3 Chand. 133 | Wis. | 1851
The plaintiff below, Larhin, declared in covenant for the rents reserved in a lease executed by him to Kellogg & Webb, of one portion of a certain warehouse, situated in the fifth ward of the city of Milwaukee. The lease contained a covenant on the part of the plaintiff by which he obliged himself, during the term for which the premises were demised, to wit: from the 7th of January to the 1st day of August following, “ not to purchase, store, or handle any wheat in the Milwaukee market, except under the direction ” of the defendants.
This covenant, as is said, being in partial restraint of trade, is prima facie bad, and should be aided by an averment of some special circumstances, showing a good reason, independent of a mere-pecuniary consideration, to support it.- And the want of. any such averment, it is further said, is a substantial defect in, the declaration which entitles the defendants to judgment upon the demurrer, notwithstanding the insufficiency of their plea.
I have found no case in which these circumstances or reasons have been expressly averred, although it is suggested that they might be set out by averment when they did not appear upon the face of the contract. Ross v. Sadgbeer, 21 Wend., 166.
The declaration is therefore sufficient in substance, to support the judgment of the county court. Let us consider if the plea demurred to discloses a good answer to that declaration.
This plea, in its character, is quite original. I think it would be difficult to say what precedent gave form to it. But in its structure it is ingenions; I think it would be quite as difficult to say what canon of good pleading was violated by it. But I have to consider, not its form, but its body in substance.
Its material averments, I think, may be stated as follows :
1. That the lease declared upon “ was made, entered into and executed for the further countenancing and proceeding in the undertakings, schemes and plans of the produce association,” of which the parties to the lease were severally members.
2. That the produce association was composed of the proprietors of certain warehouses, to the number of eleven, and the owners of certain mills in the city of Milwaukee.
3. That the produce association, on the 29th day of December, 1849, entered into an agreement by which the mill owners vwere parties of the first part, and the warehousemen were par
First. The mill owners agree to pay the warehousemen “four cents per bushel commission, or storage, on each and every bushel of wheat coming to the Milwaukee market to be disposed of, by sale in the street, or by storage, (so far as they are able to control the same,”) from that date to the 1st day of August, then next.
. Second. The warehousemen, in consideration thereof, agree “ to give to the parties of the first part, full, absolute and uninterrupted control of the Milwaukee wheat market, from the date hereof, up to the first day of August, A. D. 1850, so far as they shall be able to do so by virtue of their capacity as warehousemen or vessel and dock owners ; that they will not themselves, or through the agency of others, directly or indirectly, under any name or pretense whatsoever, purchase, contract or bargain for any wheat in the Milwaukee market, from the date hereof, up to the 1st day of August, A. D. 1850, nor make any contracts for the storage of wheat during the time aforesaid, except as agents under the direction and control of the parties of the first part.”
Third. That nothing herein contained is to give the said parties of the first part, any right to close the warehouses against the storage of wheat, or to fix a higher rate of storage than four cents per bushel.
Fourth. That “ the parties of the second part shall at all times hold themselves in readiness to purchase, store and deliver, or ship wheat for account of the parties of the first part, at the rate of four cents per bushel, as aforesaid,” and,
Fifth. That the mill owners shall pay to the warehouse-men four cents per bushel upon all wheat received into the mills for shipment or grinding, “grist work excepted.”
4. It is averred that the objects and purposes of the association were to carry out and perform these agreed plans and schemes.
Upon this last averment a point was raised upon the argument, which, as it seems preliminary to the main question, I will here dispose of.
It was said that because it is expressly averred that the “ association, its agreed plans, schemes,” etc., “ tended to the manifest injury and restraint of trade,” etc., and because the truth of this averment is admitted by the demurrer, and because whatever contracts do have such tendency, are held to be void as contravening public policy, therefore the judgment of the county court should have been for the defendants.
