16 Ga. 217 | Ga. | 1854
Lead Opinion
The Court not being unanimous, the opinions of the Judges were delivered seriatim.
By the Court.
delivering the opinion.
The reason given for this decision of the Court below was, that in the petition there was no allegation that the charier of the Planter’s and Mechanic’s Bank had been - forfeited, and 'that an assignee had been appointed. And it was insisted for the defendant in error, that though a recital or recognition of both these facts was to be found in the public laws of the State, yet that no party could have tho benefit of a public law, without proper pleading.
This latter remark may be very correct: but what is necessary to proper pleading is the question — -just the question, here.
It seems to be well settled, that setting forth a public statute, and the facts which it recites, is not necessary to proper pleading. “Public statutes, and the facts which they recite or state, must be noticed by the Courts, without their being stated in pleading.” (Bac. Abr. Stat. L. 2 Wils. 376. Willes, 210. See the reasons of Lord Ellenborough, 4 M. & S. 542. 1 Black Com. 86. 1 Ch. P. 246.)
This rule is not in conflict with what was decided by this Court, in Dougherty vs. Bethune, (7 Ga. R. 90.) There the -decision was, that the recital of a fact in a public statute, did not operate to estop a party defendant from denying it by plea, and putting the fact in issue. It was not held, that it was necessary for a plaintiff suing, to set forth such a fact, although it were recited by a public statute; but simply, that the defendant might deny it in his plea, and in this event the plaintiff must prove it. And this Court afterwards says in Beall vs. Beall (8 Ga. R. 210,) and in Thornton vs. Lane (11 Ga. R. 521) that although such facts may not be conclusive, Courts must “ treat them as true, until the contrary appear.” The inference from which is, that whilst they remain uncontroverted, as facts stated or recognized by a public statute, the rule of pleading which we have been considering, applies.
The forfeiture of the charter, and the appointment of the
It is our opinion, that this provision of our Statute, declaring that “ no person shall be permitted to deny any deed, bond, bill, single or penal note, draft, receipt or order, unless he shall make affidavit of the truth of his answer, at the time of his filing it,” (Cobb. Dig. 486) applies where the execution or factum is alleged to be the act of the party filing the answer,, or adopted by him. In the case before us, the liability of the stockholder is not placed upon any act of his, in connection with the execution of the bills. If he be liable, he is so, not because by the factum he has promised to pay these bills, but because of the fact, that by becoming a stockholder, and subjecting himself to the terms of the Statute in such case made and provided, he has, as it were, guaranteed the payment of' the bills. His guarantee is not like that by endorsement; for in that event, it might be said, that he had adopted the factum r but he has guaranteed them only, by becoming a stockholder under the provisions of the act of incorporation. Eor aught, that is known to him, or for any thing that he has done, the bills on which this suit was based, may have been all spurious.
Let us take a case which will readily serve as an illustration A contracts with B by letter, or otherwise in writing, for a sufficient consideration, to guarantee all bills which C may draw on D in favor of B within a specified time, and not exceeding a certain amount. 0 draws a bill which is accepted, but not paid by D; and B brings suit against A. Now, if the action had been instituted against C and D, the drawer and acceptor, it is”very plain that by our Statute they would not be permitted to deny the genuineness of the instrument, save upon oath. But it seems equally plain, that this rule should not apply to A, who knew nothing, and could be supposed to know nothing
For a similar reason, the execution of the bank bills sued on in this case should have been proven.
This raises the question, whether or not the return of nulla bona made by the Sheriff on this execution, is conclusive against the stockholder. A question not without considerable difficulty.
On the one hand, it. would seem that more should not he required of the bill-holder, than that he should pursue the due and ordinary course of law in exhausting the property of the bank; that this is a reasonable and practical test of his diligence ; that any diligence beyond this, should reasonably devolve upon the Sheriff, whom the law appoints to assume such responsibility and exercise such diligence, and who is in a position to do it with .advantage; or upon the stockholder who has an ultimate liability, was interested in the issuing of the bills, .and may have made gains and profits by them, and who being, as it were, in community of interest with those who issued the bills, and are holding the effects of the corporation, (if there be •any) thus possesses facilities which may enable him to discover effects, and have them subjected to the payment of the bills. Something like an analogous rule preyails in other cases, where there is an ultimate liability. The return of nulla bona, upon an execution issued on a judgment against an administrator for a devastavit, is conclusive, as against the sureties, in an action against them on the bond. A return of non est inventus, by the Sheriff, upon a ea. sa. issued in an action where bail had been taken, is conclusive against the bail, in a suit upon the recognizance.
To this may be added the consideration, that if the stockhól
On the other hand, it must be admitted that the stockholder, in this case, was no party to the proceeding against the bank, if he were not cognizant of the suing out of the execution, and the efforts of the Sheriff to find property of that bank; (and if he had been so apprised, he could have pointed out property,) would have no inconsiderable cause of complaint, should he now be concluded by the Sheriff’s return. It would seem but reasonable, that he should not be held responsible, unless he had had some notice of the effort to find property; as such notice might have put him upon diligence, and have enabled him to protect himself.
If this stockholder, in reference to this transaction, that is to say the emitting of these bills by the bank, could certainly be regarded as a privy, I should doubt the legal necessity of such a notice; but from what I have said on another point, it is evident that I regard him, in his peculiar relation to these bills —a relation created by statute, as a sort of guarantor, by a contract separate from that on which this bill-holder obtained.
Even in the case of bail, though their relation to the principal is so intimate a one, I find, that according to the long-established practice in England, it was directed that the ca. sa. should lie four days in the office, in order to give the bail, notice, that the plaintiff had elected to take out execution against the person of the principal, so that they might have the opportunity of rendering his body before the capias issued. Merritt vs. Montfort, (Barnes, 54. 2 Salk. 599. Petersd, on Bail, 358.) And in the case of a return of nulla Iona, on an execution issued upon a judgment against an administrator for a devastavit, to which reference has just been made by me, may it not be, that in view of the close interest between the principal and his sureties, and the fact that that interest is created by the same instrument or contract, the return is considered conclusive, partly because the judgment is regarded as notice to the sureties, that a fi. fa. will be sued out, and the Sheriff put upon the search for property ?
In view of all these things, and especially in consideration of" the fact, that the peculiar statutory liability of this stockholder places him in a relation to the bank, which is not precisely analogous to that of either party or privy at Common Law, I am willing to unite with my brethren in holding, that the best and most reasonable rule which can be prescribed in such a case is, that the return of nulla Iona should not be considered conclusivo against him, unless due and proper notice be previously given to him, by which ho may, if he choose, be put upon diligence in the search for property.
The effect' of this decision was equivalent to the declaration, that the plaintiff, in this case, who brought suit on nineteen hundred and twenty-five'dollars, of bills, against a stockholder owning one hundred shares, out of the ten 'thousand shares, of which the capital stock consisted, (or ten thousand dollars of the one million of capital stock,) was entitled to recover on the bills held by him and sued upon, only the proportion of of one hundred shares to ten thousand; that is to say, the one hundredth part of his claim, .or nineteen dollars and twenty-five cents.
The determination of this question turns mainly upon the construction which is to be placed upon the language used by the Legislature in the eleventh section of the Act incorporating this bank, viz: that the persons and property of the stockholders shall be bound for the ultimate redemption of the bills,, “ in proportion to the amount of shares, and the value thereof, that each' individual or company may hold in said bank.”
It must be observed, that the language here is not, that the persons and property of the stockholders shall bo bound in the ]proportion which his shares bear to the whole capital stock of the bank, but it is, in proportion to his shares. The proportion stated, is not a comparative relation of his shares to the capital stock, but such a relation of his liability to the number and value of his shares. He shall be liable, says the charter, in proportion to what he owns of the stock. Nor does the act of incorporation say, that the stockholder shall be bound for the ultimate redemption of the bills to each bill-holder “in the proportion his- shares bear to the whole stock,” which is the effect of the construction in the Court below, but it simply asserts a general liability for the redemption of the bills, (that is all the bills,) in proportion to the amount of his stock. It is very plain, therefore, that the proposition stated by the Court below, in the use of the words “ which his stock bears to the whole capital stock,” is an interpolation on the Statute.
The Act incorporating the Georgia Rail-road & Banking •Company contains a provision similar to that under consideration, making the persons and property of the stock-holders liable for the ultimate redemption of the bills. And no one will question, that the Legislature intended that this provision .•should have the same signification and effect in both charters, and in all the charters of banks in our State, where it may be found. Now the capital stock of the institution I have just mentioned, is upwards of four millions of dollars; there are some seven hundred stockholders, at present, and it is possible there might be as many stockholders as shares; that is to say, more than forty thousand. For many years, this bank has had a circulation of near one million of dollars. If it were to become insolvent, what would be the consequence ? By the provisions of the charter, these numerous bill-holders have, or were intended to have, a remedy against the stockholder, for the payment of their bills, “ as in common actions of debt”; and according to the construction which prevailed in the Court below, (and which is insisted on as that only which is just,) in order to have the benefit of this provision secured by the Act, each of these bill-holders would be compelled to institute suit against at least seven hundred, possibly forty thousand stockholders. This would be hard enough — perhaps impracticable and out of the question, even if the bill-holder happened to possess some hundreds or thousands, in bills of the bank. But lot us suppose that he had only a small amount (he might have but five dollars, or even one dollar) of these bills. In reason, justice, and according to law, he would be as much entitled to have payment for that, as for thousands. It might, indeed,
Let it not be said, that he could part with his bills to some one having more of them, and who could afford to sue, for this is as much as to say, that he could sell them at a sacrifice. It should not be believed, for a moment, that in legislating so important a provision, for the benefit and protection of bill-holders, the General Assembly of our State intended to make such a sacrifice necessary to the poor man or the small bill-holder. That body certainly designed to put every citizen upon the same footing of reason and justice, and to supply a ready and efficacious remedy to each and all.
The illustration thus presented, serves strongly to show the hollowness of that boasted justice attributed to the construction contended for by the defendant in error, of that provision which we have been considering.
I cannot consent to impute such a scheme to the legislative mind, and turn from it, to some more just method of enforcing this provision of the charter.
