670 F.2d 187 | D.C. Cir. | 1981
Lead Opinion
ORDER
Upon consideration of the petitions for rehearing filed by Respondent, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, and Interve-nor, Central Illinois Public Service Co., and responses thereto, it is
ORDERED, by the Court, that petitions for rehearing are granted and Section III A of our opinion is amended to reflect the views set out in the supplemental opinion.
Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge WALD.
Our original opinion in this case was issued on August 17, 1981.
Section III A examined Illinois Cities of Bethany’s (“Cities”) allegation that a wholesale electric power tariff, filed by CIPSCO under section 205 of the Federal Power Act, 16 U.S.C. § 824d, and approved by FERC, was too high in comparison with CIPSCO’s retail rates. Cities, a group of CIPSCO wholesale customers, claimed that they were being price squeezed.
ANALYSIS
Our decision to remand was based upon our finding that the ALJ had erred initially in rejecting a prima facie price squeeze case
The price squeeze case presented by Cities was based upon the Alcoa transfer price test. United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 436-38 (2d Cir. 1945) (hereinafter Alcoa). That test maintains that “[i]f a vertically integrated entity cannot purchase at its own wholesale rates and still realize a profit at its own retail rates, then it can be concluded that the supplier has overcharged its wholesale customers.” Illinois Cities, supra, slip op. at 14.
The ALJ appears, however, to have misunderstood the appropriate transfer price test proffered. He concluded that “it would place in the hands of the party alleging discrimination the ability to create the discriminatory premises either willfully or simply through an inefficient municipal operation.” J.A. 416. Thus he viewed it as requiring an inquiry into whether a vertically integrated company could realize a profit by purchasing at its own wholesale rates and selling at the retail rates of the party alleging discrimination rather than at its own retail rates. Language in our original opinion
The Supreme Court in Conway held that although the Commission lacked jurisdiction to fix retail rates, its jurisdiction to set wholesale rates allowed it to take retail rates into consideration where wholesale customers were price squeezed by dint either of the utility company’s desire to drive out retail competitors or of the interplay between federally and locally regulated rates. .
The Commission must arrive at a rate level deemed by it to be just and reasonable, but in doing so it must consider the tendered allegations that the proposed rates are discriminatory and anticompeti-tive.18
The Supreme Court upheld a decision of this court, per Leventhal, J., and observed that this court was “quite correct” in concluding:
When costs are fully allocated, both the retail rate and the proposed wholesale rate may fall within a zone of reasonableness, yet create a price squeeze between themselves. There would, at the very least, be latitude in the FPC to put wholesale rates in the lower range of the zone of reasonableness, without concern that overall results would be impaired, in view of the utility’s own decision to depress certain retail revenues in order to curb the retail competition of its wholesale customers.19
We read that language as permitting the Commission to adjust wholesale rates within a range of reasonableness to respond either to utility efforts to depress retail rates to meet competition, or to situations where the imperfections of regulation result in an unintended price squeeze. Since ratemaking is an inexact science, even bona fide allocations of costs between wholesale and retail operations may be imperfect or rates of return set by different regulators at the wholesale and retail levels may make it impossible for purchasing wholesalers, no matter how efficient, to compete at the retail level. In such cases, Conway acknowledges the Commission’s discretion to press wholesale rates to the lower end of the zone of reasonableness. The Conway doctrine is not, however, we emphasize, designed to subsidize particular retail competitors. Rather, the doctrine allows the Commission some leeway where it finds that the process of price setting by regulation, and not the superior efficiency of the utility, might result in retail competitors being driven from the market.
Here, the requisite • proof that a price squeeze existed was not forthcoming and indeed was refuted by the Staff study. When costs were fully allocated between wholesale and retail operations, CIPSCO’s wholesale profit margin was both reasona
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, we vacate those parts of our initial decisions as are inconsistent with this supplemental opinion, and affirm the decision of the Commission.
. Illinois Cities of Bethany, et al. v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, No. 80-1633 (D.C.Cir. Aug. 17, 1981) (hereinafter Illinois Cities).
. The United States submitted an amicus brief in support of respondent and intervenor’s petitions for rehearing. A petition of Commonwealth Edison Co. to submit an amicus brief was denied.
. Specifically, the following sections of § HI A are vacated: slip op. at 2, lines 17 (beginning “in large”) to 19; slip op. at 9, line 4 (delete “must”); slip op. at 10, lines 17-19 and n.26; slip op. at 14, line 1 (delete “, quite correctly,”); slip op. text accompanying notes and notes 50-73; and slip op. at 27, following note 85 (delete “Remanded for further proceedings consistent with this opinion. ”)
. “[A] ‘price squeeze’ occurs when a wholesale supplier, who also sells at retail, charges such high rates to its wholesale customers that they cannot compete with the supplier’s retail rate.” Hjelmfelt, A Price Squeeze Theory For Implementation of Federal Power Commission v. Conway Corp., 50 U.Colo.L.Rev. 459 (1979). Because FERC is required to insure “just and reasonable” rates, 16 U.S.C. § 824d, we are concerned here only with price squeezes not due to the vertically integrated company’s superior efficiency.
