80 F. 839 | 4th Cir. | 1897
Lead Opinion
(after stating the case as above). The question in this case is: Is the contract set forth in the bill as the sole cause of action such a contract as a court of equity will enforce? There were two competitors before the municipal authorities of Richmond, each seeldng for himself, upon the best terms he could, the grant of a street-railway franchise. Apparently both of them were promoters,—that is to say, were without sufficient capital themselves, depending upon securing the aid, co-operation, or purchase of capitalists. The competition evidently was bitter and hostile, for
A text writer (Greenhood) states the rule to be this:
“Any agreement which, in its object or nature, is calculated to dimmish competition for the obtainment of a public or quasi public contract to the detriment of the public or those awarding the contract is void.” Greenh. Pub. Pol. p. 178, Rule 172.
In Pingry v. Washburn, 1 Aiken, 264, the court held that an agreement on the part of a corporation to grant to individuals certain privileges in consideration that they will withdraw their opposition to the passage of a legislative act touching the interests of the corporation is void as against public policy, and. prejudicial to correct ;and just legislation.
In Hunter v. Nolf, 71 Pa. St. 282, a contract between two candidates for the office of United States assessor that one should withdraw, and, if the other were appointed, they should divide profits, was recognized and treated as against public policy, and void. To the same effect is Meguire v. Corwine, 101 U. S. 108.
In Smith v. Applegate, 23 N. J. Law, 352, a note given to a person in consideration that he withdrew all opposition to the opening of a road was held void for the same reason.
The supreme court of Massachusetts in Gibbs v. Smith, 115 Mass. 592, clearly marks the line in an analogous case:
*844 “An agreement between two or more persons that one shall bid for all upon property about to be sold at public auction, which they desire to purchase together, either because they intend to hold it together or afterwards to divide it into such parts as they individually wish to hold, neither desiring the whole, or for any similar honest or reasonable purpose, is legal in its character, and will be enforced. But such an agreement, if made for the purpose of preventing competition, and reducing the price of the property to be sold below its fair-price, is against public policy, and void.”
A citation and examination of the very many cases on this fruitful subject would run this opinion, already too long, into an unreasonable length. Any effort which stifles competition, or prevents a fair and reasonable price for property, is against public policy. Especially is this the case when the property is a public or quasi public franchise. In the case at bar there were two bidders before the municipal authorities of Richmond for the franchise of a street rail-w-ay. Naturally and normally that competitor would receive the franchise who made the greatest concession for the public welfare.. The competition was active. Its tendency was to promote the public interest. It was withdrawn by the coming together of the parties, who agreed to abandon it for fear that they would neutralize-each other, and also for fear that the passage of the franchise in favor of one of the two competitors would be loaded with such onerous and exacting conditions that no capitalist could be induced to put his money in it. In other words, the competition would induce-great and extraordinary concessions for the public good. To prevent this, it was abandoned. Among themselves they would decide what names to be used in procuring the franchise, and the policy to be used in procuring it; that is to say, there being but one-contractor in the field, the promoters themselves could, in the absence of competition, decide to whom the contract should be awarded, and could, in some measure, dictate the terms and concessions to-be used in procuring the franchise. “The true inquiry is, is it the natural tendency of such an agreement to injuriously influence the public interests? The rule is that agreements which, in their necessary operation upon the action of the parties to them, tend to restrain their natural rivalry and competition, and thus to result in the disadvantage of the public or third parties, are against the principles of sound public policy, and are void.” Atchesom v. Mallon, 48 N. Y. 147. The conclusion is not unreasonable that the contract was against public policy and void.
But it is contended that, if this be admitted, the complainant is-still protected by the doctrine laid down in Brooks v. Martin, 2 Wall. 80, recognized in Farley v. Hill, 150 U. S. 576, 14 Sup. Ct. 186, and in the dissenting opinion in Burck v. Taylor, 152 U. S. 668, 14 Sup. Ct. 696; Armstrong v. Bank, 133 U. S. 467, 10 Sup. Ct. 450. The principle decided in these cases is:
“When several persons enter into an illegal contract for their own benefit, and the illegal transaction has been consummated, and the proceeds of the enterprise have been actually received, and carried to the credit of one of such parties, so that he can maintain an action therefor without requiring the aid of the illegal transaction to establish his case, he may be entitled to relief.”' McCrary, J., in Cook v. Sherman, 20 Fed. 170.
See, also, Jackson v. McLean, 36 Fed. 217.
It is urged, however, that the complainant, on the very afternoon of the day on which the city council gave the franchise, exposed his agreement with Shield in a public print. Assuming that this was seen by the members of the council, it cannot avail him. The wrong complained of is not that he concealed his contract, but that he made the contract; not that he pretended still to seek a franchise, but that he sold himself out, and, doing so, defeated competition, shut the city council in to but one bidder, deprived the public of that contention among bidders which would protect the public from loss, and secure the highest price for the sale of the franchise. This is not a case in which a court of equity should interfere, and the decree of the circuit court should be affirmed, without prejudice, however, to
The CIRCUIT JUSTICE concurred in the result, on the ground that the remedy of the complainant, if any, was at law.
In this conclusion, also, SIMOHTOH, Circuit Judge, concurred.
