160 Ga. 620 | Ga. | 1925
The issue as to whether the covenant is reasonable was properly considered by the auditor as a question of law, and he properly made a finding of law on that question. It was error for the court to rerefer that issue to the auditor with the direction to make a finding of fact; and the court also erred, after the auditor had filed his finding of fact on that question, in submitting such finding to the jury for determination. From the earliest times in England down to the present time in this country, courts have uniformly ruled that the reasonableness of such a covenant 'is a question for the court to determine, and not for the jury. Where there has been a breach of such a covenant and the suit is for damages by reason of the breach, this presents an issue of fact which must be submitted to a jury. In Dowden v. Pook, 1 K. B. 45, at page 50, the Master of the Rolls, discussing the question whether the jury could decide the reasonableness of such a covenant, said: “It appears to me that from a very early stage down to the present time that question has really always been treated as being one for the court, and not for the jury. It is in .my opinion a question of law. No doubt there may be matters of fact forming elements in the determination of the question which, if they are in dispute, may have to be ascertained through the medium of a jury; but it is beyond their province to determine whether the restriction imposed is reasonable or not.” In Malian
In Tarr v. Stearman, 264 Ill. 110 (5) (105 N. E. 957), it was ruled: “Whether a contract in restraint of trade is reasonable or contrary to public policy, and whether there is an adequate consideration to support it, are questions for the court.” In Pierce v. Bandolph, 12 Texas, 290, it was held: “It was error to submit to the jury the question whether a contract is contrary to public policy; that is a question of law for the courts to decide.” The question in the last-cited case was as to the validity of a note “put up as a forfeit in case of failure to run a horse-race.” Error was assigned on the charge of the court to the effect “that if the jury believed that the note was given as a forfeit on the running of a horse-race and that such races are immoral in their tendency and
“Whether an agreement is in restraint of trade is a question for the court.” Knight v. Jillson, 172 Ind. 27 (87 N. E. 823). However, the Civil Code (1910), § 5422, provides: In an equitable cause, “when any question of fact is involved, the same shall be decided by a jury.” This is an equitable cause. It is in no sense a suit at law. Though an alleged breach of contract forms the basis of the suit, injunction, and not damages, is sought. It is elementary that it is the province of the court to construe all contracts, where no question of ambiguity is involved. This contract is plain, explicit, and unambiguous. The contrary is not suggested. The restrictive covenant is ancillary to the contract of sale. The defendants admit the execution of the covenant, but deny its
The auditor found as a matter of law that the contract in respect to territorial limitation was reasonable. This is the controlling question in the case. When the case was before us on the former occasion it was held that the contract was not void on the ground that it was in restraint of trade and contrary to public policy, “if such covenant is reasonable,” and the issue before the court when the case was returned for final trial was whether the contract was reasonable. The contract in fact provided a time limitation. Where such a contract is limited as to place, and reasonable in other respects, it is valid although unlimited as to time. Goodman v. Henderson, 58 Ga. 567, 569; Swanson v. Kirby, 98 Ga. 586 (2) (26 S. E. 71). Our Civil Code (1910), § 4253, provides that “a contract which is against the policy of the law can not be enforced; such are . . contracts in general in restraint of trade.” Obviously this contract does hot fall within the precise terms of that section. It is in partial restraint of trade. Such contracts are not void. They are not against public policy, provided they are reasonable. Such was the decision of this court with regard to this contract, thus fixing the law of the case in this respect. But what is meant by the word “reasonable,” and by what standard or standards must it be determined whether the contract is “reasonable?” When we come to analyze that question we find that there is but a single ground upon which such a contract may be held unreasonable. That ground is whether the contract unduly burdens the public interest, and thus at last we find that public
“Public policy requires that every man shall be at liberty to work for himself, and shall not be at liberty to deprive himself or the State of his labor, skill, or talent by any contract that he enters into. On the other hand, public policy requires that when a man has by skill, or by any other means, obtained something which he wants to sell, he should be at liberty to sell it in the most advantageous way in the market; and in order to enable him to sell it advantageously in the market, it is necessary that he should be able to preclude himself from entering into competition with the purchaser. In such a case, the same public policy that enables him to do this does not restrain him from alienating that which he wants to alienate, and therefore enables him to enter into any stipulation which, in the judgment of the court, is not unreasonable, having regard to the subject-matter of the contract. There are several reasons for upholding a covenant on the part of the vendor in all such cases to desist from the business in competition with the purchaser, which do not obtain in other cases. In the first place, the restraint is partial in the sense that it covers only the time and locality during and in which the vendee carries on the business purchased, and beyond these limitations the seller is at liberty to carry on the same business. Then, too, the vendor receives an equivalent for his partial abstention from that-business, in the increased price paid him for it on account of his covenant; and his entering into and observance of the covenant not only do not tend to his pauperization to the detriment of the public, but on the contrary, by securing to him the full value of his business and its good will, a value which he has an absolute right to secure in this way, the covenant operates to his affirmative pecuniary benefit and against his impoverishment, in that, while being paid for desisting from the particular business in the locality covered by it, he may still enter upon other pursuits of gain in the same locality or upon this one in other localities. Finally, while such covenants preclude the competition of the covenantor, it