So far as the rights of bill-holders are concerned, it would be better, if what the stockholder is liable to pay, could bo dis
This construction gives effect to the Statute, and carries the obvious intention of the Legislature into effect, by supplying every bill-holder with a speedy and efficacious remedy. In order, therefore, to give complete effect to this provision of the charter, creating a statutory liability, if there were nb analogy at Common Law, it would be necessary to adopt a construction which holds, that the stockholder became liable to pay every, or any of the bills to the extent of his stock; that he guaranteed each so far as the extent of his stock, and not a portion of each bill, sufficient, in the aggregate, to make up the amount of his stock; ■and that this liability ceases when an amount has been recovered from him, equal to the value of his stock; and such recovery he can plead in bar of any other action against him by a bill-holder. This construction interpolates nothing on the
I can conceive that another construction might be placed upon the words, “shall be pledged and bound, in proportion to-the amount of shares and the value thereof, that each individual or company may hold,” &c., if the question were presented, as to the extent of the stockholder’s total liability, with reference to the whole circulation of the bank. If, at the time of the dissolution, or perhaps at the time of the suit’s commencement, (should the assignee have redeemed some of the bills after the dissolution,) the whole amount of bills was greater or less than the whole amount of the stock, the liability of the stockholder would be on all of them; and it would seem not unreasonable, that in such case, it should be in proportion to his stock. If' the circulation exceeded the capital. stock, then his liability would transcend his stock, in the proportion which that stock bore to the whole capital stock of the bank. If the circulation, was less than the capital stock, then his liability would be less,, in a similar proportion. Eor example: if the circulation had been one million one hundred thousand, at the time specified, this stockholder’s liability being one per cent, or as one hundred shares is to ten thousand, he would be liable to pay eleven thousand dollars of the bills. Rut if the circulation was only nine hundred-thousand, then he would be liable to pay only nine thousand dollars of the bills. The recovery, however, in a particular case, would not be of a certain-per cent, on each bill sued upon by a bill holder, .according to the construction-which I have been opposing, but would be for the whole amount of the bill-holder’s claim, provided it did not exceed the proportion of the stockholder’s liability.
It is possible that the terms of the charter, which we are considering, may have been emplpyed, in part, at least, in the-sense which I have just expressed. Rut it is unnecessary to decide this question, as it is not presented by this record. There is before us no evidence, as to the amount of bills in circulation at any time, and no evidence that there is, now, any
The construction which I place upon this statutory liability of the stockholder, has its analogies in other liabilities at law. An example may be found in the liability of sureties upon a Sheriff’s bond. Although many persons be injured by the misconduct of the Sheriff, if one vigilant suitor exhaust the penalty of the- bond, no further recovery can be had thereon, against the sureties, by any other person. But I will put a case still more to the point. We will suppose, that on the same da.yj for a similar consideration, and payable at the same time, A gives his promissory notes, payable to bearer in different sums, amounting, in all, to twenty thousand dollars, to twenty payees. Desirous of using these notes in some common transaction, these persons, by a separate instrument, in writing, agree to guarantee the notes, each severally binding himself for the payment of the whole, in proportion to the amount of the note received by him from A provided A should, himself, be unable to pay. The notes are then transferred and assigned to other persons, upon the faith of this .guarantee. Sometime after they have become due and payable, C a holder of one amounting to one hundred dollars, brings his action thereon, and upon the guarantee against B a guarantor, and one of the original payees of a note, amounting to one thousand dollars, proves the insolvency of A in the proper way, and demands a judgment against B. Now, if he had sued in Equity, or if the holders of the other nineteen notes had filed their bill and •taken him there, and had shown that their notes were unpaid, then, perhaps, he could have recovered from B, only such proportion of his claim as B’s note bore to the whole amount; that is to say, the one-twentieth part thereof. But C is not taken into Equity, we will suppose, and no objection is made by the other note-holders, to his recovery — they may have been
It would not be difficult to find other analogies; but the length to which this opinion has already reached, admonishes me to forbear.
Let the judgment be reversed.
Concurrence Opinion
concurring.
The Court being of one mind, as to the first three grounds of alleged error, I shall address myself to the fourth only— which is, that the presiding Judge held that the plaintiff could recover such proportion of his bills only, as the stock owned by the defendant bears to the whole capital stock of the bank.
Now, the counter proposition to this and that, which I hold to be true, is, that the plaintiff is entitled to recover the whole amount of his bills out of the defendant, provided the number of his shares and the value thereof, estimated at $100 per share, is equal to the amount of the bills sued on. And there being a diversity of. opinion among the members of the Court, upon this point, I shall proceed to state the reasons, as it is made my duty to do, in support of the view which I entertain.
This action is brought on the Xlth section of the charter of the Planter’s & Mechanic’s Bank of Columbus, which is in these words : “ the persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and held bound, in proportion to the amount of shares and the value thereof, that each individual or company may hold in said bank, for the ultimate redemption of the bills or notes issued by said bank, in the same manner as in common actions of debt; and no stockholder shall be re
The case must be decided, of course, upon the proper construction of this clause in the charter, the phraseology of' which is not so explicit,- perhaps, as it might have been.
The following positions, I believe, are not denied or doubted in any quarter; at least, they are too well established to be successfully controverted:. That under this and similar provisions, in bank and other charters, the liability of the stockholders is several, not joint; that inasmuch as the measure of Jihis statutory liability may be wholly different in each case, depending upon the number of shares held respectively by the stockholders, a joint suit, at Law, would be impracticable, as there could be no joint judgment; that the Act does not intend that the stockholders should be sureties for each other— each being severally responsible for the amount of his own stock, and no further. Some of the stockholders may have removed beyond the jurisdiction of the Court, so as not to be reached by its process, or affected by its judgment: or have-become insolvent;, still, under this section, those who are liable- and solvent, cannot be made to pay more than they otherwise would, on that account. That the remedy provided by the Xlth section of the charter, is not only essentially, but exclusively a Law remedy; the liability, whatever it is, is to be enforced “ in the same manner as in common actions of debt”. That if the redress at Law should prove to be inadequate, from any cause whatever, the Superior Court, sitting in Equity, will take jurisdiction over a bill filed by one or more of the creditors, in behalf of himself and others, against all the stockholders who are solvent and suable, concurrently with a Court of Law, over separate actions, against each of them, upon his sole and separate liability. That in Equity, the rights of all concerned, on both sides, might be considered at once. It might be consideredhow much was due in the whole and to all those who should choose to adopt this remedy; and a decree might go against ••each for his share of the liability; that it is the privilege of
The question then, at issue, is narrowed down to a single-point; in a separate suit at Law, by action of debt, at the instance of a bill-holder against a stockholder, shall the plaintiff be entitled to recover the whole of his bills, if they do not exceed the amount of the defendant’s stock, or shall he recover a ratably portion only; that is, as the stock owned by the defendant bears to the whole capital stock of the bank ?
According to the construction heretofore put by this Court, upon this Act, while it was designed to create a personal liability on the part of the stockholders, it, at the same time, limits that liability. Had the section under which this suit is brought read, “ the persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and bound for the ultimate redemption of the bills or notes issued by the bank”, the only construction off such a provision could have been, that the stockholders were liable in their natural capacities, as partners, for the whole amount of the unpaid bills or notes, whatever that amount might be. But the insertion of the intermediate words, that they are to be bound “ in proportion to the amount of shares, and value thereof, held by each”, curtails the general liability, and prescribes, in the first place, not only personal and several liability — but, secondly, so restricts it that no stockholder can be made responsible, in any event, beyond the proportion which the number of shares held by him, bears to the whole number into which the capital stock of 10,000 shares is divided.
If this, then, be the true meaning of this section, and in my judgment it is all that it proposes to effect, it follows, of course, that the creditor, in his action at Law, may recover the whole of his debt, and not a proportion of it only. At any rate, this will be regulated by general principles, uncontrolled by the Statute.
Were the words of the Act ambiguous, and its grammatical structure doubtful, such exposition should be given to this section, as would best harmonize with its design. And every fair and reasonable intendment ought to be made, to effectuate the intention of the makers of the law, fro bono publico. (Heyden’s Case, 3 Rep. 7. Plewden’s Commentaries, 1057, b. Rex vs. The Eastern Counties Railway Company, 2 Q. B. Rep. 347. Williams vs. Pritchard, 4 T. R. 2. Lyde vs. Bernard, M. & W. 113. Pierce vs. Hopper, Str. 253. New River Company vs. Graves, 2 Vernon, 431.)
Indeed, these and numerous other authorities, ancient and modern, which might be cited, go quite beyond 9tho foregoing well settled rule of construction, and maintain that the words of a Statute may be construed in a sense different from their ordinary meaning, when the Act is designed to remedy some existing or threatened mischief. But I am not, and never have been, the advocate of an enlarged interpretation of Statutes or Constitutions. In the words of Mr. Justice Coleridge, “ I would never mould the language, in order to meet either an alleged convenience or an alleged equity”; and, I will add, or an alleged public policy. And if I felt that the construction which I am endeavoring to uphold, put any force on the meaning of the Act, I should refuse my concurrence, without the clearest and most indisputable evidence of legislative intent. But when the Xlth section of this charter declares that the stockholders shall be bound in proportion, it does not say, to the number even, but to the amount of shares, and the value thereof, they may severally hold, and that, too, as in common actions of debt, is there any straining of language to insist that they are respectively bound, according to the amount
What was the case of Coulter et al. vs. Robertson, (2 Cushman, 278,) that has been commended, so earnestly, to the favorable consideration of this Court ? A trustee of a dissolved bank was appointed by Statute, to sue for and collect money sufficient to pay all the debts of the bank. And what was the result of the judgment of the Mississippi Court, in that case ? Why, that the trustee might select the particular debtors to the corporation, that he would sue first; and that these had to pay, “ to the uttermost farthing,” what they owed the corporation, while all the rest went free — and this among debtors standing as these stockholders do — precisely upon the same footing. Equality of burdens was certainly wholly overlooked or disregarded, in this decision.
But suppose we have been wrong, heretofore, I maintain that the next most consistent and rational construction of which the words of the Act are susceptible, is this: That instead of the aggregate liability of the stockholders being limited to $1,000,000 only, the amount of the capital stock, they are bound for the ultimate redemption of all the unpaid bills issued by the'bank, be it one million or any other sum. And I confess there is much reason in favor of this interpretation of the charter.' It is true that the charter declares, that the stock of the company, shall consist of $1,000,000, tobe divided in shares of $100 each. But the capital is not expressly limited to that sum. It does not even say, as is usual in monied charters, that thé capital shall not exceed or be more than one million. The convenience of the intended stockholders, as well as notice to the public, required that the amount of the company’s funds should be fixed. But in this case, not only is there a departure from the common practice, in this respect, but by another fundamental rule of the corporation, they are -allowed to contract debts by bond, bill, note or other security,
Suppose that instead of $1,000,000, the unpaid circulation, ■upon the failure of the bank, had amounted to $3,000,000, may not the Legislature have intended that' the stockholders •should be personally bound for the eventual payment of the whole of this sum ? The corporation was authorized, under certain circumstances, to create this amount of indebtedness ; and the presumption is, that it was done for the benefit of the corporators. But whether this be so or not, the liability would have been incurred by the duly appointed agents of the company ; and if a total loss ensued, even to the extent of absorbing both profits and capital, ought third persons to suffer ?
