Hobart v. City of Detroit

17 Mich. 246 | Mich. | 1868

Cooley Ch. J.

The complainant seeks to enjoin the collection of a tax levied upon a lot owned by him for the purpose of paying the expense of paving in front of it with the Nicholson *252pavement; alleging, as ground of injunction, that the contract for such pavement was illegal, and therefore invalid.

The question of validity arises upon the folloAving facts: The City Charter, chap. 8, %1%, provides as folloAVs: “No contract for the purchase of any real estate, or for the construction of any public building, seAver, paving, graveling, planking, Macadamizing, or for the construction ' of any public work whatever, or for any work to be done, or for purchasing or furnishing any material, printing or supplies, for said corporation, if the purchase of said real estate, or the expense of such construction, repair, Avork, material or supplies shall exceed $200, shall be let or entered into except to and Avith the loAvest responsible bidder, Avith adequate security, * * * * and not until advertised proposals and specifications therefor shall have been duly published in at least one daily newspaper published in said city, and for such period as the Common Council shall prescribe.”

The right to lay the Nicholson Pavement in Detroit, at the time this contract Avas let, Avas OAvned exclusively by the firm of Smith, Cook & Co., the contractors, who alone, therefore, it is said, could and did bid for the contract, and there being no possibility of a competitor, the contract Avas aAvarded to them on their OAvn terms. This circumstance of exclusive right, it is claimed, precludes the application of this provision of the charter to such a contract, inasmuch as the purpose of the provision, which Avas to se'cure open and public competition, could not possibly be accomplished Avhere there could be but one bidder.

The doctrine of the complainant leads to this conclusion: That Avherever, from the nature of the case, there can be no competition, the city can make no contract, hoAvever important or necessary for the interest of the city; since contracts, except by public letting, are forbidden by the express terms of the statute, and those by public letting are forbidden by an implication Avhich is equally imperative. *253And if applied to this case, however much this mode of paving may exceed all others in utility, it can not be adopted in the city of Detroit, or in any other city with the like provision in its charter, even although the proprietors of the patent might be willing to lay it on terms more advantageous to the city than those on which pavement of loss value could be procured.

To support this conclusion, we must import into the statute a condition which we must suppose to pervade its spirit, but which is not expressed by its words. The power Avhich the charter gives to the Common Council to cause the streets to be paved, is conferred by another section in very ample terms — the sole condition imposed upon it being the public letting of the contract to the lowest bidder. The courts, I think, should be very cautious about importing new terms into a statute in order to make it express a meaning which its words do not convey, and they ought, at least, to first make sure that they are not changing the legislative intent, and giving the statute an operation that the legislature never designed, and, perhaps, would never have assented to.

The benefits to be anticipated from the public letting of contracts, must vary greatly in the different classes of cases, according to the extent of competition that is possible or can be excited. If unskilled labor is to be advertised for, or a work which is open to all, and all the materials which are abundant .at regular market rates, it is evident that everybody may bid, and the competition be general. But if the work to be constructed require the constant attendance of a scientific overseer, or if some of the materials be scarce, and owned by a few persons only, or if the work be so expensive as to be, according to the terms on which it is to be constructed, beyond the means of most persons, it must be very apparent that in these, and many other cases which can be supposed, the same full benefits of competition are not always to be obtained, which are *254probable in the cases first supposed, and that the danger of monopolies and combinations will be proportionately greater.

It will not be claimed, however, that the city has not authority to let contracts in these cases; and even if two persons only are in position to become bidders, it would be conceded that a contract could be lawfully let, even though but one of the two should actually throw in proposals. The security of the city against combinations and extravagant contracts in such cases must rest in the power which the Common Council possess to reject any bid which they might regard as unreasonable; a- power which the legislature have evidently considered of some value, as otherwise they would have made the fact of lowest bid conclusive, and the execution of a contract in accordance with it compulsory.