The answer to this objection is manifest. Undoubtedly a demurrer admits the verity of every fact well pleaded; but I have to say, that if the “ agreed plans and schemes ” which are alleged to have such pernicious tendency are any other than those that are developed in the articles of the 29th of December, 1849, then they are not well pleaded, and for these two reasons:
1. Because (as I think) they should be set forth in terms; not by describing their symptoms or effects, but stating their essence and nature, leaving the court to judge of their tendencies and probable effects; and
2. Because, in such case, this averment would be clearly repugnant to that other averment, to wit: that the “ objects and purposes of which association were to carry out and perform all' the acts, plans and schemes contemplated and agreed upon in the said article of agreement.”
But doubtless the pleader referred to the articles themselves, which he sets forth in extenso, as developing the plans and schemes alleged to be so injurious to the public interests. The agreement is therefore laid before the court for construction—
Whether such an agreement existed — whether the lease sued upon grew out of it, or was connected therewith so as to be tainted by it, if taint was in it, were questions which, if raised, must be settled by a jury. But what the agreement essentially was, and whether it violated any law of the land or any rule of public policy, were purely questions of law, to be determined by the court. Therefore no averment could give to the agreement a character which it had not, and no admission could take from it the character which it had.
Millan v. May, 11 Mees & W., 652, was an action upon a covenant not to carry on the business of a surgeon dentist in London, or in any of the places or towns in England or Scotland, where the plaintiffs might have been practising within four years, for which term the agreement ran. Plea to the second breach assigned that the plaintiffs, before the expiration of the term, had practiced in many towns in England, and that divers of them were distant from each other one hundred and fifty miles; wherefore the said stipulation was an unreasonable restriction of trade. Upon demurrer, the plea was held bad for attempting to put in issue a matter of law.
The county court, then, we think, properly assumed the responsibility of passing upon the nature and effect of the agreement, and I come now to consider the gravest question presented upon this record, to wit: whether that court erred in its estimate of the character of that agreement.
The plaintiffs in error aver that this agreement' “ tended to the manifest injury and restraint of .trade, the depression of the wheat market, to reduce the price of the commodity of wheat, and to stifle fair and lawful rivalry and competition of dealers therein,” and this view was enforced by an argument of great length, and exhibiting much ingenuity and research.
Before proceeding to discuss the question whether this agreement does in fact contravene public policy, I desire to refer to
And I desire to add that as a general rule, the immediate representatives of the people, in legislature assembled, would seem to be the fairest exponents of what public policy requires, as being most familiar with the habits and fashions of the day, and with the actual condition of commerce and trade, their consequent wants and weaknesses. And a legislative enactment would seem to be the least objectionable form of exposition, for these two reasons:
1. Because it would operate prospectively as a guide to future negotiations, and would not, like a judgment of a court, annul a contract already concluded in good faith, and upon a valuable consideration; and
2. Because a rule so established has a wider circulation among the people, and enters more generally into the information of the public.
I by no means intend to deny the right or the propriety of judicially determining, that a contract which Vs actually at war with any established interest of society is void, however individuals may suffer thereby, because the interest of individuals must be subservient to the public welfare. But I insist that before a court should determine a contract which has been made in good faith stipulating for nothing that is malum in se, nothing that is made malum prohibitum, to be void as contravening the policy of the state, it should be satisfied that the advantage
And having ventured upon these few preliminary reflections I disclaim all aid from any one of them in the determination of this cause, .but I affirm, that, upon the spirit of the letter of the law, as it has been adjudicated for one hundred and forty years, the agreement disclosed in the plea of the plaintiff in error is not against public policy.
Contracts against public policy are divided, by Me. Stout, into seven classes, as follows: 1. Contracts in restraint of trade ; 2. Contracts in restraint of marriage ; 3. Marriage brokerage contracts; 4. Wagers and gaming ; 5. Contracts to offend against the laws and public duty ; 6. Usury, and 7. Trading with an enemy.
