrastate business over all business is 32 per cent, of the revenue in the Louisville & Nashville Case, and in the South & North Case 26 per cent, of the revenue. This is explained and shown in the Louisville & Nashville Case, Record, pp. 1600-1608, Master’s Report, 165, and in the
The yearly ratio of the income of the complainants to these values for the years 1906, 1907, 1908, 1909, and 1910 is shown in the master’s report under inquiry 28. From the report it appears that the Louisville & Nashville Railroad had the net income or loss on its intrastate business as follows for the years named:
For the year ending June 30, 1906, net profit.38%
For the year ending June 30, 1907, net loss.'.95%
For the year ending June 30, 1908, net loss. 3.97%
For the year ending June 30, 1909, net loss. 1.91%
For the year ending June 30, 1910, net loss.82%
See Master’s Report, 211, 212.
And that the South & North Alabama Railroad had the following net income or loss on its intrastate business for the years named:
For the year ending June 30, 1906, net loss.53%
For the year ending June 30, 1907, net loss.46%
For the year ending June 30, 1908, net loss. 1.59%
For the year ending June 30, 1909, net loss. 40%
For the year ending June 30, 1910, net loss. 025%
—Master’s Report, p. 150.
These percentages are those on the income as affected by the statutory rates. Without the statutory rates the percentage would have been larger of profit or less of loss, but not to an extent to alter the result as to the question involved since, without the statute, the intrastate earnings afforded no fair return. It appears that in the Louisville & Nashville Case the intrastate business resulted in the year ending June 30, 1906, in a net profit of .38 per cent, on the value of the property and in the following years, including 1910, in a net loss of from .95 per cent, in 1907 to 3.97 per cent, in 1908. And in the South & North Case there was a net loss each year varying from .025 per cent, in 1910 to 1.59 per cent, in 1908.
The respondents insisted in argument that the intrastate rates on great tonnages of raw material not affected by the statutes in question. were abnormally low, and might be increased to materially augment the income, but they overlooked the fact that a statute belonging to the same series approved February 9, 1907, prohibited any increase of .the maximum rates prevailing January 1, 1907 (Acts Ala. 1907, p. 80), and, further, that these rates had prevailed for many years
The exceptions, filed by the respective parties to the report of the master on the questions of earnings and the expenses of the business and the division of the same between interstate and intrastate traffic are disallowed and overruled. The same questions were raised before the master, and were severally considered and correctly ruled on as shown in his report.
Contrasting the ratio of total income from entire business with the ratio of intrastate income for the same periods, we have for the Louisville & Nashville Railroad Company:
f entire business.... For the year ending June 30, 1008.. o . , . . , B ( intrastate business. 4.94% .38%
f entire business... For the year ending June SO, 1907.. .4 . . , , , . „ . ” ! (intrastate business (loss).. 3.92% .95%
(entire business. For -the year ending Juno 30, 1908.. , , . .. , (intrastate business (loss).. 1.28% 3.97%
... ,. „„„„ fentire business. For the year ending June 30, 1909...( . , , . . , Lmtrastate business (loss).. 3.45% 1.91%
,. f entire business. For the year ending June 30, 1910...( . , . ^ , . „ , (intrastate business (loss).. 5.20% .82%
And for the South & North Alabama Railroad:
„ ("entire business......5.74% For the year ending June 30, 1908.. J . ' Lintrastate business (loss).53%
„ ,, ,. (entire business...5.79% For the year ending June 30, 1907. ..H ' (intrastate business (loss).48%
_ . .. r entire business.2.67% For the year ending June 30, 1908., ( intrastate business (loss).1.9o%
f entire business. 5.45% For the year ending June 30, 1909...4 „.... (intrastate business (loss).04%
f entire business.5.80% For the year ending June 30, 1910... 4 ...... .. ’ (intrastate business (loss).02o%
The above tables are from the report of the master under inquiry 28, and are on basis of income after deducting statutory losses; that is, what the income was under the rate statutes after it went into effect. The year ending June 30, 1906, was before the statute, and most of the year 1907. It is evident that the most radical errors in valuations, if made, would not, on correction, show a fair return to complainants on the property invested. It is shown that the statutory rates effect a loss of from 10 per cent, to 50 per cent, reduction on the rates prevailing before the statutes were passed on the same commodities, and that the total losses to the Louisville & Nashville per annum on account of the statutory rates is $263,252.52 on the basis of losses for the six months from June 30 to November 30, 1909. (Master’s Report, L. & N. Case, p. 205, and record tiñere cited); that the South & North losses are, oti the same basis, pfcr annum $210,-286.46 (Master’s Report, S. & N. A. R. R., 124, -find record cited).