It is very clear, therefore, that the courts can not step in and declare a contract thus publicly let to be void, because the anticipated benefit was not obtained from the competition, if any competition was possible. The statute has fixed a rule from which great benefit will be derived in many cases, and some benefit in most cases; and it has declared, in effect, that contracts shall be valid which comply with that rule. The rule is made general for the benefits that will generally flow from it; and the purpose is to attain those benefits wherever practicable, be they more or less. We cannot declare a, contract void on the sole ground that no benefits followed the application of the rule in that particular case, though the Common Council might have refused to enter into it, for that reason, if they had seen fit. And if we can not declare a contract void because of this result, neither, I think, can we do so because, beforehand, the result might be supposed inevitable.

The case was argued as if such a patent right was a thing which stood by itself, so that very few cases could be liable to the objection now taken. This, however, is not so. *255The objection would be applicable in any case where the city might have occasion to procure any patented machine, or to let any contract requiring the use of any invention secured by letters patent. It is true that in the case of machines of known utility, the market will generally be supplied at regular rates; but it frequently happens that one person, firm or corporation alone has them for sale, so that there is a practical monopoly, -even though some of the' machines may be in the hands of individuals who have purchased for their own use. Yet unquestionably other persons than the owners of the right may bid for a contract to supply such machines, relying, perhaps, on being able to obtain the privilege of manufacturing them, or upon purchasing them at the rates at which they are generally sold. Their contract would be valid, notwithstanding they might find it difficult or even impossible to perform it.

But it is sometimes the case that there is as complete a monopoly of some material necessary to the performance of a public contract, as of a patent right the use of which is essential. It might even happen with a common material, that at a particular emergency all that was within reach, or that could be obtained within the necessary time for the performance of the contract, would be owned by a single individual. In such a case, on the complainant’s theory, the public work must be suspended, however necessary and urgent. And as a monopoly in regard to any necessary article, however insignificant, would be as fatal as if it extended to all the material, injunction bills of this kind, I fear, would multiply upon us, to the great detriment of the city, since contractors, in making their bids, rvould be compelled to add thereto a sum sufficient to cover the risks of loss from delayed payments and from possible defeat in a suit in chancery.

But it is not, I apprehend, strictly correct to say that because the patented invention which must be made use of is owned by one person exclusively, therefore, no one else *256can be a bidder. Every one has a right to bid, and to take upon himself the risk of being able to procure the right to make use of the invention. Certainly the showing that Smith, Cook & Co. owned the right to put down the Nicholson pavement in the City of Detroit, does not go far enough to show that they alone could bid on a contract for that purpose. If that firm held the privilege of putting-down the pavement for sale at a regular price per square foot or yard, the opportunity to bid for a public contract would be as much open to public competition as for any other work requiring skilled labor. Eor aught we know this was the case; and we may well take notice of the fact that it is frequently by thus selling the “royalty” that the owners of new inventions expect to obtain their reward. The royalty acquires a sort of market value which becomes well understood; and all persons have the benefit of this market value just as much as they would if the ownership and right to control were of such a character that monopoly would be impossible. True, the owner may at any time withdraw the royalty from sale in order to drive hard bargains; but, if he does, the public still retain a security in the power to refuse to contract with him.

The theory of the complainant is that more than one bid in this case was impossible. But suppose, in point of fact, Smith, Cook & Co. had not bid at all, but several other persons, having first ascertained at what price they could obtain the royalty, had entered into a sharp competition for this contract, would it not have been demonstrated that not only was more than one bid possible, but that -the very benefits the charter designed to secure by the public letting had been obtained? And if this is so, how can it be said that the fact that a monopoly of the patent exists necessarily defeats all contracts to which the patent is essential ?

On the theory of the complainant it is easy to imagine cases in which the court would be placed in the remarkable *257position of holding contracts void on the ground that competition was impossible, and, therefore, the benefits of the public letting could not be obtained, when in fact there had been competition, and the benefit had actually been realized. I do not believe there is any mere implication of the law which can force us to this conclusion; and, to my mind, it is very clear that the legislature would not intentionally have so tied up the hands of the city authorities as to preclude their making use of new and valuable inventions. I am not, therefore, disposed to put upon the charter a forced construction to that effect, which its terms do not appear to me to justify.