. We apparently attached too much importance to the establishment of a prima facie case of price squeeze in our initial decision. The Commission informs us in its brief on Rehearing that it uses prima facie case “to mean that enough has been shown to warrant inquiry into the price squeeze allegations to ascertain whether price discrimination exists.... It is merely a threshold which must be crossed to put the question at issue. If there is sufficient evidence to suggest that price discrimination may exist, then the ‘prima facie case’ is established. The utility is then required to prove the absence of price discrimination. This is unlike the ordinary use of a ‘prima facie case’ where the party who establishes it is, as a matter of law, entitled to relief unless the defending party rebuts that case.” Respondent’s Petition For Rehearing and Suggestion For Rehearing En Banc (hereinafter Respondent’s Petition) at 8 n.l 1.
. Illinois Cities, supra, slip op. at 15. We were misled, as the ALJ may have been, by the assumption, suggested by questioning of an expert witness, that CIPSCO would have incurred the same costs that Cities has incurred. J.A. 139. Compare Petitioner’s Reply Brief, Illinois Cities, at 12-14 (Alcoa test properly set out).
. Respondent’s Petition at 3, 6, 9.
. Intervenor’s Petition For Rehearing and Suggestion For Rehearing En Banc at 2.
. Respondent’s Petition at 3.
. See Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 437:
*190 The plaintiff’s theory is that “Alcoa” consistently sold ingot at so high a price that the “sheet rollers,” who were forced to buy from it, could not pay the expenses of “rolling” the “sheet” and make a living profit out of the price at which “Alcoa” itself sold “sheet.” To establish this the plaintiff asks us to take “Alcoa’s” costs of “rolling” as a fair measure of its competitors’ costs, and to assume that they had to meet “Alcoa’s” price for all grades of “sheet,” and could not buy ingot elsewhere.
We note that Alcoa’s own costs of rolling were used as a fair measure of its competitor’s costs. Here, competitor’s costs were offered as a fair measure of CIPSCO’s costs. Although it may be, as Cities asserts, that its retail costs were lower than CIPSCO’s, there was inadequate evidence in the record to prove that assumption. Petitioners draw our attention to J.A. 136-39. Although the evidence there correctly indicated that if CIPSCO owned each of the Cities’ distribution systems it would pay higher taxes, J.A. 136-38, the hypothetical itself merely assumed that CIPSCO would incur the same costs that Cities incurred.
. See Opinion No. 62, Southern California Edison Co. Opinion and Order on Rate Increases, FERC Docket No. ER 76-205, Aug. 22, 1979 at 31, J.A. 625.
. Cities argues that the Staff study cost of service test was inferior to the price squeeze test because it merely relied upon a sample of the relative rates of return in wholesale and retail markets. Response By Cities of Bethany, Et Al. To Petition Of CIPSCO For Rehearing and Suggestion For Rehearing En Banc at 3-4, 7. But see, slip op. at n.27 (sample used by petitioners themselves to establish prima facie price squeeze case). It is true that an exhaustive comparison of wholesale and retail rates of return would probably be more accurate than a sample. However, we do not find, as apparently the ALJ and FERC did not, that the sample indicated that there was need to conduct a full comparison of wholesale and retail rates of return. Had the Staff study indicated otherwise, we assume that either a more exhaustive cost of service study would have been run or possibly a transfer price test would have been conducted.
. See 16 U.S.C. § 824d(b); see also Federal Power Commission v. Conway, 510 F.2d 1264 (D.C.Cir.1975), aff'd, 426 U.S. 271, 96 S.Ct. 1999, 48 L.Ed.2d 626 (1976) (hereinafter Conway).
. Under the price transfer test the vertically integrated company’s costs of retail operations must be added to the product purchased at its wholesale rates to determine profitability, so the usefulness of that test depends upon an accurate identification of retail costs. If the company fails to realize a profit under this test, indications are that retail costs have been improperly transferred to the wholesale operations, (or, less likely, retail operations are inefficient). Under the methodology of the Staff study, wholesale and retail revenues over their respective incurred costs are compared. This method of analysis also depends upon a proper identification of wholesale and retail costs. If after wholesale and retail costs are fully allocated the company’s wholesale profit margin is significantly greater than its retail profit margin, indications are that a price discrimination is occurring. Both methods of analysis are acceptable methods of establishing a price squeeze case. See J.A. at 625. Although the results of a cost of service study are phrased in terms of a profit differential, see Memorandum By The Cities of Bethany, Et Al. In Response To The “Memorandum Amicus Curiae” Filed By The Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice at 4, like the price squeeze test, the cost of service study also seeks to determine whether the vertically integrated company maintains artificially high wholesale prices in order to squeeze out its retail competition. If, after costs are fully allocated, it appears that the wholesale rate of return of a vertically integrated company is reasonable and, in fact, lower than retail rate of return, it would appear that wholesale customers are not being price squeezed — indeed, the higher the retail rate of return vis-a-vis the wholesale rate of return, the greater the wholesale customer’s discount.