If this be the true exposition of this individual liability sec-lion — the clause under consideration means this — that the ■stockholders shall be personally and severally responsible for the ultimate redemption of all the unpaid bills and notes of the bank, be the same more or less, at least up to three millions.
But the question recurs, how liable ? Still, not as unincorporated persons, but in terms of the charter, in proportion to the amount of shares held by each, and the value thereof, viz: if the circulation to be taken up amount to $200,000, and the defendant, Mr. Harris, owns 100 shares, he is liable for $2,000. If the unredeemed circulation be $1,000,000, he is bound for $10.000: if $3,000,000, for $30,000. This construction makes the measure of each stockholder’s interest and right to •dividends, the measure, also, of his responsibility. And thus forecloses the question of contribution, as between' the stockholders, themselves, because no one of them can be compelled, under any circumstances, to pay more than his proportion of the whole debt. And in this way, all real or apparent hardship is avoided.
I concede that the true constructive effect of this clause is not clear, beyond a doubt. And as I grow in years, at least, if not in wisdom, I have learnt to repose less confidence in my own, as well as in the opinion of others, however authorita
That the same individuals should be permitted to repudiate debts which they have contracted as corporators, is contrary to all the inflexible rules of law and justice, as applied to every other business transaction of life. The Legislature has already, by the Acts of 1843 and 1845, adopted this principle and made it applicable to all corporations, except banks and insurance companies. (Cobb’s Digest, 542-3.) And I am content, therefore, to administer the law as I find it settled by the sages of the science who have gone before me, “ whose shoe’s latchet I am not worthy to unloose”.
Either of the two views which I have undertaken to present of this question, stand equally opposed to the idea of a ratable liability nfon each bill.' For in the last light in which it has been contemplated, it would only be incumbent on the plaintiff to show that the proportional liability of the defendant, upon his hundred shares, for the outstanding bills, was sufficient to cover his demand; and he would be entitled, as under the first view taken of the Act, to a recovery for the whole amount of his claim. I thus yield what might, perhaps, admit of debate, to-wit: that the onus would be upon the plaintiff, to prove the amount of the unredeemed circulation. And this he could do by resorting to the books of the bank — its published reports, and by such other testimony as he might have it in his power to procure.
It is, indeed and in truth, as was “forcefully” urged in the finished argument of Mr. büsbet, a practical denial of the benefits of the Statute, and an utter repudiation of the legislative policy. Let this ratable liability doctrine obtain, and these personal and individual liability clauses, which have been introduced into our modern charters, will become a dead letter. To hold that every man who is unfortunately the owner of a five dollar bill of one of these insolvent corporations, shall either sacrifice it at a forced sale of ten cents in the dollar, or some other nominal sum, or institute a hundred suits at law, to get his money, or file his bill, bringing all the bill-holders and all the stockholders before the Court, at a cost of fifty times the amount of his claim, is to contravene and render nugatory this most wise and beneficent policy of the Legislature.
In Russell et al. vs. The Men dwelling in the County of Devon (2 D. & E. 667) where the question was, whether an action would lie against the inhabitants of a county, for an injury sustained by an individual, in consequence of one of the public bridges being out of repair, Mr. Justice Ashurst said, “if separate actions have to be brought against each individual of the county for his proportion of the damages, it is better that the plaintiff should be without remedy” — and so we say hero.
But it is said that the mischiefs to be apprehended from this decision of Judge Starlce, are too highly colored. It is suggested that the stockholders will, in most cases, upon the mere presentation of each bill, promptly pay their respective quotas; and that recourse need not be had to the Courts to compel
However the fact may be, therefore, the section must be construed as intended to supply a -coercive proceeding — and we must, of course, spell out the meaning and will of the Legislature, in that aspect of the Statute.
But were it otherwise, the inconvenience to the small bill-holders (and nine-tenths are of this description) of seeking satisfaction in this way, even could they succeed, by getting a modicum contributed by each stockholder, on whom they might successively call, would be little less than would be incurred by every bill-holder dragging every stock-holder to Court, to collect out of him his ratable proportion.
It may be contended, that this is the only sort of liability-which takes an equitable view of the rights of all the bill-holders, as well as the liability of all the stockholders. That the former have equal rights as creditors, to demand and receive payment of the latter, and that to allow one or more to collect the whole of their money out of one or more of the solvent stockholders, by means whereof a portion of the rest may be entirely excluded, is unjust, and consequently, ought not to be sanctioned. This objection, so far as it in reality exists, arises not from any defect in the law, but from the imperfection of all human institutions. Each stockholder owes to a bill-holder the amount of the value of his shares. It is a statutory debt, quasi ex contractu. The bill-holders are in the position of a number of creditors of a common debtor, who is bound only to pay a given amount. They stand primarily equal in their right.
So in Corning vs. White, (2 Paige 567) it was held that the filing of a creditor’s bill, gave to the vigilant creditor the right to priority; and that there was nothing in the principle of equal distribution among all the creditors, pro rata, which has been considered powerful enough to set aside the priority already acquired by a vigilant creditor. Hubbard et al. vs. Hamilton Bank (7 Metcalf's R. 340.)
Favored as rent is in England, a landlord could not there, until the Statute of Ann, destrain goods taken under execution, and which were, as it is called, in custody of the law. That Act gave him a remedy for one year’s rent, but no more. The industrious creditor seized and appropriated the rest. Is not the whole doctrine of the Statute of Limitations founded upon the maxim, vigilantibus non dormientibus jura subveniunt ? The law regards those who watch, and not those who sleep— the law is only for the protection of those who use diligence to protect themselves. In popular actions to recover penalties, the right to which is given to all the people in common, he who brings his suit, and can obtain the first judgment, secures a title, to the exclusion of every body else.
A most striking illustration of this principle is to be found in the lair, prescribing the order in which the debts of an insolvent testator or intestate are to be paid, by the executor or-administrator. The Statute directs, peremptorily, that the legal representative shall pay first, funeral and other expenses of the last sickness, and so on. Besides, it is u'ell settled that
So in Ashley vs. Pocock, (3 Atkins. 209) Lord Sardwicke said, “ Suppose two creditors at large of the first testator, Barnsley, and one brings a bill before the other, and obtains a final decree and a report of the master, and that report has been confirmed; and then the other brings a bill, and obtains a final decree, and his demand is affirmed, to be sure the executor ought to have paid the first who used the first diligence. So in case of an action at law, the creditor who obtains the first judgment, should be preferred”.
The very motto of the law is, “the race is to the swift.” Why the priority given by law to first judgments, first attachments, first deeds, first mortgages, the first entry of public lands — the first every thing ? The universal response is, non leges vigilantibus, non dormientibus subveniimt. Even the miller’s rule is, “first come, first served”, which is a strong, though homely translation of this fundamental maxim. It was recognized and enforced by this Court, in the case of a Sheriff’s bond. Bothwell vs. Sheffield, (8 Ga. Rep. 569.)
The Sheriff of Dooly County had given his bond, in terms of .the law, in the sum of $5000. It was to indemnify all persons aggrieved by the official misconduct of himself and his deputies. Moneys were collected by them on executions, far exceeding in amount the penalty of the bond, and which they failed to
On the demurrer, the Court below dismissed the bill, upon the ground that the complainants had a complete Common Law remedy. And this Court affirmed the judgment, and held that whenever, by previous recovery, the penalty of the Sheriff’s bond has been exhausted, the sureties may, even at law, plead this fact and protect themselves from further liability — • and this being the case, it would be unjust to more vigilant suitors, who had been injured by the official misconduct of the Sheriff, to restrain them from prosecuting their rights at law.
We say of a case eurrit quartuor pedibus, or that it goes upon all fours, when it is exactly similar in its circumstances to the case in support of which it is quoted, or when it is exactly in point. Bothwell vs. Sheffield is all that and more. Eor in this case, every one of the execution creditors whose money was collected and withheld, was equally entitled to participate in the security, provided by the Sheriff’s bond, as was every other person aggrieved by the misconduct of that officer, whether a judgment creditor or not. And yet a Court of Chancery refused to entertain an injunction upon the application of the securities, to restrain the creditors who had first sued, upon .the ground, that the liability of the securities was limited by their bond; and that they might protect themselves by a plea to that effect, as well at Law as in Equity. And that this being so, the vigilantibus doctrine should not be disturbed.
I have said that this case covers the one at bar, and that it does more; and it is true in this, namely: that the creditors of the Sheriff have but a single fund to which they can look: whereas, in the case before us, every other stockholder besides the ones sued, is also liable to every other bill-holder for the amount of his shares. And unless some of them are bankrupt,
Had all the bill-holders severally sued the corporation before its dissolution, would not the first judgments have been first satisfied ? And yet all could not have been paid had the corporate property been limited in value. And this. would have been a parallel case to that of the Sheriff’s bond, why should a different rule prevail, when proceedings are instituted against the corporators to charge them personally, instead of against the corporation ? a rule which is contrary to all the analogies ■of the law, and in conflict with the maxim and motto to which I have referred; and which are indelibly inscribed over the ■door-way of every Court-house ? It is certainly not for the benefit of the bill-holder, whatever other interest it may sub-serve.
I am sufficiently conscious that the opinion in Bothwell and Sheffield is more than questioned by the decision of Judge Starke. It is virtually over-ruled, and with it, in effect, though unintentionally, of course, the Act of the General Assembly, passed in 1847, and approved December 30th of that year. (Colb 502.) Eor, on examination, it will be found that the opinion of this Court is in literal conformity to the provisions of that Act. Indeed, it was based upon it, and was so under.stood by the author of the New Digest, -as will be seen by his marginal reference. And although that Statute was passed for a different purpose, it is nevertheless a plain and palpable legislative recognition of an old Common Law principle.
This Act is directory of the mode of entering up judgment on official or voluntary bonds.
And it not only repeals the rule as laid down by this Court, in Stephens and others vs. Crawford, Gov. (3 Kelly’s Rep. 499) that there can be but one recovery on a bond at Common Law, but it affirms, by clear and irresistible implication, the •doctrine that, primarily, all persons injured by the misconduct
While this Statute stands in the Book, it is in vain to talk of the unreasonableness of the rule about to be established in these bank cases. Both are in strict accordance with the whole logic of the law; and are, I had almost' said, indissolubly interwoven with the- whole frame-work and superstructure of the science.
When the inquiry is made then, who is the promisee, under this quasi contract, and which bill-holder shall have the preference ? shall he who is sharpest and who has outstripped the rest in the race, receive payment, while others who are more modest, though equally, if not more meritorious, are postponed ? we answer, should even this result follow, which can hardly be anticipated, “ so the law is written”.