Dissenting Opinion
I dissent. Hyer and Shield were rival promoters, each seeking from the city council of Richmond a franchise for a street railway on Broad street, and both looked to Stewart, a banker in Hew York, for the money to carry out the enterprise. Hyer had already obtained a franchise from the council, and was asking for some amendments thereto. Stewart, fearing that the continued rivalry might result in the defeat of both, or in the obtaining of a franchise of such nature that capital would not embark in it, advised the parties to come together, and they united in an agreement for mutual co-operation, and for an equal division of whatever profits were realized. The agreement does not, on its face, bear any of the indicia which mark a dishonest purpose. It does not show, nor can it be reasonably inferred, that any sinister, extraneous, or corrupting influences were to be brought to bear upon the city council of Richmond to superinduce the granting of the franchise, nor is it alleged that any improper means were to be used to accomplish it, and thus it is cleanly distinguished from all that class of cases where the courts have held contracts void as reeking with corruption, such as using official influence for private gain, securing public office for pay, retiring from competitive candidacy under agreements to divide fees, securing public contracts upon like terms, or bargains for lobbying services to influence legislation. Hone of those elements enter here, and the sole ground upon which the decision rests is that the agreement was calculated to diminish competition for the obtaining of the franchise. It is not contended, nor can it be assumed, that Hyer or Shield, either or both, had such control or monopoly of the building of street railways that they could, by combination, put up the price, or demand an unusual or unreasonable franchise, or embarrass the city of Richmond, and thus injure or jeopardize the public interest, either by their action or nonaction. A rule that might be justly applicable to a kind of business which could not be restrained to any extent whatever without prejudice to the public interest ought not to be arbitrarily extended so as to interfere with that freedom of contract which is a fundamental right. The franchise in question was not a thing that was put up at public auction, and bound to go to the lowest bidder, where a combination to chill the bidding might be held to be in contravention of the public interest. The city council of Richmond, faithful, as it must be assumed, to its obligations to the public, was not bound to give the franchise to this or any other combination except upon such terms as it chose to annex, and there was no agreement for any corrupting influences to affect its action. An honest co-operation between two parties to effect an
The extent to which the doctrine of invalidating contracts of this nature may be safely carried is not clearly defined, and there is no immutable standard by which, this rule is to be tested. Within it are clearly embraced all cases of fraudulent acts, and all combinations having for their object the stifling of fair competition at bid-dings with the design to become purchasers at a price less than the fair value of the property, but combinations for mutual convenience, with a view to enable parties to do in common what neither could do individually and which do not disclose a dishonest purpose, are as clearly not within the rule. Courts must determine each case according to its peculiar facts and circumstances, and can only determine rightly when those circumstances are considered in their relation to the reason and grounds of the rule. In Atcheson v. Mallon, 43 N. Y. 147, the case cited in support. of the adverse view,. Justice Folger says:
“But a joint proposal, the result of honest co-operation, though it might prevent the rivalry of the parties, and thus lessen competition, is not an act forbidden by public policy. Joint adventures are allowed. They are public and. avowed, and not secret. The risk, as well as the profit, is joint, and openly assumed. The public may obtain at least the benefit of the joint responsibility and of the joint ability to do the service. The public agents know then all that*848 there is in the transaction, and can more justly estimate the motives of the bidders, and weigh the merits of the bid.”
That Hyer and Shield had made this agreement was no secret. The fact was published in the newspapers in Richmond on the afternoon before the city council passed the ordinance granting the franchise, and we have no complaint from that city—from the party supposed to be injuriously affected—that the suppression of competion has induced the granting of a franchise not duly regardful of the public interests. The bill states that it was Hyer’s intention to lay the whole matter of this agreement before the city council, and there is no ground for the suspicion that there was any concealment. I have not thought it necessary to consider carefully the effect upon this contract of the rule stated by Lord Cottenham in Sharp v. Taylor, 2 Phil. Oh. 801, and approved in McBlair v. Gibbes and Brooks v. Martin and other cases in this country, although I am inclined to the opinion that the doctrine there announced is directly applicable. Here the contract to obtain the franchise which is held to be illegal has been consummated, the franchise has been obtained, the aid of the court is not sought to enforce it, nor can the franchise be in any manner affected by what it may do; the transaction alleged to be illegal is completed and closed; one of the parties is in possession of all the fruits, and the other seems to me to be entitled to recover in an appropriate action his share of the realized profits. Public policy requires that men should perform their contracts, and they ought not to be allowed to evade their obligation upon vague and shadowy grounds. If this were a proceeding on the part of the city of Richmond to vacate the charter on the ground that it was obtained by any corrupt practices, or by the suppression of fair competition, the court should lend attentive ear to every suggestion of improper conduct on the part of the promoters; but the judicial conscience should not be awakened for the protection of one who seeks to avoid a ■contract of his own seeking on the ground that it was immoral, and therefore that he has the right to make off with the swag. Those who have legitimately invested their brains and capital in this enterprise of public utility should not be harassed by the injunctions and other processes which would impede its successful consummation, but the plaintiff is, in my opinion, entitled to an accounting and to a share of the profits realized by his co-promoter, and the bill, limited in its scope to that object, should be retained.