. Illinois Cities, supra, slip op. at 16 n.47; see also San Antonio, Texas Acting By and Through Its City Public Service Board v. United States and Interstate Commerce Commission,
. See Illinois Cities, supra, slip op. at 16 n.47.
. Conway, supra, 426 U.S. 271, 96 S.Ct. 1999, 48 L.Ed.2d 626.
. Id. at 279, 96 S.Ct. at 2004.
. Conway, supra, 510 F.2d at 1274 (footnotes omitted).
Rehearing
OPINION AS MODIFIED ON REHEARING
Before WRIGHT,
Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge WALD.
In this action, eight Illinois municipalities
I. THE FACTS
On December 1,1977, CIPSCO filed tariff sheets with the Commission proposing increases in three wholesale rates: W — 1, which governs sales to electric cooperatives, W-2, which covers sales to full-requirement
Hearings were not held on the disputed issues until December, 1978.
Both parties filed briefs on exceptions to the Initial Decision with the Commission. Six months later, on February 21, 1980, the Commission issued an order summarily affirming the ALJ’s opinion in all but two respects.
The Cities have petitioned this court for review of the Commission’s order. CIPSCO moved for and was granted leave to intervene before this court in support of the Commission’s actions.
II. THE ISSUES
Though the Cities preserved twelve arguments by their petition for rehearing, they present only six in this petition for direct review.
Petitioners raise three novel claims of error. They challenge first the Commission’s decision to deny “price squeeze” relief to the Cities, contending that they established that a price squeeze, as defined by the Commission’s regulations, existed and thus that the Commission’s adoption of the ALJ’s finding that no price squeeze relief was warranted lacked a substantial eviden-tiary basis. Secondly, they claim the Commission erred in failing to normalize the excess generating capacity created by the opening of the new Newton power plant, thereby unreasonably inflating the rate base and corresponding rate assessments. Finally, they argue that the Commission’s reversal of the ALJ’s recommendation that FERC investigate CIPSCO’s management constituted reversible error, and they ask this court to direct the Commission to undertake the investigation.
III. ANALYSIS
A. Price Squeeze
The most serious of the Cities’ allegations is that the challenged rates are set too high in comparison to CIPSCO’s retail rates to allow the Cities to compete with CIPSCO for retail, especially high-volume retail,
1. The Elements of a Prime Facie Case
Though a fixture of antitrust law since the 1945 decision in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America (“Alcoa”),
(1) Specification of the filing utility’s retail rate schedules with which the intervening wholesale customer is unable to compete due to purchased power costs;
(2) A showing that a competitive situation exists in that the wholesale customer competes in the same market as the filing utility;
(3) A showing that the retail rates are lower than the proposed wholesale rates for comparable service;
(4) The wholesale customer’s prospective rate for comparable retail service, i.e., the rate necessary to recover bulk power costs (at the proposed wholesale rate) and distribution costs; and
(5) An indication of the reduction in the wholesale rate necessary to eliminate the price squeeze alleged.25
It should be noted that unlike the ordinary situation where a party who establishes a prima facie case is, as a matter of law, entitled to relief unless the defending party rebuts the case, the establishment of a pri-ma facie price squeeze case means only that enough has been shown to warrant inquiry into the price squeeze allegations to ascertain whether price discrimination exists. It is, the Commission assures us, merely the threshold
Petitioners claim that they established a prima facie ease by comparing the wholesale rates W-2 and W-3 with the comparable
Petitioners challenge the ALJ’s reliance on the revised retail tariffs. They claim that the proper comparison is always between the wholesale and retail rates in effect on the date of implementation of the revised wholesale tariff because “CIPSCO had full discretion to wait until after a resolution of its retail rates before filing a wholesale increase.”
Petitioners further challenge the ALJ’s finding that the wholesale rates were lower than the retail rates by arguing that a “true comparison” of the two rates requires that the wholesale rate be compared to an “adjusted” retail rate, that is, the retail
They argue that a utility performs three analytically distinct functions: generation, transmission and distribution. Generation and transmission are company-wide costs and do not vary with the type of customers taking the power. Distribution, on the other hand, is largely a retail cost since the municipals provide their own distribution. Thus, the cities argue that we should compare the wholesale rate for transmission and generation with the average retail rate for serving all customer classes with transmission and generation. Any disparity would be implicitly unjustified since these costs should be uniform company-wide. Consequently, the difference would show the amount of the price squeeze.42
Petitioners attempted to show that under this test a price squeeze exists here by working the transfer price analysis forwards and backwards. First, petitioners subtracted costs they claim are associated only with the distribution function from the revenues that would have been collected from them had petitioners been charged for their electricity purchases under the retail rates 9 and 9-B. The difference, according to petitioners’ calculations, is less than the amounts actually collected from them under the wholesale rates.