The proof shows that a garment selling at retail in Alabama at 50 cents and weighing half a pound has a freight rate of 26 cents per hundred pounds from Mobile. The freight on the garment is I3/ioo of a cent or 1/3so of the price. Cotton overalls selling at $1, weight one pound, have a freight rate of 26 cents per hundred pounds, and the total freight is sa/ioo of a cent on the garment. This view is applied in the proof to long schedules of the commodities affected by the rate statutes (U. & N. Record, 3635), and demonstrates that 10 per cent, or 20 per cent, reduction in the freight rates would and does not make the goods any cheaper to the ultimate consumer or purchaser. The people buy from necessity, and their demands are not enlarged nor
The gross earnings of the Louisville & Nashville Railroad in Alabama for the year 1910 amounted to $8,434,099.08, and on intrastale business $3,615,102.61. Take 10 per cent, or 20 per cent, or 40 per cent, from these sums, and there would be left in the case of 20 per cent., only $470,221.77 of net income for entire business, and only a ratio of 1.13 per cent, on value of $41,443,462.39, instead of a ratio of 5.20 per cent., without this 20 per cent, reduction in income from rates. A similar catastrophe would follow in the case of the South & North Road, and, it is believed, of any road in the United States. There is no margin of 20 per cent, or even 10 per cent, to be spared on the earnings of any road. And, of course, as there was during that year (1910) a net loss of .82 per cent, without such supposed reduction of 20 per cent, of rate income on intrastate business, the reduction of 20 per cent, or even 10 per cent, would add to such loss.
The effect of the statutory reduction of rates then in these cases is to inflict a direct additional loss on the intrastate business, in the case of the Louisville & Nashville of $263,252.52, and in the case of the South & North of $210,286.46, per annum, when there was no net income above operating expenses on such business under the prevailing rates when the statutes'in question were enacted making the reductions. Of course, such being even proximately the result, it is evident that the Legislature misapprehended the situation when the statutes were enacted. Inter and intra. state business consist in the transportation of persons in any number, and of freight in any quantity, for any distance, on the fines of the carrier. At first view, it may appear surprising, at least to ordinary observation, that it costs relatively much more to do tlie intrastate than it costs to do the interstate business in the aggregate. The explanation is that the intrastate business generally involves short hauls with many stoppages and in less than car load lots; while the reverse is the case with the interstate business, which is generally through traffic with full loads, fevr stops, and for much longer hauls. It is evident that there is more profit in full loads, long hauls, and few stoppages than in the reverse. Another difference in tlie relative costs of the two traffics arises from the fact that the cost is composed of two classes of items — those affecting distance Or haulage, and those not affecting distance or non-haulage or terminal charges. It is estimated that 90 per cent, of a 30-mile haul is made up of nonliaulage cost, but the nonhaulage cost is uniform; that is, it does not increase with the length of the haul. It attaches alike to intrastate and interstate shipments.. Ret me illustrate this: A terminal charge at the point of starting say is $1 per ton, or any sum. Now, if we take an intra and an inter state ton
“We hear much about a reasonable return on capital. A reasonable return is one which under honest accounting and responsible management will attract the amount of investors’ money needed for the development of our railroad facilities. More than this is an unnecessary burden. Less than this means a check to railfoad construction and to the development of traffic. Where the investment is secure, a reasonable return is a rate which approximates the rate of interest which prevails in other lines of industry. Where the future is uncertain the investor demands, and is justified in demanding, a chance of added profit to compensate for his risk. We cannot secure the immense amount of capital needed unless we make profits and risks commensurate. If rates are going to be reduced whenever dividends exceed current rates of interest, investors will seek other fields where the hazard is less or the opportunity greater. In no event can we expect railroads to be developed merely to pay their owners such a return as they could have ob-*831 tamed by the purchase of investment securities which do not involve the hazards of construction or the risks of operation.”
The whole question was elaborately discussed' in Central of Georgia Railroad v. Railroad Commission of Alabama et al. (C. C.) 161 Fed. 925, wherein it was held that railroad companies in Alabama were entitled to be permitted to earn a net profit of 8 per cent, per annum on the value of the property employed by them in intrastate business so long as the business was done without unjust discrimination and at reasonable rates.
The Maximum Rate Act.
Two years before the enactment of the statutes complained of, the Railroad Commission of Alabama made an exhaustive investigation of the reasonableness of the intrastate rates then charged in Alabama, the net revenues the carriers derived therefrom, and decided among other things that “the net earnings shown by the several railroads operating in Alabama are not in excess of a fair and just return upon the legitimate value of the properly employed,” and that reductions would be confiscatory. A table annexed to the opinion then rendered showed that the Louisville & Nashville Railroad Company earned 2% per cent, from its domestic business on the proportion of its property devoted to intrastate business, and that there was a deficit in the case of the Nashville, Chattanooga N 8t. Louis Railroad Company. Nothing is shown in the proof in these cases, or by any matter of which
Interference With and Control of Interstate Commerce.
It has been strenuously insisted on the one side and denied on the other that the rate statutes in these cases as to local rates necessarily affecting interstate rates on an interstate road amount to a direct regulation of, and control of, interstate commerce, and that the statutes are void on that ground also. The argument in support of that contention is stated in a masterly manner by Judge Sanborn in Shepherd v. Northern Pac. Ry. Co. et al. (C. C.) 184 Fed. 765. The master sustained those views, and held that the state had no power to make rates on railroads engaged in interstate commerce. As I have held the rate statutes attacked in these cases void on two distinct grounds, I deem it unnecessary to go into the question of their being void on a third and distinct ground that they directly interfere with and control the interstate commerce of the complainants. This direct point is involved in the Minnesota case now before the Supreme Court and will doubtless be decided within a few weeks. While Congress under its power to regulate interstate commerce and to preserve its uniformity may have the power to annul state rates which interfere with that result, I do not believe that under the present statutes Congress has done so. I will therefore sustain the exceptions of the respondents in the several cases to the master’s findings on this point.
Counsel for complainants may prepare a draft of the decree in accordance with this opinion, and submit it to counsel for respondents.