This agreement clearly does not fall under either of the six heads last above mentioned. If objectionable at all, then it must be as a contract in- restraint of trade. In that light alone it was considered by the counsel for the plaintiffs in error upon the agreement.
But contracts in restraint of trade are divided by Parker, J. in Mitchell v. Reynolds, 1 P. Wms., 181, into involuntary and voluntary, the former comprising restraints arising from either: 1. Grants or charters from the crown; 2. Customs, or 3. Bylaws, and the latter comprising those restraints which arise from the agreement of parties.
When I have said then, that the agreement we are considering, most certainly does not present a case of involuntary restraint, I think I have dispensed with the necessity of examining that large class of cases, cited by counsel upon the argument, and which arose upon royal grants and charters, customs or by-laws. These decisions rest upon reasons applicable
These latter cases are again distinguished as, 1st. General; or, 2d. Particular; as to places or persons, or time.
A general restraint which is defined to be “ an agreement not to carry on a certain business anywhere ” (Story on Conf. Laws, § 550) is against public policy, and is void. So it was held after several arguments in Mitchell v. Reynolds, supra, and the doctrine has been affirmed and reaffirmed in numerous cases since, and I am not aware of the propriety of the rule being questioned in any single case. Parker, J., in Mitchell v. Reynolds, states the reasons upon which the rule is founded, as follows:
"First. The mischief which may arise from them. 1. To the party by the loss of his livelihood,.and the subsistence of his family. 2. To the public by depriving -it of a useful member. Another reason is the great abuses these voluntary restraints are liable to, as for instance, from corporations who were perpetually laboring for exclusive advantages in trade, and to reduce it into as few hands as possible; -as likewise from masters who are apt to give their apprentices much vexation on this account, and to use many indirect practices to procure such bonds from them, lest they should prejudice them in their custom when they come to set up for themselves. 3. Because in a great many instances they can be of no use to the obligee, which holds in all cases of general restraint throughout England, for what does it signify to a tradesman in London, what another does at Newcastle? And surely it would be unreasonable to fix a certain loss on one side, without any benefit to the other.”
I do not notice here the 4th and 5th reasons assigned, because the 4th is declared by the learned judge to be in favor of the contract, and so opposed to the rule, and the 5th applies to contracts with a consideration, which he evidently supposes to be without the rule, and which he says the law is not so un
Now, in applying the rule to any given case, it is important that we attend to the reasons upon which it is founded. “ Whoso knoweth not the reason of the law, knoweth not the law.”
And in regard to the reasons above stated, I have to say that I very much question whether, here in Wisconsin at the present time, and in view of our present social and political position, more than one of them is entitled to an}1, considerable importance, in our consideration. The opportunities for employment are so abundant, and the demand for labor on all sides is so pressing and urgent and the supply so limited, that I much question, were we to consider the subject as res integra, if we should feel authorized to hold that a man had endangered his own livelihood and the subsistence of his family, by an agreement which merely excluded him from exercising the trade of a blacksmith or a shoemaker, leaving all the other departments of mechanical, agricultural and commercial industry open to him.
And while we have no privileged classes here, but little individual, and less associated capital, and while our resources are so imperfectly developed, while the avenues to enterprise are so multiplied, so tempting and so remunerative, giving to labor the greatest freedom for competition with capital, perhaps, that it has yet enjoyed, I question if we have ■ much to fear from attempts to secure exclusive advantages in trade, or to reduce it to few hands.
While so much more remains to be done than all hands can do, I question if the better way to foster individual effort be not to secure it the greatest possible freedom, either to direct it to any particular calling, or to abandon that calling to another for an equivalent.
And while apprentices are sought for oftener than they seek apprenticeships, we need hardly fear, I think, that they will be
As to the third reason, I apprehend it would be thought a dangerous precedent were a court to annul any other voluntary bond for which a voluntary consideration has been received, upon the ground that it was of no use to the obligee. Ordinarily, we say, let parties who are competent to contract determine for themselves what contracts will profit them. And certainly I do not understand why that should be called a certain loss on one side when, for what the party has abandoned, he has received an ample equivalent. If the loss is supposed to arise from a total want of consideration, or from its inadequacy, these are distinct grounds for interference.