The ALJ rejected the Cities’ first attempt at proving that they were being charged more than retailers for generation and transmission services not by rejecting individually the proposed adjustments
concept ... so new that one doubts if it will ever become old for it would place in the hands of the party alleging discrimination the ability to create the discriminatory premises either willfully or simply through an inefficient municipal operation.48
He concluded with the parting shot:
it is not the policy of Conway to guarantee that all costs incurred in operating a municipal system (efficiently or otherwise) should be “subsidized by its investor-owned supplier.”49
The price transfer test, as set forth in Alcoa, is a legitimate means of indicating a price squeeze. FERC itself has accepted that test.
The Commission must arrive at a rate level deemed by it to be just and reasonable, but in doing so it must consider the tendered allegations that the proposed rates are discriminatory and anticompeti-tive.57
The Supreme Court upheld a decision of this court, per Leventhal, J., and observed that this court was “quite correct” in concluding:
When the costs are fully allocated, both the retail rate and the proposed wholesale rate may fall within a zone of reasonableness, yet create a price squeeze between •themselves. There would, at the very least, be latitude in the FPC to put wholesale rates in the lower range of the zone of reasonableness, without concern that overall results would be impaired, in view of the utility’s own decision to depress certain retail revenues in order to curb the retail competition of its wholesale customers.58
We read that language as permitting the Commission to adjust wholesale rates , within a range of reasonableness to respond either to utility efforts to depress retail rates to meet competition, or to situations where the imperfections of regulation result in an unintended price squeeze. Since ratemaking is an inexact science, even bona fide allocations of costs between wholesale and retail operations may be imperfect or rates of return set by different regulators at the wholesale and retail levels may make it impossible for purchasing wholesalers, no matter how efficient, to compete at the retail level. In such cases, Conway acknowledges the Commission’s discretion to press wholesale rates to the lower end of the zone of reasonableness. The Conway doctrine is not, however, we emphasize, designed to subsidize particular retail competitors. Rather, the doctrine allows the Commission some leeway where it finds that the process of price setting by regulation, and not the superior efficiency of the utility, might result in retail competitors being driven from the market.
Here, the requisite proof that a price squeeze existed was not forthcoming and indeed was refuted by the Staff study. When costs were fully allocated between wholesale and retail operations, CIPSCO’s wholesale profit margin was sufficiently lower than its retail profit margin so that there was no occasion for the Commission to exercise its Conway discretion.
B. Normalization of Generating Capacity
In 1977, CIPSCO opened a new generating plant resulting in a sudden increase in the system’s generating reserves.
While we recognize that rate treatment of excess generating capacity in the electric utility industry is controversial in this era of slow demand growth, we are also aware that it is notoriously difficult to project accurately the demand for electric power far enough in advance to coordinate need with the construction of new generating facilities,
C. Refusal to Investigate
The ALJ found that CIPSCO’s operating and maintenance costs exceded the industry norm, and recommended that FERC investigate the causes of this phenomenon.
Petitioners’ argument is misdirected to this court. It is now settled law that, barring extreme circumstances, an agency’s refusal to institute an investigation is unreviewable.
Affirmed.
Judge Wright did not participate in the rehearing.
. The eight municipalities are: Cairo, Flora, Metropolis, Roodhouse, Carmi, Bushnell, Marshall and Rantoul.
. Petitioners Cairo, Flora, Metropolis, Rood-house and Carmi are full-requirement customers of CIPSCO.
. Petitioners Bushnell, Marshall and Rantoul purchase only part of their electric power supply from CIPSCO.
. See Central Illinois Public Service Company Initial Decision of the Administrative Law Judge, No. ER78-80, at 2 (July 26, 1979) (“Initial Decision"), Joint Appendix (“J.A.”) 348.
. Initial Decision at 2-3, J.A. 348-49.
. Id at 3, J.A. 349.
. Id. CIPSCO filed an application for rehearing of the December 30th order, which was denied on February 28, 1978. Id.
. Formal and informal settlement negotiations as well as extensive discovery took place during the intervening nine months. Id.
. Id. at 3 — 4, J.A. 349-50. See also note 4 supra.
. CIPSCO stated that the proposed tariffs would increase its revenues by approximately $1,407,000. Initial Decision at 2, J.A. 348. While the Commission staff fully supported CIPSCO’s W-2 rate increase, they found $191,-000 of the W-3 increase to be unjustified. Id. at 4, J.A. 350. CIPSCO concurred in five of the Staffs proposed adjustments; the ALJ found in favor of the Staff on three of the four remaining ones. He also agreed with the Staff’s position on the allowable rate of return, contract discrimination, and price squeeze issues. The only issue on which the Cities prevailed before the ALJ without the support of the Staff was on their request for an investigation into CIP-SCO’s operating efficiency.