The State, in permitting a paper currency, has evinced great care to prevent any injury or loss to the people. It has adopted this measure, amongst others, for this purpose. No legislation can absolutely protect the community against the possibility of loss, because no legislation can, as was said by the Court in another case, “make the directors of all the banks equally skilful and prudent — all their officers honest and all their debtors solvent”. Still, in construing these Acts, we should steadily keep in sight the end for which they were passed. And in case of doubt, that interpretation should be preferred which, while it saves a multiplicity of suits and consequent accumulation of costs, will, at the same time, afford the best safeguard against the evils of adventurous banking. Acting under proper restrictions, and honestly and faithfully performing the duties assigned them by their charters, these monied institutions will always prove valuable instruments of public utility and convenience. But relax these legislative checks, and the grossest management, not to use any harsher terms, must and will be the natural and inevitable consequence.
I am not satisfied that the return of the Sheriff can be controverted in this suit, especially as the return was made in the county, where the bank was located, and where, it is reasonable to suppose, it had property subject to the fi. fa. if any where. No case was adduced to authorize it. Goodall vs. Stuart, (2 Hen. &. Mang. 105,) is a precedent directly against it. And I find it very difficult to answer, satisfactorily to my own mind, the reasoning upon which that decision was made. Such a practice would be attended with difficulties which would seem to be almost insuperable. Besides, the general principle is indisputable, that a return by the Sheriff is conclusive between the parties, and can be impeached only in an action, ■against the officer, for a false return. It required a special Statute to authorize the impromptu answers made by Sheriffs, to rules and orders taken even against] Mm, to be traversed. (Cobb, 579.)
And suppose it be true, that there are assets belonging to the bank, as the plea alleges, these very assets belong to and are the property of the stockholders, which distinguishes this case from that of principal and security, to which it has been likened. But I forbear to discuss this assignment.
Dissenting Opinion
dissenting.
When this case was called up, Mr. Dougherty, one of the Counsel for the plaintiff, objected to my presiding in it on three grounds — First. That a case or cases like this was pending in the Superior Court of Muscogee County, in favor of the plaintiff in this case, against Mrs. McDougald, as the executrix of Daniel McDoughald, deceased, and that at the time of my being elected a Judge of this Court, I was of Counsel for her in the case or cases.
• Secondly. That cases like this were pending in that Court in favor of other persons than this plaintiff, against Col. Sea-born Jones, as a stockholder in another bank — the Chattahoochee Rail-road & Banking Company, and that Col. Jones was my father-in-law, and had been, at the time of my election as Judge, my client in those cases.
Thirdly. That the Counsel for the defence, in each of the cases commonly called the “bank cases,” to which cases belonged this, had agreed, among themselves, to make, or had made “ common cause” in the defence of all the bank cases; and so, that all of those Counsel were to be considered as substantially •engaged in the defence of each and every one of the cases; that, consequently, I was to be considered as having been, at the time of my election, substantially one of the Counsel for the defendant in this very case.
These grounds I did not think sufficient to support the objection, and therefore, notwithstanding the objection, I presided in the case. Was I right in this ? That I was, I will state my reasons for thinking.
First, then, as to the third ground. That ground, as far as it concerns me, has no foundation, in fact. I never made any agreement with any body, to make common cause in the defence of the bank cases, generally, or of this case, in particular. I never took part in the defence of the cases generally, or in the defence of this.
As to the other two grounds, I shall admit them to be sub
I take this to be a true principle of law — that it is the duty of a Judge to preside in all cases in which he has had given him authority to preside. This principle, it seems to me, necessarily results from the relation of principal and agent — that relation in which the State and a Judge stand toward each other. The State delegates to a citizen authority to decide cases. Why ? I can conceive of no reason why, except that the State wishes him to decide the cases. As to the purpose of the State, in the delegation of the authority to him, there are but three things that occur to me as supposable — one, that the State wished the authority to be used — one, that the State wished the authority not to be used — one, that the’State was indifferent whether the authority should be used or not. To say that the State wished the authority not to be used, is to say that the State is so foolish as to do an act which is not merely superfluous, but an act which can have no result, whatever, except a result which defeats the State’s wishes. To say that the State was indifferent whether the authority should be exercised or not, is to say that the State is both so foolish as to do a superfluous act, and is indifferent whether wrongs done by one of her citizens to another shall go unredressed — whether wrongs done to herself shall go unpunished — whether right, public or private, shall be left without a guard: and to say this, is to say that the State has prepared the whole body of her law, both civil and criminal, without an object; for if the State be indifferent whether her laws be executed or not, what motive can she have had for preparing those laws ? To say that the State’s purpose was, that the authority should be exercised, remains the only thing supposable.
Now, what is the will of the principal, is the law of the agent;
It is not for the Judge to elect one sort of case for presiding in, and to reject another. If any thing of that kind is to be done, it is to be done by the State. As to the Judge, the cases all stand upon the same footing.
If, when the Judge has been authorized to sit in all cases, it is not his duty to sit in all, which are to be the excepted ones — > and what is to be the ground of exception ? Are they to be cases in which, for some reason or other, it would be disagreeable to the Judge for him to preside ? If so, whether the Judge shall preside in any case whatever or not, will depend upon the Judge’s pleasure. Are they to be cases in which, for some reason or other, it would be disagreeable to the parties, or to any party, for the Judge to preside? If so, whether the Judge shall preside in any case whatever, or not, will depend upon the pleasure of any party in the case. And what cases remain tb be the excepted ones, if none of these are to be excepted cases ?
But as to the Judges of the Supreme Court, this duty, it seems to me, has been prescribed to them by the Act organizing that Court. That Act, in its third section, says, “ It shall be the duty of all the Judges of said Court to attend,- at each term; but if, from Providential cause, any "one of-said Judges cannot attend a Court, such Court may be holden by two Judges.”' Why is it made the duty of each-Judge to attend at every Court? There can be but one answer — that each may sit and take a^ part in deciding the cases returned to every Court — in deciding one of such cases as much as another, provided that the authority to each Judge to sit in one, is the same as it is to sit in another. When the authority to sit in one case, is the same as •it is to sit in another, is not the duty to sit in one, the same as-
Considering it, then, to be true, that it is the duty of a Judge to sit in all cases in which has been given him authority to sit, I proceed to the question — what cases are they in which no authority to sit has been given a Judge? What cases are they which a Judge is disqualified to preside in? These being seen, those which a Judge is qualified to preside in will also be seen.
It is a maxim of the Common Law, that a man cannot be judge in his own cause. “ Aliquis non debet esse judex in propria causa." (1 Coke Litt. 141 a.)
Within this maxim a number of cases have been held to fall, although not cases in which the Judge was a party, viz : cases in which the Judge, though not a party, had an interest. (14 Vin. Abr. 574-6.)
Then there have been a number of other cases, in which individual Judges have held themselves disqualified to sit, although they were neither parties in the cases nor interested in them. A Judge has declined to sit on account of “ being connected with the parties”, (5 Maule & Sel. 21,) or “ being ■connected with one of the parties,” (5 Durnford & East, 5,) or for having, when at the bar, been “ Counsel in the cause,” (1 Barn. & Adolph. 605. 1 Brod. & Bing. 161,) or for having been “ consulted” in the cause, (6 Barn. & Cr. 566. 3 Barn. & Adolph. 2,) or for having been “ concerned” in the ■cause, (2 East. 272, do. 389, do. 478, do. 520, do. 555, 3 do. 245, do. 393, 2 Bos. & Pul. New. R. 451.) There have been cases in which two out of four Judges have declined to give any ■opinion, “as they had been engaged in the case while at the bar,” (5 Maule & Sel. 103.) In Doe ex dem. Early of Jersey vs. Smith, (5 Maule & Sel. 475,) a case of this sort, Lord Tfflenborough said
The example of these English Judges has been followed by the Judges of this Court. Instances of that are to be found in 1 Kelly, 29, 275, 348, 365, 402, 466, 481, 513, 525, 598, 639.
To bring all of these cases within the maxim, that a man shall not be a judge in his own cause, it is necessary, it must be confessed, to read that maxim most liberally, according to its spirit and not to read it according to its letter. Rut if they cannot be brought within it, they have to stand without justification, for there is no other maxim or law, of which I am aware, within which they may be brought.
Admitting them to be within the maxim, it may be doubted whether the maxim, itself, has not been repealed by the part of the Constitution of the State which provides for the establishment of this Court, and by the Act of the Legislature which establishes the Court.
In the Constitution are these words: “ The Supreme Court shall consist of three Judges”, &c. “And the said Court shall, •at each session in each district, dispose of and finally determine each and every case on the docket of such Court, at the first term”, &c.
The expression “ each and every case”, is broad enough to include all cases of the kinds above enumerated. And all cases which it includes, the Court is required to determine; and the Court is declared to be a something which shall consist of three Judges; and is it not clear that what consists of but two Judges does not consist of enough to constitute that something ? Did not the Constitution intend that it should take all three of the Judges to make a Court ? If it did, then, when it required the Court to determine “each and every case” on its docket, it required each of the three Judges to sit in each and every such case; for the sitting of each Judge is essential to the making of the Court, and so is essential to a determination of any case by the Court. In short, if the Constitution intended it
The third section of the first article has these words:— “The Senate shall be elected biennially” “and shall consist of forty-seven members,” &c.
The seventh, these: “ The House of Representatives shall be composed of one hundred and thirty members,” &c.
The twelfth, these: “a majority of each branch shall be authorized to proceed to business, but a smaller number may adjourn from day to day, and compel the attendance of their members in such manner as each House shalkprescribe”.
In the old Constitution, that of 1777,-are to be found provisions similar to these, and also a.provision in these words: “All causes” “shall be tried in the-Supremo Court”, “which Court shall consist .of the Chief Justice and three or more of the Justices residing in the county. In case ■ of the absence of the Chief Justice, the senior Justice on the bench shall act as Chief Justice”, &c.
This language in the third and seventh 'sections, which the Constitution applies to both branches of the Legislative department, is the same, or the same in substance, as that in another section, which we have seen it to apply to as much of the Judicial department as is constituted by the Supreme Court. The Supreme Court shall consist of three Judges”. The language, therefore, it is to be presumed, was applied to the Supreme Court in the same sense in which it had been applied to the two branches of the Legislative department. But as to those branches, is it not clear that the Constitution considered the language as saying, that to make a senate, it should take full forty-seven members; to make a House of Representatives, full one hundred and forty; for if the Constitution did not consider the language to say this, what, reason had it for inserting the provision contained in the twelfth section. The provision that
Now this provision in the twelfth section, is confined to the two branches of the Legislature. It is not extended to the Supreme Court. It is not said of the Supreme Court that a ■majority of its members shall be authorized to proceed to business. And inclusio unius exclusio alterius.