It is enough, however, that one good reason still remains to uphold the rule. The loss to society of a valuable member is as great a public injury now as it ever was, and as great here as anywhere. I hope, indeed, that the market value of a human being is higher now than it was in England at the beginning of the eighteenth century, when the case of Mitchell v. Reynolds was decided. The capacity of an individual to produce (using that word in its largest sense) constitutes his value to the public. That branch of industry in which a man has been educated, and to which he is accustomed, and for the abandon7 ment of which he demands compensation, is supposed to be the one in which he can render the greatest profit. The value of what he produces belongs to himself. The actual product belongs immediately to him who employs him, but mediately to the state, and goes to swell the aggregate of public wealth. Therefore, the law says to each and every tradesman: You
But none of these reasons apply to what are called partial or limited restraints, or to agreements not to exercise a particular calling in a particular place. Indeed these seem to be not so much restraints upon trade as upon tradesmen. Eor when a silversmith obligates himself not to pursue that particular business in Milwaukee, the trade need not necessarily be restrained thereby, for he can pursue if he pleases in Racine, or elsewhere in the state; and to all legal intendment with equal advantage to himself and to the public. Accordingly, such agreements have uniformly been upheld by the courts, when founded upon a sufficient consideration.
This modification of the rule is said to have obtained as early as 1621. Brand v. Joliffe, Cro. Jac., 596.
In Mitchell v. Reynolds, 1 P. Wms., 181, the law is declared so to be, and so to have been.
The cases which have been decided in accordance with this doctrine are numerous. I will only instance Bunn v. Gay, 4 East, 190; where an attorney bound himself not to practice within London and one hundred and fifty miles from thence. In Leighton v. Wales, 8 Mees & W., 545, the restraint was against running any coach on a particular road. Pierce v. Fuller, 8 Mass., 223; Palmer v. Stebbins, 3 Pick., 188; Pierce v. Woodward, 6 id., 201; Nodes v. Bates, 7 Cow., 307; Chappel v. Brockway, 21 Wend., 158; Perkins v. Lyman, 9 Mass., 532; which latter case arose upon an agreement not to be interested in any voyage to the northeast coast of America, or any traffic
Now it is manifest, that by every known rule of construction, the agreement exhibited to us in the defendant’s plea is one falling within the principle of the cases above cited. The restraint it imposed upon trade, if any, was partial and limited ; limited in every particular referred to in the books. It was limited as to persons, as to object, as to place, and as to time (though this last is not essential.) As to persons, it was limited to the proprietors of eleven warehouses; as to object, it was limited to the traffic in wheat; as to place, it was limited to the Milwaukee market; and as to time, to a period of about seven months.
It was indeed objected upon the argument that there was nothing upon the record to show the extent of the Milwaukee market. But surely this objection cannot be well taken. Admitting for the purpose of the argument, the law to be that only so much restraint upon the obligor will be upheld by the courts as shall appear to the court to be necessary to the protection of the obligee, still the agreement is before us, and if we are to construe it as á contract, and with reference only to the apparent intention of the parties, I think we would find no difficulty in holding that the contracting parties intended by that term to confine themselves to the market in Milwaukee, a city which we judicially know to exist, and the market or place of sale in which, I think we may legally infer, is not more extensive than the boundaries of the city.