. See Opinion No. 75, Central Illinois Public Service Company Opinion and Order Affirming in Part and Modifying in Part Initial Decision, No. ER78-80, Feb. 21, 1980, J.A. 423.
. Opinion No. 75, supra note 11, at 2, J.A. 424.
. Id.
. The Commission now argues that the Cities failed to raise some of these issues in their petition for rehearing, and thus are barred from arguing them before this court, see 16 U.S.C. § 8251(b) (inclusion of issues in petition for rehearing is jurisdictional prerequisite to review in this court). However, our review of the petition for rehearing, see J.A. 427-464, reveals this argument to be groundless. Though the Cities did not argue each point at length in their petition for rehearing, they specifically (1) detailed each decision to which they were objecting and (2) incorporated by reference specific pages from documents previously filed with the Commission in this docket at which such arguments were contained.
. See 16 U.S.C. § 8251(a) (rehearing deemed denied for purposes of judicial review if FERC takes no action on petition within 30 days).
. See Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 4 — 5.
. See Brief for the Petitioner, Village of Rantoul, Illinois v. FERC, No. 80-1632 (D.C.Cir. July 10, 1981) (mem.) at 1-2 (listing arguments). The three arguments in common are: that CIPSCO should be required to offer each customer service at the rate offered to certain customers by virtue of pre-existing contractual requirements; that the Commission erred by ordering tax normalization subject to refund for rate-making purposes pending the outcome of a related rule-making proceeding; and that the Commission erred in failing to take proper account of the self-generating potential of the W-3 customers in allowing CIPSCO’s proposed demand allocations.
. Village of Rantoul, Illinois v. FERC, No. 80-1632 (D.C.Cir. July 10, 1981) (mem.).
. See General Rules of the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit, tit. II, rule 8(f).
. At oral argument, counsel for the Cities contended that the contract discrimination issue in this case differs from that in Rantoul because, unlike that case, there is no evidence here that the petitioners were offered and rejected the now favorable contract terms. In this case, each city (with the exception of Carmi, Rood-house and Bushnell, which began purchasing power from CIPSCO after it had ceased offering long-term contracts to customers, see J.A. 150-06 (cross-examination of Carl Wall, CIP-SCO vice-president)) had had a contract similar to those still governing the sale of power to the cities of Marshall and Metropolis. Because they had entered into the fixed rate, fixed term contracts at a date earlier than had Marshall and Metropolis, their contracts expired at an earlier date. See J.A. 79 (cross-examination of Bruce Barnes, Jr., Cities’ witness); J.A. 105-06 (cross-examination of Carl Wall). We view this factual dissimilarity as a distinction without a (legal) difference. Petitioners have still failed to demonstrate more than that a rate differential stemming “from the fact that a public utility is free to file for unilateral rate increases with respect to some of its customers while the rate it charges to the remainder are frozen under the Mobile-Sierra doctrine” exists; as we have made clear in previous cases, more is necessary to establish a violation of section 205(b) of the Federal Power Act. See Boroughs of Chambersburg v. FERC, 580 F.2d 573, 578 (D.C.Cir.1978).
The Cities agreed at oral argument that their tax normalization and demand allocation argu-merits were identical in all essential respects to those made in Rantoul. Our review of the record reveals that petitioners in this action, like the petitioner in Rantoul, lack a substantial evidentiary basis for contending that the demand allocation method used failed to credit petitioners’ for their generating capacity. We likewise find without merit their argument that the Commission could not order rates collected subject to refund pending the outcome of a highly disputed rulemaking proceeding. The Commission clearly has the discretion to adopt interim procedures which, if found inappropriate for any reason, will be remedied on a retroactive basis.
. Petitioners claim they are unable to compete with CIPSCO’s 9 and 9-B rates. Retail rate 9 applies to sales to large light and power customers, primarily industrials. To qualify for rate 9-B, customers must guarantee “load,” that is, a fairly constant demand, as well as high demand. See J.A. 60 (additional testimony of Carl Wall).
. Petitioners in fact ask for a variety of remedies, which often conflict with one another, in their initial and reply briefs. See Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 31 (asking for wholesale rate set at 1977 retail rate); id. at 35 (asking for rate calculated on 7.07% return); id. at 37 (asking for rate low enough to allow petitioners to compete for 9 and 9-B customers); Reply Brief for the Petitioners at 11 (wholesale rate should be 1977 retail rate “adjusted for any cost savings and applicable tax law”). We have taken the liberty of rephrasing their argument to correspond with the price squeeze remedy accept
. 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945). The Commission summarized Alcoa’s mandate as follows:
In Alcoa, the court found that the company was engaged in two distinct activities: The production of “ingot” and the manufacturing of “sheet.” Alcoa had a monopoly over the production of ingot which is used to manufacture sheet, but had competitors for its manufacturing function. In applying the transfer price analysis the court assumed that the cost of manufacturing the sheet was the same for Alcoa and its competitors and found that since the competitor’s total costs were greater than Alcoa’s, Alcoa was charging more than a fair price of the ingot.