I am aware of the contrary decision which, by a divided court, has been made in Wisconsin in the case of Dean v. Charlton, but with great respect for the reasons assigned by that court, I am still brought to the conclusion that the decree of the Circuit Judge was correct, and it must be affirmed.

Christiancy and Graves JJ. concurred. ' . Campbell J.

I am unable to reconcile the action of the city with the provisions of its charter. It may be very desirable to allow such a course to be taken, but the prohibition seems to me to be very clear, and if this case can be taken out of it, I do not perceive how, in any case, the citizens can be protected from the very dangers which this clause was intended to prevent.

The charter — Chap. 8, § A2 — declares that no contract for paving (or various other things), if for more than $200, shall be “let or entered into, except to and with the lowest responsible bidder, with adequate security, and not until advertised proposals and specifications therefor shall have been duly published in a daily paper.” The same section prohibits contracts with persons who are in arrears to the *258city, as well as some others, and forbids contracts requiring mechanical skill to be let to other persons than mechanics.

It can not be claimed that if the monopoly of the pavement in question belonged to a public defaulter, or to one who was not a practical mechanic, any ground of dispensation could be found. Yet the necessity for opening the door would be as great in that case as in any other, if the city needs the improvement. But it has not been deemed safe to allow a full and free choice and we have no power to remit any legislative requirement.

The clause in question can not usually create more difficulty where articles or processes are patented, than in other cases. The patent laws contemplate that things patented shall be offered to the public on equal terms, and so generally is this done that the rule of damages for infringement is governed by the price usually charged. And in most cases, therefore, improvements requiring the introduction of patented articles or methods, are as open to general competition as any others. But if a rigid monopoly is kept up, there can be no competition, and all the evils contemplated by the act are introduced. Instead of obtaining the work at the lowest price, it can only be had at the highest. price, which is supposed to fall short of prohibition. Instead of competing skillful workmen, those must be employed whom the patentees see fit to force upon the corporation.

Instead of choice in the quality of materials, it must accept such as the contractor is willing to engage for. And publication of proposals must be an empty ceremony when there is no chance for competition, and when the choice of the patented improvement is practically equivalent to a choice of the contractor at his own price.

The charter was designed not only to provide against extravagant prices, but also, (as is very clear from many clauses), to prevent the opportunity of favoritism and corruption in the Council. If there are several different kinds of paving, and only one is patented, the patentee, retaining *259his monopoly, would find it well worth his while to be liberal in inducements to select his plan, and could afford to be all the more liberal because he could recover back his outlay by enhancing his prices. But those whose bids were open to competition would, to say the least, stand on a much less favorable footing. While there is no reason for imputing any wrong motives in this case, and while I do not believe that many public bodies are open to these sinister influences, yet it is not to be denied that this is one of the dangers in the eye of the legislature, and I can conceive of no more fruitful source of possible inducements to corruption than the monopoly of paving the streets of a large city.

It must not be forgotten that while the adoption of a new style of paving may be convenient, it can never be necessary. No patent continues beyond a few years, and a city that is within fourteen years of the last improvement can not be very backward in progress. Moreover, the real merits and durability of a new pavement can never be fully tested very much before the term of privilege has approached its close. As each new plan is generally somewhat expensive, its adoption must always require some consideration. The cost of paving is never a very light burden, where property is unproductive, and falls heavily upon many who are not able to bear any needless charges. Those plans which have been tried and best known are apt to be reasonably economical. The charter requires these safeguards to protect the individual citizen upon whom this expense is charged, and nothing short of necessity can render it expedient to open the door to unchecked expenditure. I can not see any strong reason for assuming that if this very case had been presented to the legislature they would have found in it any occasion for qualifying their language, or for removing the restrictions which they have in terms imposed.

I think the case comes within the spirit as well as the letter of the charter, and that the injunction should be made perpetual.

midpage