Indeed, an argument of the same sort is to be drawn from the sixth section of the third article which concerns the Inferior Court, in which it is said, “ the Inferior Court shall have power to vest the care of the records and other proceedings therein, in the Clerk; or such other person as they may appoint, and any one or more Justices of the said Court, with such Clerk'or other person, may issue citations and grant temporary letters”, &c.
The Act ofjhe Legislature for organizing the Court is, in this particular, stronger in some respects, perhaps, than the Constitution. It uses this language : “ the said Court shall consist of three Judges,” &c. “ It shall be the duty of all the Judges of said Court to attend at each term of said Court: but if, from Providential cause, any one of said Judges cannot attend a Court, such Court may be holden by two Judges. If only one Judge shall attend a Court, it shall be his duty to open the Court, and to adjourn it to a day not more than two days beyond the regular term, at which time, if two Judges do not attend, the Court shall, in that case, be adjourned to the next regular term.” (Sec. 3.) “ The Supreme Court shall proceed, at the first term, (unless prevented by Providential cause) to hear and determine each and every cause which may, in manner aforesaid, be sent up,” &c. '
“If, from Providential cause, any one of said Judges cannot attend a Court, such Court may be holden by two Judges.” Is not the implication this: that if the cause which keeps a Judge absent be Providential, then the other two Judges may hold the Court: but if the cause be any thing else than Providential, then the other two may not hold it. If so, again inclusio unius exclusio alterius.
In other respects, the Act is like the Constitution — like that, it requires the Court “ to hear and determine each and every cause which may be sent up” to the Court.
All these things taken together, not to mention the rules of the general law, as to the strict construction of naked powers, and as to the manner of executing powers delegated to more persons than one, I think there is enough to make it most doubtful whether both of the following propositions are not true : First. That it takes all three of the Judges of the Supreme Court to make that Court, on all occasions, except those on which Providential cause prevents one of the Judges from, sitting. Secondly. That the Court, thus made, has to hear and determine each and every case before it.
If it be assumed that both of these propositions ai e true, then it follows.that-the rule, a man ought not to be a judge in his-own cause, is repealed, unless the words “each and every case” be restricted in their- meaning.
Let it be assumed, that these words are not to be restricted in their meaning, and that with these words, in their unrestricted meaning, the propositions are true.
This assumed, let us apply the propositions to a possible case, and see how they will work.
Suppose the case before the Supreme Court to be a case in which one of the Judges of that Court is an actual party — say the defendant in error. What would be the effect of these propositions, if true, on such a case ? This: First. All three of the Judges would have to sit in the case. Secondly. There would be a chance for reversing the judgment. Two of the three Judges would be disinterested, and they, if the other dis
The effect, then, of these propositions, if true, ujdou the case supposed, would be to give the plaintiff in error, the party opposed to the Judge, a chance for a judgment in his favor — a chance for a reversal.
Suppose, now, the plaintiff in error to object that the Judge, who happens to be the party defendant in error, ought not to sit; and that that Judge yields to the objection, what is the effect of that ? It amounts to an affirmance of the judgment below. The effect is to make the Judge certainly gain the case, and the objecting plaintiff, his adversary, certainly lose it.
Now, the only difference between this supposed case and the real case is, that in the real case, the Judge, against whose sitting the objection was made, was not at all a party in the case. He was only of Counsel in a like case — only the connexion of a party in a like case.
But suppose the words, “ each and every case” in the latter of the two propositions, are to be restricted in their meaning— restricted to such cases as by the law existing at the time when those words were used by the Constitution and the Statute, it was lawful for a Judge to preside in, viz: cases in which ho was not a party and so forth, then what would be the effect of the propositions upon the case supposed ? The certain affirmance of the judgment of the Court below. One of the Judges would be the defendant in error. He could not sit. The other two.
The difference between this supposed case and the real case has been above stated. The effect of yielding to the objection, that the Judge ought not to preside in the real ease would, these propositions, in this restricted sense of the words, “ each and every case”, considered as true, have been to make the party objecting certainly lose his case. The effect of not yielding to the objection, was to give him a chance to gain it —a chance which, as it happened, resulted in success.
Now I have not said that I consider to be true, both or either of these propositions, viz: first, that it takes all three of the Judges of the Supreme Court to make a Court, on all occasions, except those on which one Judge is, by Providential cause, kept from sitting. Secondly, that the Court, thus made up of all three Judges, must determine “each and every case” before it. What I say is, that it is very doubtful to my mind whether they are not true.
If true, and the words, “ each and every case” in the second, are to have their literal meaning, then I think it clear that the law expressed by the propositions, repeals the maxim, that a person ought not to be a judge in his own cause.
If true, and these words are not to have their literal meaning, but are to have a meaning restricted to cases in which, by law, it was lawful for Judges to preside, viz: cases in which they were not parties or the relations of parties, or in which they had not been of Counsel before they became Judges, then the-law expressed by the proposition does not repeal that maxim; but it is capable of producing, in some cases, an effect which it-was the object of that maxim to prevent from being produced
The questions involved in these propositions have never, as far as I know, received any consideration from the Supreme Court. The Judges of the Court, however, have, from the beginning, acted upon the notion that two Judges could make a Court and render a judgment, not only in cases in which the cause that kept the other Judge from sitting with those two was Providential, but also in cases in which the cause was other than Providential, as in cases in which the Judge was- a relation of one of the parties, or had been of Counsel for one of them.
It has frequently happened that one Judge has declined to sit in a case for one of the reasons aforesaid, and the other two have rendered a judgment in the case. The example thus set by the other Judges, I have felt myself, not without some difficulty, at liberty silently to follow. The practice, as far as I know, has not been complained of by those on whom it has had direct operation — the parties in such cases, or by any others — still, I must say that I have never yet made up my mind, as to whether a judgment pronounced by two only of' the Judges of that Court, in a case in which the third did not sit — did not sit for some reason that was not Providential, was valid.
Admit, therefore, that the old maxim — a man cannot be a-judge in his own case, has not been repealed or at all affected by the parts of the Constitution, and of the Statute organizing the Supreme Court, to which I have referred, yet, it is certainly true that by those parts, the maxim has not been enlarged. It is certainly true, that no reason can be found in those parts of the Constitution and of the Statute, to multiply ■.the variety of cases to be subjected to that maxim.
This maxim, then, being to be taken as in force, to its full extent, what is that extent? It is what we have already seen. The extent is to disqualify a Judge from sitting in all cases im
Say the Judge is a stockholder in a bank or in a rail-road, or has a relation that is one; or at the time of his election as Judge, was Attorney for the bank or the rail-road, or for some stockholder in either. The case is against another bank, or rail-road, or stockholder, in one or the other, and is such as to-involve the question, whether a bank, as the indorser of a bill of exchange, is liable, on notice of dishonor given to the president or to the cashier, or to the teller, or to a director ; or liable without any notice at all; or liable if the indorsement is not made by signature and counter-signature of president and ■cashier ; or liable if the indorsement is not directly and expressly authorized by the board of directors, &c. &c.
Or such as to involve the question, whether the rail-road is liable, as a common carrier, &c. &c.
Or such as to involve any question, as to whether either the bank or rail-road is liable, under the general law applicable to corporations.
Or such as to involve the question, whether a failure to do ■something required to be done by some provision which is com
Or such as to involve the question, whether the Legislature has not power to repeal a charter.
Or in short, say the case is such as to involve any of the thousand possible questions which are common to all banks and all rail-roads, and all stockholders in either.
Or say that the Judge happens to be a landholder, by grant, from the State, or is a relation to a person that is such landholder, or was, when elected Judge, Counsel for a man whose case turned on the validity of a grant from the State for land, and the case before him is that of some other man, which involves the question, whether the Legislature can annul a grant or make a young grant take precedence over an old; or whether a grant carries with it mines and minerals, or any of the possible questions which are common to all grants.
Or say the case is one which involves the question, whether one of the. parties to it is bound to pay the poll-tax imposed by the general tax law on all persons, the Judge included, he insisting that the Legislature has no power to pass such a law.
In this case — in all these cases, and in others indefinitely numerous, of similar character, this reading of the maxim makes it illegal for the Judge to sit.
The result of such a reading would be, or come near to being, to make the cases in which a Judge is disqualified to sit, as numerous as those in which he is qualified to sit. And such a result I know of nothing sufficient to bring about, except a law made by the law-making power — a law sufficiently enlarging the maxim, a person ought not to be a judge in his own cause, to bring it about.
The case in which this objection to my sitting was made, is, in some respects, a peculiar one. On one side of it the party is the holder of bank bills ; is therefore one of a class, which, for all practical purposes, may be said to include in it all the,people of the State, not even excepting the Judge objected to, for every man holds, or expects to hold, the bills of some bank; and so, has an interest in preserving a sound bank-bill cur
Question — which party to this case, is it most to the Judge’s interest to decide in favor of ? If he decides against the bill-holder, and can get one or both of the other two Judges to go with him, it is possible that the decision may, in the long run, work to the benefit of his father-in-law, by having some influence, in fact, on the decision of the case against him. If he decides against the bill-holder, but cannot get either of the other two Judges to go with him, it is not possible for his decision to work at all to the benefit of his father-in-law, because a dissenting decision or judgment counts for nothing.
From this is to be seen the degree of interest which the Judge has to decide against the bill-holder.
If he decides in favor of the bill-holder, it is possible, perhaps not improbable, that he shall please nearly every man in the State, as every man is the holder of the bill of some bank, or is continually expecting to be; if, in so deciding, he puts in possible peril one who is as near to him as father-in-law, and also one or more who were as near to him as clients, it is possible — is it not probable — that he shall give nearly every man in the State exalted pleasure — fill him with a proud rapture at the idea of having to preside over him, a Judge of such magnanimity — such purity — such love of justice.
Behold what the Judge stands a chance to gain by deciding in favor of the bill-holder.
By deciding against the bill-holder, may the Judge lose any thing ? The Judge, by deciding against any bill-holder at all, risks offending the whole, or nearly the whole of his fellow bill-holders — a class co-extensive with the people of the State — by deciding against one, when it is possible that such, the Judge’s decision, may operate to the benefit of a person who stands to the Judge as father-in-law — of another who stands to him as a former client — the Judge risks not only offending this proportion so large — of this class so extensive — he also risks inspiring it with the horrible suspicion that he is a corrupt Judge. The Judge risks more than his popularity.
See, then, what the Judge, by deciding against the bill-holder may lose.
A dissenting decision against the bill-holder — a thing that counts for nought — has not the Judge every thing to lose— nothing to gain by making that? If yet he will sit and make such a dissenting decision, does it not seem certain that he is ■actuated, in his conduct, by some motive stronger than that of personal loss or gain ? Does it seem impossible that that motive can be a sense of duty ?
The only reason given in support of the objection to the Judge’s sitting in this case was, that the decision of the case would be, in law, a decision of the other cases. It was said that this case would be a precedent for those, and that Courts are bound by precedents.