Opinion No. 62, Southern California Edison Co. Opinion and Order on Rate Increases, FERC Docket No. ER76-205, Aug. 22, 1979 at 30, J.A. 624.
. See FPC v. Conway Corp., 426 U.S. 271, 96 S.Ct. 1999, 48 L.Ed.2d 626 (1976). Section 205(b) of the Federal Power Act, 16 U.S.C. § 824d(b) provides:
No public utility shall, with respect to any transmission or sale subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission, (1) make or grant any undue preference or advantage to any person or subject any person to any undue prejudice or disadvantage, or (2) maintain any unreasonable difference in rates, charges, service, facilities, or in any other respect, either as between localities or as between classes of service.
. 18 C.F.R. § 2.17.
. Respondent’s Petition For Rehearing and Suggestion For Rehearing En Banc at 8 n.ll.
. Petitioners claim the W-2, W-3, 9 and 9-B rates are comparable because they are calculated for customers with the same load and de
. See Exhibit 1A, J.A. 157; Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 27.
. Initial Decision at 67, J.A. 413.
. Id.; See also Exhibit 1, J.A. 156 (1978 retail rates annualized); Exhibit IB, J.A. 168 (actual retail rates in effect).
. Initial Decision at 67, J.A. 413.
. Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 28.
. Because both state regulatory agencies and FERC can suspend the effectiveness of proposed rates, prescribe temporary rates pending the outcome of investigations, and order refunds at the conclusion of lengthy (often three to four year) investigations, thus retroactively reducing rates, see Note, The Applicability of Antitrust Laws to Price Squeezes in the Electric Utility Industry, 54 St. John’s L.Rev. 103, 109-10 (1979); see also Brief for Intervenor CIPSCO at 37 (detailing procedure of Illinois Commerce Commission), a utility may be unsure of what rates are in effect at any given time until long after the fact. Ruling that they must wait out this lag time before proposing new increases, in this era of rising fuel costs and inflation, would be truly unreasonable.
. In Cities of Batavia v. FPC, 548 F.2d 1056 (D.C.Cir.1977), this court considered and remanded to the Commission for reconsideration a price squeeze complaint arising from a ten-month period in which wholesale prices exceeded comparable retail rates. Obviously, the longer an objectionable price differential exists, the more likely it is that anticompetitive effects will result and the more unwilling we will be to gloss over the fact that such a differential existed by relying on “annualized” rate tables.
. The retail rates were lower than the wholesale ones for one-quarter of the year.
. On average, the retail rates were higher than the comparable wholesale ones during the 1978 calendar year. See Exhibit 1B, J.A. 168; Initial Decision at 67, J.A. 413; Reply by Intervenor CIPSCO to “Response by Illinois Cities to Question Posed by Court at Oral Argument” at 2-4 (citing transcript of testimony of Bruce Barnes, Jr.).
. Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 28.
. See Initial Decision at 68-69, J.A. 414-15 (subtraction of costs from revenues inappropriate failing adjustment for all variables).
. To call 18 C.F.R. § 2.17 a “regulation,” as even FERC contends, is to overstate its importance. It was promulgated as a statement of general policy to guide the Staff in dealing with price squeeze cases in the immediate aftermath of Conway, the Commission has felt free to disregard its strictures when conducting price squeeze proceedings. See, e.g., Opinion No. 62, supra note 23, at 21-22, J.A. 615-16 (guideline “just a statement of the standards the Commission intends to apply in price squeeze cases”; “[ejither the parties or the Commission are free to argue that the standards thus set out are inappropriate”); Opinion No. 53, Boston Edison Co. Opinion and Order Affirming in Part and Modifying and Reversing in Part Initial Decision and Establishing Just and Reasonable Electric Rates, Docket No. E-8855, July 31, 1979 at 23, J.A. 593 (proposing different test for price squeeze allegation when wholesale rate less than comparable retail rate). Indeed, in this proceeding, the ALJ did not stop with a conclusion that petitioners failed to present a prima facie case under the section 2.17 criteria. Rather, giving petitioners the benefit of the doubt, he assumed arguendo that they had presented a prima facie case and evaluated evidence of CIPSCO’s relative rates of return as rebuttal testimony. Initial Decision at 67, J.A. 413 (Staffs presentation an affirmative defense).
. See Hjelmfelt, A Price Squeeze Theory for Implementation of Federal Power Commission v. Conway Corp., 50 U.Colo.L.Rev. 459, 459 n.2 (1979).
. Reply Brief for the Petitioners at 12; see note 23 supra (utilization of transfer price test in Alcoa); Hjelmfelt, supra note 40, at 459 n.2 (listing authorities).