If on the contrary we are to construe it as a part of the plea in the case, having reference to that degree of certainty requisite in good pleading, I have simply to remark, that whatever is uncertain in this behalf, is the fault of the plaintiffs in error, from whom the pleading comes; and because they have not . averred the Milwaukee market to have an unreasonable extent, we are to presume that it has not. 1 Ch. Pl., 345. In either
But the parties are said to have combined and agreed not to engage in trade, and that this was clearly against public policy ; and in the plea, the plaintiffs and defendants, together with divers other persons, are averred to have formed themselves and entered into an association. Let this matter be understood, and we need not bp frightened by the terms employed to characterize it. The agreement discloses no combination and no association in the sense in which the words are evidently used. It is of two parts. It creates mutual obligations, and provides mutual equivalents, as every contract, inter partes, does. But there is no identity of interest or of duty between the parties of the second part, no more than always exists between landlord and tenant. The warehousemen received their daily compensation, and the millers received their daily profits.
And there was no combination between the parties of the second part, the warehousemen. Perhaps they must be considered to have jointly promised the party of the first part, but it is not disclosed that they have promised each other, which I understand they must have done, before they can be said to have combined.
Besides, if the design be lawful, as the abandonment of'trade in a particular place is, what matter how many combine in it ? But at all events, it is said, that as creating a particular restraint, the contract is prima facie bad ; and the facts and circumstances which will justify it, if any such exist, should be made to appear.
And upon this point, the authority of Lord Macclesfield is again invoiced who says in Mitchell v. Reynolds that “ a particular restraint is not good, without just reason and consideration.” And again, — “In all restraints of trade, where nothing more appears, the law presumes them bad.” Special circumstances may exclude the presumption, and the court is to
What were those special circumstances in that very case ? Why, that the plaintiff was the assignee of a lease of a messuage and bakehouse in Liquor Pond street, in the parish of St. Andrews, Holborne, for the term of five years. This was held a sufficient reason to support a covenant not to exercise the trade of a baker within that parish during the said term.
What are the special circumstances in this case ? The ob-ligees are the proprietors of several mills in the city of Milwaukee, for the manufacture of wheat into flour. Will any one presume to say here is not as good a reason for upholding a promise not to traffic in wheat in Milwaukee, to the prejudice of these proprietors, for the term of seven months ?
But how should these special circumstances be made to appear ? By averment in the pleadings and by proof upon the trial ? Certainly not. It was not so in the case just cited. They appeared upon the face of the instrument sued upon, by way of preamble to the conditions, were set out on prayer of oyer, and the question arose upon demurrer to the declaration.
Here these circumstances appear in the agreement which is set out in the plea, and the question arises upon demurrer to the plea.
It is insisted further that the contract of the 29th December, 1849, discloses an attempt to create a monopoly of the wheat market. And in support of this position we are again referred to the leading case.
“ It may be useful,” says Parker, J., “ and lawful to restrain him from trading in some places, unless he intends a monopoly, which is a crime.”
But the word monopoly is used to signify something which is very different from aught that could have been intended by this contract. The learned judge himself interprets it in an-
Now could the parties possibly have intended by this simple contract, to vest in the mill owners the sole exercise of the traffic in wheat, throughout the state of Wisconsin ? If so, there was the most extraordinary disproportion of means to the end ever betrayed in the negotiations of business men. But they intended nothing of the kind. Not, even a monopoly of the market in Milwaukee. On the contrary, these mill owners who desired to purchase wheat for manufacturing, evidently sought to protect themselves against the competition (doubtless often sharp and injurious) of the warehousemen.
The obligors possessed large facilities as warehousemen, vessel and dock owners, for storing and freighting the produce which came to that market. Their interests led them to deal in that produce in the bulk, because so it would pay the most storage and the most freight. On the other hand, to give employment to their mills, the obligees sought the same produce for manufacture. Here their interests clashed. The contract before us is the result of a compromise of those conflicting interests. And if the argument needed any such beggarly support, I think it might well be asked if the public interests were not promoted, rather than prejudiced by an arrangement which saved to the wealth of our state, the earnings from the manufacture of so large a quantity of wheat as we may reasonably suppose to have been floured in' the Milwaukee mills, and which, but for this arrangement, would have been floured in the mills of some eastern state.
I waive this consideration. I say there was no monopoly intended, none effected. We cannot fail to perceive, that in spite of this contract, all the rest of Wisconsin was an open and unrestricted market for the sale of wheat. And even. in.