This is a mistake. Courts are bound by nothing but law, and nothing is law but something that is made law by the lawmaking power. Courts are not this power. They are express
In a case between A and B, say as to what is lawful interest for money. The Court decides it to be tender cent. Are all future Courts, in all future cases, to say it is ten per cent. ? or-are they to go by the word of the law-making power, which, says such interest is seven per cent. ? In the case supposed, however, say the decision is, that the interest is seven per cent. Are future Courts, when they too say seven per cent, to be considered as saying so because of that decision, or because of that law on which that decision rests?
What, then, is a decision worth ? It is, to the parties to it, worth all that a law would be worth. To the parties to it, a decision may, indeed, without any great departure from propriety of language, be said to be a law. To A and B, the parties to it, the decision is a law — to the rest of the alphabet it is none. Are previous decisions, then, worth nothing, to operate on future decisions ? Decisions are evidence to show the opinion which the Judges making them have, as to what the law is om the question decided. They are evidence of opinion, and they are worth what opinion is worth. What opinion is worth, depends upon many things. It is. worth nothing, when it stands-on one side, and law stands on the other. When it is doubtful on which side the law stands; then Judicial opinion, as to the side on which the law stands, if it be of good quality, and especially if it be also of good quantity, is worth much. But in no case does it govern — in no case is it law. The respect which is paid to it, is paid voluntarily. The Courts, if they choose to depart from it, and go by their own original opinion of what the law is, always do so. And what respect is it likely that Courts would voluntarily pay to a decision made by a Court, one of the members of which was, say a party to the decision ?
■ Re the influence of precedents, however, what it may, there is no law which says a Judge is disqualified to sit in a case, the decision in which may chance to be claimed as a precedent in some other case in which he or some connection of his, or some person whom he was Counsel for at the time when he became Judge, may be a party. And there is a law, as I think I have shown, that he must sit in all cases in which he has been authorized to sit.
■ Upon the whole, my conclusion was — Eirst. That it is a Judge’s duty to sit in every case in which authority to sit has been given him. Second. That authority had been given me to sit in this case.
So, considering it to be my duty to sit in the case, in it I sat. I was not aware of any right in me to make the case stand on a footing different from that on which other like cases stand — of any right in me to have one rule for one case, another rule for a fellow case.
■ I may remark that this, my opinion, of what law and duty is on the point in question was known — well known to the Legislature which made me Judge.
- In this case, the plaintiff in error, by his Counsel, insisted that the following proposition is true: “our proposition is, that plaintiff is entitled to recover the whole amount of his bills out of the defendant, if the number of his shares and the' value thereof is equal to the amount of his bills; and that a recovery against the defendant, is a good plea, in bar to any and all actions brought against him by bill-holders, except as to costs”. I quote from the printed argument of one of the Counsel— Judge Nisbet.
' Ry the woi'ds “value thereof,” the Counsel mean the value of the shares got by considering the shares as each worth one hundred dollars. They say, “we admit, as stated by this Court, that the liability of the defendant is proportional. He
By the words, “a recovery against the defendant, is a good plea in bar to any and all actions brought against him by bill-holders, except as to costs,” they, the Counsel, mean not only that such a recovery is such a good plea in bar, but that a voluntary payment of the bills made by the stockholder, is equally such good plea in bar. They mean that the stockholder will be as much protected, if he volun tarily takes up bills, as if he is forced, by suit at law, to take them up. They say, “if we are right in our positions, that the defendant is our'idebtor to the full amount of his liability, and that we have the right to demand and have it of him, then it follows, as an inevitable legal inference, that he cannot be compelled to pay it to any body else. Satisfaction to us is a defence to him against the world. According to naked principles of justice, as well as the settled rules of the law, a man cannot be compelled to pay to any body, a debt which he has paid to the rightful creditor, or for which, to him, he has become personally charged”. “ They (the bill-holders) are in the position of a number of creditors of a common debtor, who is able to pay only a given amount.
They stand primarily equal in their right, but he who is bona fide preferred and paid, may receive payment without wrong to any body. And he who is vigilant and sues and gets judgment as in all other cases, acquires a preference under the law”.
The extent of a stockholder’s liability is a sum equal to the value of his stock, rating his stock as worth one hundred dollar's a share ; the manner by which the liability may be discharged, is by the stockholder’s taking up bills to an amount equal to the valxie of his stock, rating his stock as 'worth $100 a share, or by his coming under obligation, by judgment or otherwise, to take up bills to that amount. This is what the Counsel mean by their proposition, as I understand them.
And that proposition, in this sense, if I mistake not, was,
What is the meaning of these words ? It is, in my opinion, such as not only not to support, but such as to oppose the proposition ; and that in every important respect.
As I think these words do not mean to say, that in a valuation of the shares of stock for any purpose, the shares are to be considered worth the fixed sum of one hundred dollars each; regardless of whether as much as $ 100 a share has been paid the bank on them or not — or mean to say, that in all cases when the stockholder has taken up or become bound by judgment to take up bills, to an amount equal to the value of his stock, he is, as a matter of course, discharged from all liability to take up other outstanding bills — or mean to say, that the quantity of any stockholder’s property, liable to the ultimate redemption of bills, is to be a quantity equal to the value of his stock, let the value be rated as it may.
For thus thinking, I will now give my reasons; and then I will state what I think to be the true meaning of the words, and my reasons for so thinking.
First, then. Is the value of each share meant by these words, a fixed sum of ¡$100, or is it a sum equal to the sum which, may have been paid in on the share, or is it something else”?
How is this question to be determined ?
2. If the words fail to give a clear meaning, then and not till then, by an appeal to the “context”; that is, to Legislation in pari materia.
8. If the context fails to give a clear meaning, then and not till then, to the “subject matter”.
4. If this fails, then to the effects and consequences.
5. Or, to that which perhaps includes the effects and consequences — the “ spirit and reason” of the words.
Eor these answers to the question how ? I go no further than to Bladestone. (1 Black. Com. 60.)
Let us then appeal, first, to the zvords. ^The words are, “in proportion to the amount of shares and the value thereof”. There is nothing in these bare words, from which it' can be argued that the meaning is that the “value” is to be considered as of any fixed sum. These words certainly are plainly, not per se, equivalent to these, “in proportion to the amount of shares and the value thereof, rating the value thereof at $100 a ■share”.
The only meaning, as it seems to me, which is to be drawn from these words thus taken by themselves is this — in proportion to the amount of shares and the value thereof, rated at what the shares sell for in market. When men speak of the value of a horse, a piece of land, State stocks, stocks generally, they mean the value of each thing, estimated according to what it will fetch, when exposed to sale in open market.
When the Legislature and the stockholders in this bank used the word value, in connection with the stock of the bank, is it to be said that they used the word in a sense different from that in which all men use the word on similar occasions ? If it is, then, it must be, for some reason, outside of the mere words.
The meaning to be drawn from the naked words is, that the value of the stock is to be estimated at the market value.
What says the “ context”- ? Does the context say the value of the shares is to be estimated at $100 each share ? The second section of the charter declares that “ The stock of the
It seems to me plain that the declaration in this second section, means that a subscription of a million of dollars in stock, is not to be considered of the value of $1,000,000, until a $1,000,000 have been paid upon it. The declaration seems to mo plainly to mean, that a subscription of a million of dollars is to be considered of no value whatever, until 25 per cent, of it has been paid; and that after that per cent, has been paid, it is to be considered, as to all banking purposes, of no more value than the value of that per cent, thus paid upon it.
The directors have power to call for payment of the remainder of the subscriptions ? True, but this being a power to be used at the will of the directors, and the directors being the creatures of the stockholders, payment may neyer be called
Thus far, then, there is nothing in the “context” to affect the meaning which we had got from the “words”, viz: that the value of the shares is to be taken to be what is their market value.
There is other legislation in pari materia, as the Tax Act of 1817.
This act declares that “ there shall be annually paid to the State, a tax of thirty-one and a quarter cents on every hundred dollar’s value of bank stock operated upon or employed within this State, which tax shall be assessed and collected in the manner following, viz : It shall be the duty of the, president and directors of every bank incorporated by the Legislature of this State, to cause the cashier thereof to transmit to the Treasurer of the State, annually, a return sworn to by him before some Justice of the Inferior Court or of the Peace, in which shall be stated the amount of capital stock annually paid in on the first day of January preceding the time of making such return, and on or before the first day of December in each year, cause to be paid into the Treasury, free of any cost or deduction whatever, the said sum of thirty one and a quarter cents on every hundred dollars of capital stock returned in manner aforesaid.” This Act was made to extend to banks established as well after as before its passage. (Pr. Dig. 859.)
The principle of stock valuation contained in this Act, is recognized, and more vigorously applied in the Act of 1845, “ to compel the banks of this State to pay a tax on the highest amount of bank stock” thereafter “ returned by them as subject to taxation.” (Cobb Dig. 1077.)
This principle is the one which, by other tax Acts, is used
The taxation of the stock of the Central Rail-roacl and the Georgia Rail-road, is regulated by the respective charters of those corporations. By those charters, the tax has to be one on net income.
The Act of 1817 was in operation at the time when the Act incorporating the Planter’s and Mechanic’s Bank was passed. By the terms of the Act extending it to banks to be established after the date of it, the Act applies to that bank. For one great purpose, that of taxation, the Act absolutely prescribes what shall be considered to be the value of the stock of the bank ; and that is, “ the amount of the capital stock actually paid in.” This it is, that is to be considered the value of the stock, for the great purpose of the taxation of the stock.
Other acts prescribe a similar rule of valuation for stock, in the casé of corporations of other kinds — of the great internal improvement kinds.
From all this, is it not to be inferred that the Legislature considered the general principle for assessing the value of all corporation stocks, in cases in which they were to be assessed at all, to be the amount of money actually paid in on the stocks ? I think it is. When the Legislature has fixed the value of a thing at so and so, for one great and general purpose, and afterward, in connection with another not very dissimilar purpose, speaks of the value of the thing, in my opinion, it has in mind that same value which it had before fixed, for the thing.
But, at least, did not the stockholders, when they accepted the charter, have ground from this Act, for insisting that they accepted it in the sense that the value of their stock was to be rated ; no higher, in estimating their liability to pay the debts
The result, then, of the appeal to these Statutes in pari materia is, that the meaning of the Words “value thereof” aforesaid, in the charter, is not the market value of the shares, as the words naturally import, but a value equal to the amount of money actually paid in on the shares.
It may, however, be said, that as a general thing, this value and the market value will not greatly differ.
This result is one not to be affected by any thing, of which I am aware, in the “subject-matter” — the “spirit and reason” of the charter, or “ in effects and consequences”.