. Opinion No. 62, supra note 23, at 30, J.A. 624 (footnote omitted).
. See Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 28-29; Initial Decision at 66, 68-69, J.A. 412, 414 — 415.
. See Exhibit 56, J.A. 315-19; J.A. 139-40 (cross-examination of James Bachman).
. He chose this strategy although evidence existed on the record from which he could have concluded at least some of the adjustments advocated by the Cities were unwarranted. See, e.g., J.A. 74 (prepared testimony of James Bachman) (distribution factors deducted by Cities’ witness duplicate “without justification” voltage discounts calculated into rates 9 and 9-B); J.A. 59 (prepared testimony of Carl Wall) (transmission loss credit developed by Cities’ witness inaccurate).
. See J.A. 16 (revised testimony of David Hed-berg, Staff witness) (CIPSCO earned 8.65% and 9.89% return on rates W-2 and W-3 and 15.99% and 12.96% return on rates 9 and 9-B respectively).
. Petitioners now challenge the accuracy of the study’s allocation of costs of service between retail and wholesale customers. However, the majority of their challenges stem from their dissatisfaction with the way FERC has defined the cost of wholesale service in this proceeding, a definition which we uphold in its entirety in this appeal. In addition, petitioners claim that the ratio of wholesale to retail costs may have changed in the two years since this study was conducted. However, the Cities have not indicated any reason aside from the passage of time why such ratios might have changed, see Initial Decision at 68, J.A. 414; in the absence of such evidence, we will not hold that the utilization of a two year old study for these purposes is per se unreasonable. Two years is not so long a time that substantial changes can be presumed to have taken place. Finally, petitioners allege that neither the ALJ nor the Staff examined the methodology of the study. This assertion is belied by the record. See Initial Decision at 68, J.A. 414; J.A. 13 (testimony of David Hedberg); J.A. 129-131 (cross-examination of James Bachman); Exhibit 9, J.A. 200-201 (Display A) (letter to Carl Wall from Arthur Anderson & Co. re cost of service study). In view of the total lack of evidence that extrapolation from this study would lead to distorted results, we accept the Commission’s decision to utilize it as a reasonable exercise of its discretion.
. Initial Decision at 70, J.A. 416.
. Id.
. Opinion No. 62, supra note 23, at 31, J.A. 625.
. See Opinion No. 62, Southern California Edison Co. Opinion and Order on Rate Increases, FERC Docket No. ER 76-205, Aug. 22, 1979 at 31, J.A. 625. Cities argues that the Staff study cost of service test was inferior to the price squeeze test because it merely sampled the relative rates of return in wholesale and retail markets. Response By Cities Of Bethany, Et Al. To Petition Of CIPSCO For Rehearing And Suggestion For Rehearing En Banc at 3-4, 7. But see slip op. at n.27. It is true that an exhaustive comparison would probably be more accurate than a survey, however, the survey indicated that there was no need to conduct a full comparison of wholesale and retail rates of return. Had the Staff study indicated otherwise, we assume that either a more exhaustive cost of service study would have been run or possibly a transfer price test would have been conducted.
. See 16 U.S.C. § 824d(b); see also FPC v. Conway Corp., supra.
. Under the price transfer test the vertically integrated company’s costs of retail operations must be added to the product purchased at its wholesale rates to determine profitability, so the usefulness of that test depends upon an accurate identification of retail costs. If the company fails to realize a profit under this test, Indications are that retail costs have been improperly transferred to the wholesale operations (or, less likely, retail operations are inefficient). Under the methodology of the Staff study, wholesale and retail revenues over their respective incurred costs are compared. This method of analysis also depends upon a proper identification of wholesale and retail costs. If, after wholesale and retail costs are fully allocated, the company’s wholesale profit margin is significantly greater than its retail profit margin, indications are that a price discrimination is occuring. Both methods of analysis are acceptable methods of establishing a price squeeze case. See J.A. at 625. Although the results of a cost of service study are phrased in terms of a profit differential, see Memorandum By The Cities of Bethany, Et Al. In Response To The “Memorandum Amicus Curiae” Filed By The Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice at 4, like the price squeeze test, the cost of service study also seeks to determine whether the vertically integrated company maintains artificially high wholesale prices in order to squeeze out its retail competition. If, after costs are fully allocated, it appears that the wholesale rate of return of a vertically integrated company is reasonable and, in fact, lower than retail rate of return, it would appear that wholesale customers are not being price squeezed — indeed, the higher the retail rate of return vis-a-vis the wholesale rate of return, the greater the wholesale customer’s discount.
. See supra at 198 n.47.
. Id. See also San Antonio, Texas Acting By and Through Its City Public Service Board v. United States and Interstate Commerce Commission, 631 F.2d 831, 837 (D.C.Cir.1980), slip op. at twelve (courts reluctant to interfere with agency’s choice of methodology); but see, id. at 841 (when errors in methodology apparent, courts available for relief).