True, tbe language of the contract is, that tbe parties of the second part, “ agree to give the parties of the first part, full, solute and uninterrupted control of the Milwaukee wheat market; ” and had it stopped here it might well have been urged that there was an agreement for a monopoly of the trade in that market. And if that had been the only market for Wisconsin (which it is not), it might well be said tbe agreement was as pernicious as an agreement to strike the sun from the system. Either, if performed, would be ruinous to the farmers of Wisconsin; but I submit that the impossibility of performing, would constitute as good a reason for holding either of them void, as the injurious consequences certain to result from performance. But this stipulation is qualified by adding the words, “so far as they shall be able to do so,” and had they stopped here, to any objection that a monopoly was agreed upon, it might well be answered, that the giving of such control or such monopoly (if they are synonymous terms), of the Milwaukee wheat market-as those parties could give, was no monopoly at all. But the agreement is still further limited by the words, “ by virtue of “their capacity of warehousemen, vessel and dock owners.”
It is then simply an.agreement to give to the mill owners, such control of that market as they can give by virtue of those specified employments. In other and equivalent terms, it is a transfer of such control as the obligors possessed in right of their employment as warehousemen, etc. Such are the general terms selected by the draftsmen to express the complete abandonment of that trade in that market to the obligees.
Personally, the obligors were to do nothing to confirm the mill owners in that trade to the exclusion of anybody but themselves. Accordingly they go on to render the nature and meaning of the stipulation more definite, by specifying several things
It is unnecessary to examine the cases cited by counsel in support of the proposition I have here been combatting. They all arose upon royal grants or by-laws, and consequently were cases of involuntary restraints. They do establish the doctrine that the grant of a monopoly is void; but they do not support the averment of the plaintiff in error; that this contract disclosed a monopoly. Upon this point, better authority may be found in the language used by Bronson, J., in Chappell v. Brockway, 21 Wend., 157. To a similar averment, he replied: “ The defendant can gain nothing by giving the transaction a bad name, unless the facts of the case will bear him out. He calls this a monopoly. That is certainly a new kind of monopoly which only secures the plaintiff in the exclusive enjoyment of his business as against a single individual, while all the world beside are left at full liberty to enter upon the same enterprise.”
But the crowning objection urged against the validity of this agreement is, that it tends “ to depress the wheat market; to reduce the price of the commodity of wheat, and to stifle the fair and lawful rivalry.and competition therein.” It is quite observable that the word “ stifle ” is used more adroitly than aptly. But if its use is insisted upon, I admit that it does tend to stifle the competition of these obligors, and I assert that the right to stifle competition by contract, so far as it is injurious to the parties contracting has not before been denied or questioned for two hundred years, unless two cases reported in 4 Denio, 349, and 5 Denio, 434, are to be considered as denying the right. Nor can I perceive how this agreement can reduce the price of wheat, below its actual market value.
Wheat, being an article of almost universal consumption, has a market everywhere, and a valué in every market. And that value in any particular place is determined, less by the number of purchasers in that place, than by its distance from, and
Numerous cases were cited upon the argument in support of this last averment. Few of them, however, bear any analogy to the case before us. Most of those cases arose upon secret agreements not to bid at auction sales, or upon the employment of secret bidders. All such secret arrangements are very properly discountenanced by the courts, and forbidden by the law. They are frauds upon the party who is uninformed of them and who acts in good faith.
When a man publicly offers his property to the highest bidder at an auction sale, thereby obligating himself to take the highest sum offered for it, however disproportioned that sum may be to its actual worth, it seems very .reasonable that he should be protected against secret agreements between the bidders, by which one may be enabled to make the purchase upon
But the distinction between the case at bar, and the case referred to is too apparent to require illustration. And I would not have felt called upon to notice those cases at all, but that they have been supposed to sustain two other decisions pronounced by the supreme court of New York, and which are claimed by the plaintiffs in error to be entirely decisive of the main question presented upon this record. I refer to the cases of Hooker v. Vanderwater, 4 Denio, 849, and Stanton v. Allen, 5 id., 434. These cases arose upon contracts between different transportation companies upon the Erie canal, by which the parties agreed to stock their capital, and turn their earnings into a common fund, to be then apportioned between the different proprietors, under certain regulations contained in the articles of agreement.