But say that I am wrong in this conclusion, and that in finding the liability of the stockholder, the stock is to be estimated as of the value of §100 a share; then I cannot agree with the majority of the Court, that this liability is one which may be discharged by the stockholder’s taking up bills to an amount .equal to the amount of his stock, or by his becoming bound, , by judgment, to take up bills to that amount, wholly regardless of the question, whether or not there may not be other outstanding bills, wishing to be taken up. ■
Supposing now, for argument’s sake, that the true mode for finding the amount of a stockholder’s property, which is liable for the ultimate redemption of the bills of the bank, is to measure the value of his stock and to take an amount of his property equal to that value, then I say that in my opinion, this amount of property, whatever it may be when found, is to be divided out among all the bills needing “ultimate” redemption, and giving notice of their existence to the stockholder; and that if he, after getting such notice, applies the whole amount of the property to the payment of some of the bills to the exclusion of the others, he does not, thereby, become discharged from those others.
In such a case, (assuming that the charter, itself, fixes no ratio of distribution,) I think that the law requires the fund or
This opinion is founded upon the words of the charter, and upon a vast body of law in pari materia.
The words of the charter that I rely upon, are these: “ the persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and held bound” “for the ultimate redemption of the bills or notes issued by said bank”. I understand by the words, “ the bills or notes”, all the bills or notes. If I am right, then, by the words of the charter, the property of the stockholder is pledged and bound to the ultimate redemption of each and every bill issued by the bank. Every bill or note, therefore, has a right to a share in this property. How, tíren, can the stockholder justify himself for taking the whole property, thus belonging, in shares, to all, and giving it to one ? or which is the same thing, justify liimself for letting so large a judgment go against him, in favor of one bill-holder, as shall force from him all the property thus belonging, equally, to the other bill-holders ?
But if the charter were silent, the vast quantity of law in pari materia, speaks a language that leaves me, as I think, no alternative but to adopt the opinion which I have above expressed. In every case in the law, which I can think of, in which a fund is to be distributed among different claimants upon it, the rule of distribution is the pro rata rule — the rule which gives to each claimant a share — a share proportioned to the amount of his claim.
This, by Statute, is the rule in the distribution among creditors, of the assets of a dead man; this, by Statute, is the rule by which a debtor’s property is to be divided .among his judgment creditors, whose judgments are of equal date; this, by Statute, is the rule by which the money of a debtor, in the hands of Sheriffs, &c. is to be divided among the debtor’s judgment creditors, whose judgments are of the same dater
The idea, then, that a stockholder may, as to his individual property, liable to the ultimate redemption of the bills of the bank, prefer one bill-holder to another, as long as the fund lasts, is, it seems to me, condemned by the words of the charter, and by a vast body of law in context with the charter — by all the law that exists on kindred subjects. And here I might stop, for when the answer which the “words” and the “context” give is free from doubt, we are not at liberty to go fur
But I will add a word as to the “ effect” of the rule, that would allow the stockholder a chance to prefer one bill-holder to another. When a bank suspends specie payments, its bills fall at once below par, and this, no odds what may be the amount of its ultimately available assets. If there is distrust of these, the fall is great in proportion to the distrust. The existence of an ultimate liability on the part of the stockholders to redeem the bills, presents but a slight resistance to the downward tendency of the value of the bills. This experience has proved. Now, this rule gives the stockholder the full benefit of the depreciation, whatever it may be, and therefore the rule makes it to his interest that the bills should depreciate as much as possible. All he has to do is, to buy up bills to an amount equal to the value of his stock, and be discharged. He will not be fool enough to wait for judgments to be obtained against him on bills for the full amount of the bills. Before the time has come for such judgments to be rendered, he will have voluntarily redeemed bills to an amount equal to the amount of his stock, i. e. will have bought them up at the lowest price at which they may be selling in the market, and having done that, all else he will have to do will be to plead them to such suits as may be pending against him on other bills — and what means and facilities have stockholders for aggravating the depreciation of the bills of their bank, as by misrepresenting the condition of the bank ; by misrepresenting the condition of the individual stockholders; by misrepresenting the quantity of bills to be redeemed; by misrepresenting the quantity that each stockholder has already redeemed; by misrepresenting the market price of the bills; by threatening all sorts of defences to suits upon the bills, and so forth and so forth. Admit that bank stockholdeis may be as honest as other men, yet why tempt the most honest men in this way ? Why, indeed, give them the benefit of that depreciation, which at best, is inevitable on bank suspension? Would not the rule be far better if it were such as that is which is applied to executors and adminis
I am aware that a decision of this Court was quoted in support of what I am now combatting, that made in Bothwell and others vs. Sheffield and others, (8 Ga. R. 569.) That case was one in which the sureties of a Sheriff asked for an injunction to restrain a number of suits, which had been brought against them on their bond, suggesting that the amount of the demands in the suits exceeded the amount of the bond, and praying that “ the Court would so direct the recoveries, that the creditors first entitled, should recover to the amount of their bond; and the remainder be restrained from prosecuting their suits against the sureties”, and in which the Superior Court, on demurrer, dismissed the bill “ on the ground that complainants had a complete Common Law remedy” — a decision which was affirmed by this Court. This is the whole case. The opinion is contained in eight lines, and is put exclusively upon a Statute at that — an Act of 1847. (Pamph. 201.)
This judgment was, I think, right, even without any Statute to give it special support. Those sureties, as far as I can see, had no more nee'd of the aid of a Court of Equity to protect them from the overplus of suits, than has an executor or administrator the need of the aid of such Court to protect him from ■an overplus of suits against him, i. e. from suits on demands’ which exceed the value of the assets. The executor or administrator, may, at law, plead the state of the assets and of the debts relatively to each other, and at law the plea will be to him an ample protection. I see no reason why the sureties on a Sheriff’s bond may not do a similar thing. Hence, I think the judgment in the case was right. If the opinion of the Court has in it more than this, the excess is but an obiter dictum. I doubt, however, whether it has more.
First, as to what the “ words” say. The words are, “ The persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and held bound” “for the ultimate redemption of the bills or notes issued by said bank.” By the expression “bills or notes issued”, I understand is meant all the bills or notes lawfully issued. If I am right in this, then the positive command of the words is, that the property of the stockholders shall be bound for the ultimate redemption of all the bills issued by the bank. Now, if the property is to bo bound for the ultimate redemption of all the bills, of course enough of it is to be bound so to redeem all. That is to say, an amount of property is to be bound equal to the amount of bills in circulation needing ultimate redemption. The amount of such bills may, it is true, happen to be just equal to the value of the stock, though the chances are many against it. The amount will almost always be either greater or less than the value of the stock. For, by another part of the charter, the bank may issue bills to any amount, which shall not exceed “ three times the amount of their capital stock actually paid in, over and above the amount of specie actually deposited in the vaults for safe-keeping.” Supposing all the capital stock of the bank paid in, viz: $1,000,000, and that the bank had on actual deposit another $1,000,000 in specie — then it might issue bills to the amount of $4,000,000 — that is to say, to an amount exceeding by $3,000,000 the value of its capital stock, rated at $100 a share. But if, in such case, the bank should issue $4,000,000 in bills, the amount of individual
Again, the “ words” say that “ the persons and property” shall be bound “in proportion to the amount of shares and the value thereof.” This rule, for ascertaining the amount of property liable, entirely rejects the words, “the amount of the shares” and confines itself exclusively to the words “the value thereof.” But the two sets of words are not synonymous. The first set means the number of the shares, irrespective of their value. And.the quantity of individual property liable, is to be got by a proportion in which one of the terms is made up, in some way, both of the number of the shares and the value of the shares. This principle absolutely rejects from the case the element or ingredient, the number of the shares, although the words put that clement as much in the case as they do the element, the value of the shares. And, indeed, upon the principle that it is the value of the shares which is to be the measure of the quantity of individual property liable, it seems to me impossible to do anything else than reject the words, “the amount of the shares.” Yet these words have a plain meaning. The language of the charter is amount of shares as well' as value of shares: — the language of this principle is value of shares only. So much for the condemnation of the principle that comes from the “words” of the charter.
The condemnation from the context is, I think, if possible, more decided. I have examined, I believe, all of the corporation charters which contain provisions similar to that contained in this eleventh section of the charter of this bank. Most of those charters are for banks, but some are for rail-roads, some for insurance, and some, perhaps, for other purposes. There are thirty or more of them; and as to the times of their creation, they
In this charter, the expression, it will be remembered, is “ the amount of shares and the value thereof.”
Now, what I have to say is, that the principle that the amount of the property of the individual stockholders is to be found by finding the amount of the value of their stock, will not work through all of these charters. It will not work in those in which the expression is, “the amount of the shares”, or “the number of dollars issued on each share”, or “amount of the stock”, or “ amount equal to the proportion of stock”,
The defect of the rule, in this respect, may be well illustrated by the case of the clause in the charter of the Bank of Columbus. By the clause in that charter, the common stockholders are to be liable in proportion to “ the amount of their shares”; the other stockholder, the State, in proportion “ to the amount of the value of the shares”. The amount or number of the shares of the State and the other stockholders, respectively, may be, say 100, the value $10,000. This principle will tell you that the State is liable for $10,000, but it can not tell you what the other stockholders are liable for. And yet, can there be a doubt of its having been the intention of the Legislature, that in such a case, the State and the other stockholders were, respectively, to be liable for precisely the same sum ?
This defect in the principle may still more clearly be shown, by a reference to those charters in which the words are, “in proportion to the number of dollars issued on each share”. In these charters, it is manifest that the principle utterly fails to give any solution. •
Now I think it was the intention of the Legislature, that in the case of each of these charters, the extent of individual liability of the stockholders, was to be ascertained in precisely the same way — by precisely the same rule. The principle of the majority of the Court cannot be true, if the intention were this.
So much for the present, as to what the context says.
As to the “ effects and consequences” of this principle, if it is allowed to be the true one, they have already been slightly adverted to, when it was said that for the ultimate redemption
And in connection with this topic I may ask, what was the “reason and spirit” which actuated the Legislature in putting provisions of this kind into bank charters ? Was it not to get the bills of the banks paid — if possible, paid by the banks themselves ; if not possible, by the banks, then by the stockholders ; at all events, to get the bills paid ? If this was the spirit and reason — if this was the end, and if this end was to be accomplished by first subjecting the property of the bank to the payment of the hills, and when that gave out, then by subjecting the property of the individual stockholders to their payment, is it to be presumed that the Legislature would subject, of that individual property, either more than enough to accomplish the object, or less than enough, or not rather just enough ? It is not to be presumed, therefore, that the amount of the individual property of the stockholders, which the Legislature intended so to subject, was an amount equal to the value of their shares, for this value, would in more, probably, than nine hundred and ninety-nine cases out of a thousand, be an amount which would be either greater or less than the amount of the bills to be redeemed by it.