. See Alcoa, 148 F.2d at 437:
The plaintiff’s theory is that “Alcoa” consistently sold ingot at so high a price that the “sheet rollers,” who were forced to buy from it, could not pay the expenses of “rolling” the “sheet” and making a living profit out of the price at which “Alcoa” itself sold “sheet.” To establish this the plaintiff asks us to take “Alcoa’s” costs of “rolling” as a fair measure of its competitors’ costs, and to assume that they had to meet “Alcoa’s” price for all grades of “sheet,” and could not buy ingot elsewhere.
We note that Alcoa’s own costs of rolling were used as a fair measure of its competitor’s costs.
. FPC v. Conway, supra, 426 U.S. at 279, 96 S.Ct. at 2004.
. FPC v. Conway, 510 F.2d 1264, 1274 (D.C.Cir.1975), aff’d 426 U.S. 271, 96 S.Ct. 1999, 48 L.Ed.2d 626 (1976).
. The addition of the Newton generating plant increased the anticipated reserve capacity for 1978 to 30.2%. J.A. 4 (testimony of Bruce Barnes, Jr.). CIPSCO’s average reserve capacity for the previous ten years had been 10.61%, id., below the Commission’s recommended norm of 15-20%. See Initial Decision at 28, J.A. 375.
. See Initial Decision at 28-29, J.A. 375-76.
. Id.
. See Villages of Chatham and Riverton v. FERC, 662 F.2d 23, 35 (D.C.Cir.1981); Initial Decision at 30, J.A. 376. See generally Treb-ing, Equity, Efficiency, and the Viability of Public Utility Regulation, in Application of Economic Principles in Public Utility Industries 17, 33-34 (W. Sichel & T. Gies, eds. 1981).
. For instance, in times of increasing demand, a utility would have to open new plants each year to maintain a constant reserve capacity. As pointed out by the Commission in another proceeding involving a similar question, it may be cheaper in the long run to take advantage of economies of scale by building larger plants at more infrequent intervals, thus resulting in excess capacity at portions of the building cycle. See Opinion No. 63, supra note 50, J.A. 632-34; see also Initial Decision at 29, J.A. 375.
. The magnitude of the mismatch is not so great that we can conclude that CIPSCO’s management was per se incompetent, or even that CIPSCO committed a gross error in judgment. Moreover, it is unclear to what extent the mismatch will burden the ratepayers with extra costs. The ALJ points out that CIPSCO is expected to sell most of its excess capacity to other utilities, and the revenues “would necessarily redound to the benefit of ratepayers.” See Initial Decision at 31, J.A. 377. One point troubles us, however. Because FERC sets rates in advance, if CIPSCO was expected to sell its excess generating capacity during the 1978 calendar year, the expected revenues should have redounded to the ratepayers’ benefit — that is, they should have been factored into the rates accepted by the Commission. The ALJ’s use of the future tense to describe the crediting of these revenues may have been a mere “slip of the pen.” However, on remand, the Commission should check to ensure that any expected sale revenues were in fact credited against the sums to be raised from the ratepayers.
. We note, however, that some state utility commissions as well as commentators have advanced a form of normalization, not unlike that which petitioners press here, as a more equitable way of sharing the risks of overfore-casting utility demand. This alternative involves charging maintenance and depreciation expenses on the excess capacity as above-the-line operating expenses to be paid by the ratepayers over a period of years until the capital investment has been repaid. Because the excess capacity is not included in the rate base, however, shareholders do not receive any return on their investment. See Trebing, supra note 77. It may be that different rate treatments of excess capacity are not only justified, but necessary, to attain a “just and reasonable” price in other circumstances.
. Initial Decision at 52, J.A. 398.
. Opinion No. 75, supra note 11, at 2, J.A. 424.
. Initial Brief of the Petitioners at 60.
. Reply Brief for the Petitioners at 22.
. See City of Chicago v. United States, 396 U.S. 162, 165, 90 S.Ct. 309, 311, 24 L.Ed.2d 340 (1969); North Carolina Util. Comm. v. FERC, 653 F.2d 655, 669 (D.C.Cir.1981); General Motors v. FERC, 613 F.2d 939, 944 (D.C.Cir.1979). Petitioners do not argue, and we see no support for the proposition, that FERC’s decision not to institute an investigation in this case overstepped a statutory directive. Cf. Nader v. CAB, 657 F.2d 453, 456 (D.C.Cir.1981) (allegation that suspension policy violated statutory directive reviewable). In their reply brief, the Cities argue for the first time that this decision not to investigate is reviewable because “the Commission simply did not consider all the relevant factors in a way which would allow this Court to determine that the agency has actually exercised its discretion.” Reply Brief for the Petitioners at 23. However, the record lends no support to this contention; FERC clearly considered all the relevant factors listed by petitioners when exercising its discretion to refuse to launch an investigation. See Opinion No. 75, supra note 11, at 2, J.A. 424.