This court has dealt with contracts in partial restraint of trade in a number of cases. Among them are the following: Brewer v. Lamar, 69 Ga. 656 (47 Am. R. 766); Rakestraw v. Lanier, 104 Ga. 188 (supra); McAuliffe v. Vaughan, 135 Ga. 852 (70 S. E. 322, 33 L. R. A. (N. S.) 255, Ann. Cas. 1912A, 290); Kinney v. Scarborough, 138 Ga. 77 (74 S. E. 772, 40 L. R. A. (N. S.) 473); Morris-Forrester Oil Co. v. Taylor, 158 Ga. 201 (122 S. E. 680). These cases contain able and elaborate discussions of such contracts, which renders it useless to discuss the numerous decisions and citations- found in those cases. The utter impossibility of harmonizing the conflicting opinions has already been recognized by this court. The law on this question has undergone constant evolution from the strictest limitations according to the earliest adjudications to the more and more liberal limitations according to modern adjudications. 6 R. O. L. 785, § 190. When the case was formerly before us it was ruled: “ Such covenant will be reasonable and proper if it only affords a fair protection to the party in whose favor it is made, and is not injurious to the public. 6 R. C. L. 798, § 200, and cases cited in notes 20 and 1; and where it is of such character, it may extend to all the territory covered by the business the good will of which has been sold.” Legg v. Hood, 154 Ga. 28 (supra). The same rule was stated in Rakestraw v. Lanier, 104 Ga. at p. 194 (supra); Shirk v. Loftis, 148 Ga. 500, 504 (97 S. E. 66); 2 Page on Contracts, 1377, and collection of authorities cited and classified by States. Mr. Page states further that the test is to be applied according to the circumstances of the contract, and is not to be arbitrarily limited by boundaries of time and place; and that where this view is enter
In Anchor Electric Co. v. Hawkes, 171 Mass. 101 (50 N. E. 509, 41 L. R. A. 189, 68 Am. St. R. 403), it was said: “The changes in the methods of doing business, and the increased freedom of communication which have come in recent years, have very materially modified the view to be taken of particular contracts in reference to trade. The comparative ease with which one engaged in business can turn his energies to a new occupation if he contracts to give up his old one makes the hardship of such a contract much less for the individual than formerly, and the commercial opportunities which open the markets of the world to the merchants of every country leave little danger to the community from an agreement of an individual to cease to work in a particular field. . . Arbitrary rules which were originally well founded have thus been made to yield to changed conditions, and underlying principles are applied to existing methods of doing business.” This rule, however, is broader than the rule adopted in this State.
In considering a covenant such as we now have for consideration, in the case of Hall Mfg. Co. v. Western Steel & Iron Works, 227 Fed. 588 (L. R. A. 1916C, 620, 142 C. C. A. 220), the court said: “In this case, and in all of the kind, two public interests are to be balanced against the one that is opposed to restrictive covenant: Honesty and fidelity among our business men; and the interest of every one, and so of all, in being able to sell on the most advantageous terms whatever property he owns or has produced, whether tangible or intangible. Unless injury to the public manifestly outweighs the public policies of honesty and of freedom of alienation, restrictive covenants should be enforced. . . Freedom of alienation is a byword, if appellee may sell ^property, retain the proceeds, and then repossess itself of the property with impunity. And what injury to the public was done that preponderates over honesty and freedom of alienation in the other scale?” In the Fleckenstein case, supra, it was said: “It is of public interest that every one may freely acquire and sell and transfer property and property rights. A tradesman, for example, who has engaged in a manufacturing business, and has purchased land, installed a plant, and acquired a trade connection and good will thereby, may sell his property and business, with its good will. It is of public interest that he shall be able to make such a sale at a fair price, and that his purchaser shall be able to obtain by his purchase that which he desired to buy. Obviously, the only practical mode of accomplishing that purpose is by the vendor’s contracting for some restraint upon his acts, preventing him from engaging in the same business in competition with that which he has sold. Trenton Potteries Co. v. Oliphant, [supra]. . . As was said by Lord Macnaghten in Nordenfelt v. Maxim Nordenfelt Guns & Ammunition Co., A. C. 573, in speaking of a case like the present, it seems almost absurd to talk of public policy in connection with such a case. It is a public scandal when the law- is forced to uphold a dishonest act; and the public suffers no injury in being deprived of the privilege of dealing with a man who is carrying on his business in violation of his solemn engagement not to do so.”
In deciding whether such a contract is reasonable the court will look to the whole subject-matter of the contract, the kind and
There was no substantial conflict in the evidence before the
The remaining headnotes do not require elaboration.
Judgment on the mam bill of exceptions reversed; on the cross-bill affirmed.