These are my objections to the rule which the majority of the Court deduce from this eleventh section of this charter.
I will now state what I conceive to be the true rule to be deduced from that section, and why I so do.
I think the following propositions are true:
1. The quantity of property of all the stockholders which, is liable for the ultimate redemption of the bills of the bank, is a quantity just equal to the quantity of bills to be so redeemed.
2. This quantity of property is to consist of separate parcels, a parcel to be supplied by each stockholder.
3. Of these parcels, the quantity of any one is to be such
4. Of the -aggregate quantity of these parcels, such a portion is to be advanced by all the stockholders, at any one time, as shall be sufficient to satisfy the demand upon that aggregate quantity, existing at that time; that is, as shall be sufficient to pay off the bank bill or bills, which may, at that time, be demanding ultimate payment.
5. Of this portion, thus to be advanced by all the stockholders, at any one time, the part to be advanced by any one stockholder, is to be such that it shall bear to the whole portion to be advanced by all, the same ratio which the parcel of that stockholder bears to the aggregate of the parcels .of all the stockholders.
6. And as this parcel bears to the aggregate of all the parcels the same proportion — the same proportion which the quantity of stock belonging to the stockholder owning the parcel,„ bears to the aggregate quantity of all the stock; therefore,
v 7. The part to be advanced at any one timo, by any one stockholder, is to be such that it shall bear to the part then to be advanced by allj i. e. to the amount of the bill cr bills then to be''paid, the same proportion which the stock of that stockholder bears to thb'l^tíale stock.
This result is the:.same, in effect, as that to which the Court below arrived: which was, that the bill-holder, in this case, had the right to recover of this stockholder, such a proportion or per cent, qf;his bills, as the stock owned by the stockholder-bore to the whole stock. It is the same, in effect, as that to which this bill-holder, himself, and his Counsel, Mr. Dougherty, first arrived. The suit in this case was originally framed so as to demand no more of the stockholder than what he would, according to this result, have to pay. And the declaration remained in this form for years, I believe. Recently, it was amended so as-to make it .conform to the rulo considered by
Nevertheless, I will biiefly state some of the particular reasons, apart from this, of contemporaneous construction, which make me think the propositions true, on which this conclusion of mine depends.
1. The language of the charter is, that “the persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and held bound”' “ for the ultimate redemption of the bills or notes issued by said bank”, &e. By the words, “bills or notes issued”, I take for granted is meant all of the bills or notes lawfully issued. If so, then, the amount of the language is, that as much of' the property of the stockholders as shall be sufficient for the-ultimate redemption of all the bills thus issued, shall be bound for the ultimate redemption of all such bills. The language does not say that more than as much as this shall be bound; and as there can be no other x-eason than a positive command-' of law, why more should be bound, I say no more is bound.. Hence, I think my first proposition is true ; and that is the leading one. If it is true, the rule laid down by this Court cannot be true.
2. That the quantity of property so bound, is to consist of parcels of some sort, to be supplied by each stockholder, I be
3. The language of the charter is, that “the persons and property of the stockholders shall be pledged and held bound, in proportion to the. amount of shares and the value thereof, that each individual or company may hold in said bank”.
Taking my first and second propositions to be true, this language may be so varied as to read thus: “ The persons of all the stockholders, and so much of their property as shall be sufficient for the ultimate redemption of all the bills of the bank, shall be bound for that ultimate redemption, such property to consist of parcels; — such parcels to be supplied by each stockholder, in proportion to the amount of his shares and the value thereof.”
My third proposition, is that of the parcels of property to be supplied by each stockholder; the.quantity of any one parcel is to 'be such that the parcel shall bear to all the parcels taken in the aggregate, i. e. to the whole quantity of property to be supplied by all the stockholders, the same proportion which the quantity of stock belonging to the stockholder who is to supply that parcel, bears to the aggregate quantity of the stock belonging to all the stockholders. This proposition, I think I may safely say, is entirely consistent with the words of the section. It does not the least violence to any of those words. It .rejects none.
May I not go further, and safely say that this proposition expresses the natural and obvious meaning of the words ? Of the words, “in proportion to” what is the natural and obvious sense ? Is it not one which implies the existence of some proportion ? And is it not the essential characteristic of every proportion to consist of four things, of which the first shall bear to the second, the same relation which the third bears to the fourth? This is the foundation of the “Rule of Three,” the great rule in practical arithmetic. To make the words, “ in proportion to,” equivalent to the words, “equal to,” is, as it seems to me, to subject the words to some degree of violence.
And if any proportion is implied, the one which is it, there
And then this proportion works just as you would have it work. It always brings out the right result — the exact one which you seek for. There are, say, bills calling for ultimate redemption, to the extent of $10,000. Of course, to redeem them, property to the value of $10,000 is to be supplied by all the stockholders, taken in the lump. This term you know.
The amount of the stock of all — the amount of the stock of each — these terms you also know. The term which you wish to know is, what is the particular amount of this property, which each stockholder is 'to supply ? From the three known quantities, how easy it is to come to know that. As the amount of the shares and the value thereof belonging to all the stockholders, is to the amount and value of the shares belonging to all, so is the amount of property to be supplied by all, to the amount to be supplied by one.
And this same result, the proportion works out, in whatever sense you take the words, “ the amount of the shares and the value thereof” — whether you consider the proportion to be one, “to the amount (number) of the shares” and to “the value of the shares” amount and value taken separately, but both taken; or one to the amount of the shares added to the value of the shares; or one to the amount of the shares multiplied into the value of the shares. And it will make no difference whether you estimate the value of the shares to be $100 — $50—$10 —$1—each. The fourth term in each of the following proportions will be precisely the same quantity. As the amount and value, at any rate, of the whole stock is to the amount and value, at the same rate of the stock of A, so is the quantity of property to be supplied by all the stockholders to the quantity to bo supplied by A. As the amount of the whole stock is to the amount of the stock of A, so is the whole quantity of pro
Using this proportion, therefore, you may use all the words of the section, and not have to reject any, as you have to do when you say the quantity of property to be contributed by any stockholder, is to be a quantity equal to the value of His shares; in which case, you have to reject the words, “ amount of the shares and”.
This proportion, not only thus unlocks this provision of this charter — it equally unlocks the similar provisions of all the other thirty charters in existence. Take the provision in some of those charters, which is most unlike the provision in this, viz that in which the quantity of property to be supplied by any stockholder, is to be “in proportion to the number of dollars issued upon each of the shares” held by him, and see. With such a provision as this, the rule of the majority cannot deal at all.
According to the words of this provision, the proportion will have to be as the number of dollars issued on each of the shares belonging to all tho stockholders, is to the number issued on each share belonging to stockholder A, so is the quantity of property to be supplied by all the stockholders to tho quantity to be supplied by A. But this proportion is precisely the same as this: as the quantity of stock of all the stockholders is to the quantity of the stock of A, so is the quantity of property to be supplied by all to the quantity to be supplied by A; for the number of dollars issued upon each of all the shares is to all the shares as the number issued upon each of A’s shares is to all of A’s shares.
This third proposition, then, in connection with the first and second, unlocks all of these provisions in the thirty-one charters, and shows the inside of each provision to present precisely tho same face — a face of which the leading feature is, that the •quantity of property to be furnished by the whole lot of stockholders, is to bo a quantity just sufficient to redeem all the
Is not this third proposition then true ? I think it is.
The other propositions, the fourth, fifth, sixth and seventh, follow from these three.
The whole amount of property to be advanced by all of the stockholders at any one time, is obviously to be no more than shall be needed at that time; no more than shall be sufficient to redeem the bill or bills then demanding payment. Admit that there may be other bills outstanding, yet they may never be presented for payment, and so may never require any property to be advanced on their account. And if presented afterwards, they will, equally with those presented then, be within the rule and -be entitled to call for an advance from the stockholders, sufficient for the payment of them.
And so it is equally obvious that of this whole amount, thus to be advanced by all the stockholders at any one time, the part to be advanced by any one stockholder, at that time, is to be to the -whole so to be advanced by all, as his stock is to the stock of all. He is to pay his part of every bill, as it comes forward for payment, and the other stockholders are to pay theirs. Thus the whole bill will be paid — thus all the bills to be paid will be paid. And this is the end the Legislature had in view.
Will this interpretation of the charter work badly in practice ? I think not — but if it did, it being the one which to my mind so clearly results from the words' and the context of the charter, I should, myself, have to stick to it. When the words and the context say one thing, and effects and consequences, (the understanding of “learned” Courts, or indeed aught else) say another, a Judge has to go by what the words and the context say. Hence, although a few decisions of other States wore cited in the argument of this case, I have laid them entirely aside, as improper to influence my opinion. Upon a
But the practical effect of this interpretation will not be bad —it will be good. The rule it supplies will work easily, and will finish its work as it goes. Is there a bill to be redeemed ? Let it present itself to any stockholder and say, “ sir as the quantity of your stock is to the quantity of all the stock, so is-what you have to pay me on this bill to what the other stockholders have to pay me — therefore, pay it to me.” In a minute, the proportional quantity is found, and the stockholder has nothing to do but to pay it. Does he refuse ? if so, on what ground ? that he does not like the rule — does not understand the rule ? Such do not appear to have been the objections in this case. The stockholder, in this case, understood the rule — it was the one he insisted upon. But suppose the stockholder puts his objection to paying, on other grounds, as for example, that there is nothing due by reason of the bills being void, (say) because issued without authority, or extinguished, or barred by the Statute of Limitations, is his refusal to pay to be set down as evidence that this rule works badly ?
Let there be no obstacle to payment but this rule itself, and payment will go on as fast as it does in any case where payment has to be got out of different debtors. In every such case, it is necessary that creditor and debtor shall have a meeting — . that the debt to be paid shall be presented for payment. So the bill-holder will, in like manner, have to be at the trouble to, go round to the stockholders and present his bill to each. And each will be, at least, as likely to pay as any other debtors are— for the costs of suit would become a terrible penalty to such as might refuse to pay.
And then, payment thus made to the bill-holder, would, at one blow, settle all rights. The bill-holder will have got only
Again : this interpretation of mine makes the security for the ultimate redemption of the bills of the bank, expand and contract with the bills to be secured. No odds how much these bills may exceed the amount or value of the stock, so they be bills lawfully issued, this interpretation makes the security extend to every bill. For the ultimate redemption of every such bill, it makes the property of the stockholders liable. The rule
This interpretation presents no opportunities to the stockholder, to prefer one bill-holder to another — gives him no chance to discharge his liability, by taking up bills at their depreciated value — offers him no temptation, therefore, to use means to depreciate the value of the ■ bills; in all which respects, also, it is in contrast with the rule of the majority of the Court.
And these are my reasons for thinking this interpretation to be the true one.
I had, therefore, to agree with the Court below, and to disagree with this Court.