The purpose assigned for the arrangement was the establishing of fair and uniform rates of freight, so equalizing the business among themselves • as to avoid all unnecessary expense in doing the same. In the case first mentioned, the agreement was held to be void as conflicting with a statute of that state. In the second case the same court held the agreement void at common law.. In the former case, Jewett, J., remarks: “It is a familiar maxim that competition is the life of trade. It follows that whatever, destroys or even relaxes competition in trade is injurious, if not fatal to it.” And in the latter case, McKissock, J., observes that: “ While, the introductory terms of the agreement proposed nothing apparently objectionable, the ultimate object is-very manifest, and is of a different character. It is nothing less than the attainment of- an exemption of the standard of freights, and the facilities and accommodations to be rendered
Such reasons are assigned in support of the judgments pronounced in those cases. I would be reluctant to subscribe to them. I think it would be unsafe to adopt as a rule of law, every maxim which is current in the counting room. It was said some three hundred years ago, that trade and traffic were the life of every commonwealth, especially of an island. City of London's Case, 8 Co., 125.
If it be true, also, that competition is the life of trade, it may follow such premises, that he who relaxes competition commits an act injurious to trade; and not only so, but he commits an overt act of treason against the commonwealth. But I apprehend it is not true that competition is the life of trade. On the contrary, that maxim is one of the least reliable of the host that may be picked up in every market place. It is in fact the shibboleth of mere gambling speculation, and is hardly entitled to take rank as an axiom in the jurisprudence of this country. I believe universal observation will attest that for the last quarter of a century, competition in trade has caused more individual distress, if not more public. injury, than the want of competition.
Indeed, by reducing prices below, or raising them above values, (as the nature of the trade prompted), competition hah
But upon the abstract question whether the agreements disclosed in those cases did contravene public policy, the decisions therein pronounced are entirely conclusive upon us. And if the policy of that great state imposes upon her citizens the obligation of unrestrained and unrelenting competition in the business of transportation upon her canals, in order to swell the revenues from that already munificent source, I have nothing to urge against it.
I am not sure I should have discovered the rule applied in the determination of those cases, had it not been disclosed. to me by the high authority of that court. • Entertaining the views I do of the extreme caution to be observed in setting aside bonafide contracts in behalf of public policy, I am not sure I should have found, as a legal presumption, that when the parties to those contracts had combined their efforts and capital in order to diminish their expenses and increase their profits, they would have so abused the advantages thereby secured as to
But entirely controlling as those judgments are upon the question decided, they are far from being decisive of the case before us; for those agreements are broadly distinguished from the one I am considering, in the following characteristics: The theater upon which' the restraint was imposed by those contracts was the property of the state, was built by the state, from which the state received the revenues. Here the theater is the city of Milwaukee, from which the state receives no revenue except what is derived from ordinary taxation. There the theater was the only one within the state affording like facilities to the same trade. Here the city of Milwaukee is only one (though doubtless the most considerable) of very many markets within the state for the sate of wheat. There the combination comprised, in one case, a large portion, and, in the other, all the facilities employed- upon the canal. Here the record does not inform us what portion of the facilities for the wheat trade existing in Milwaukee are placed under the control of the mill owners. There, an unlimited power was reserved to raise the price of transportation. Here the right to increase the price of storage above four cents per bushel is expressly denied.
Because, therefore, the restraint imposed by this agreement is limited and reasonable, and because it is supported by a good consideration, in the judgment of this court, the same does not contravene public policy, is not void; and the judgment of the county court must be affirmed.