Henry & Co. v. Northern Bank

63 Ala. 527 | Ala. | 1879

MANNING, J.

The deposition of J. I. Donegan was taken in 1872, several years before the trial of this cause, for the defendant, upon the statutory ground that the defense, or a material part thereof, defended exclusively on the evidence of this witness. — Code of 1876, § 3069, el. 5. At the time of the trial, in November; 1877, plaintiff made an affidavit, according to section 3079, that he believed the personal attendance of the witness on the .trial of the cause was necessary, and that he resided in Madison county; in which county the court was held. Whereupon, the judge made an order, and a notice thereupon was issued and served, requiring of the witness his personal attendance, to testify orally before the court; and he not appearing, the plaintiff insisted that, under said section, his deposition “must be suppressed.” But, it being proved by the family physician of said Donegan, and by his son, a member of his family, that his physical condition was such that his personal attendance at the trial would probably endanger his life, and that he was men*537tally imbecile (all of which was undisputed), the motion to suppress the deposition was overruled, and the deposition read in evidence. Plaintiff objected and excepted to the testimony, and to the ruling of the court, and here insists that it erred.

The legislation on this subject must be considered as a whole. Its object was to enable either party to take and secure in writing the evidence of an important witness in a pending cause, to be used on the trial, subject to the right of the adverse party to require that he should attend and testify in person before the jury, if then able to do so. In this instance, it was shown that the witness was both physically and mentally incapable of attending, and testifying in person. The object of the law would, therefore, have, been defeated by the suppression of his deposition, and there was no error in permitting it to be submitted to the jury. •

2. Nor did the Circuit Court err, in refusing' to permit the plaintiff, Henry, to testify that Donegan, the president of the Northern Bank of Alabama, at a time when he was interested in establishing a national bank under the acts, of Congress, at Huntsville, in 1867, admitted the liability of the Northern Bank to the plaintiffs, and proposed “to allow plaintiff one-half of his claim, provided plaintiff would take $10,000 of the stock of the National Bank of Huntsville, giving his note for the difference between what was to be allowed him on said claim and said $10,000, payable at twelve months.” Although Donegan “said nothing about buying the peace of the banjr” on that occasion (the Northern Bank of Alabama), it was not within the scope of his authority to charge it with a debt, by his admission. The management of its affairs had been committed, by the charter, to a board of ten directors. Debts of the bank might result from its contracts, or arise out of transactions with it, but could not be created by the mere admissions of its president, any more than its rights could be released or annulled by his unauthorized directions. — Spyker v. Spence, 8 Ala. 333.

3. A more important question remains to be considered. Plaintiffs, residing at Guntersville, in Alabama, had dealings with defendant, the Northern Bank of Alabama, in November and December, 1861, and the early part of 1862, during the war between the Confederate States and the United States of America. The only circulating medium then in use — that by means of which all the business of the country was carried on — consisted, in part, of the notes of suspended Southern banks, not redeemed or redeemable in coin, and much more largely, almost entirely, of the treasury-notes, issued to circulate as money, by the government of the Con*538federate States. These treasury-notes were promises to pay the number of dollars specified in them, respectively, when a treaty of peace should be concluded between said Confederate States and the United States of America. A currency so precarious, kept in circulation by the imperious exigencies of a period of .revolutionary turmoil, when a government newly set up, supported by large armies, and many millions of people, was struggling to maintain in these Southern States the authority it had seized from an older and stronger government, supported by larger armies, and more millions of people, who lived outside of the same territory, could not be otherwise than of uncertain and doubtful value. This fact was recognized by everybody. The paper in use 'as a currency not only had no intrinsic value, but its redemption ultimately was wholly problematical. But, being forced into universal use by the necessities of the times, it was contracted for, received, and paid out, as á substitute for money, because there was nothing else with which the functions of money in the transaction of business could be performed. As a consequence, the banks of the country were compelled to receive and pay out this currency, or close their doors, and cease to exist. If they had done the latter, the people would have been deprived of the useful agency of these institutions in collecting debts due from one to another, keeping their funds on deposit, and paying them out on demand upon cheques or orders.’

It was to do these things for t’oem, that plaintiffs availed themselves of the services of the Northern Bank of Alabama. They deposited in it notes, cheques, and other commercial paper, that it might collect and take care of the proceeds, and have the amount thereof forthcoming when and as demanded. They knew, also, that it could not make collections, in any other than Confederate currency; and this they authorized the bank to take for them, and engaged to take from it, under the extraordinary circumstances of the times, by not informing it that they would not do so. Mr. A. G. Henry, himself, testified that “when he drew said order on Ewing, McCrarey & Co., of $2,600, and when he delivered the same to said bank for collection, and when he remitted from Memphis said certificate of deposit for $2,255 22-100, on the Bank of Memphis, he gave the defendant no directions as to the kind of money” that should be required, and that “he supposed, if he thought anything about it at all, that it would be collected in currency.” Outside of public knowledge on the subject, the testimony shows nothing else could be obtained.

This suit was brought April 10th, 1868. The complaint *539claims, in tbe first two counts, $6,154.25, on an account stated; the first count alleging that the account was stated April 4th, 1862; and the second, that it was stated the 10th day of December, 1867; and by two other counts, subsequently added, the same sum is claimed to be due, for moneys had and received by defendant, for the use of plaintiffs, at those same dates respectively. There is no claim founded on a count setting forth the special facts of the case, or the particulars of any transaction. The evidence relied on by plaintiffs, to show such indebtedness, was the passbook they received in April, 1862, of defendant, and its account with them on its books, corresponding with the entries on the pass-book : by both of which, and other evidence, it appears that, with the exception of the first item of $120 in gold, all the others were of deposits with it, or payments made to it for plaintiffs, in Confederate currency. This was indicated also, and understood to be indicated, by the letter “C,” written in the lines with those items, as a part of the same. No demand was made for any payment, until a considerable time after the war was ended in the overthrow.of the Confederate government; and it is not proved, or pretended, that this currency then had any value.

Tbe circuit judge charged the jury, that “money” consisted (1st) of the coin issued or circulated under the laws of the United States; (2d) of bank-notes payable and redeemable in such coin; and (3d) of the paper commonly called “greenbacks”, and the notes issued under the laws of the United States commonly called “national-bank notes.” “In this definition,” he added, “I do not include the notes issued by the Confederate States during the late war, nor the notes of banks that had suspended specie payments during such suspension. Such might be circulated,- as a medium of commercial transactions, but were not money.” And he, in effect, charged the jury that, unless defendant bad admitted itself indebted in money, as thus described, or beyond the extent to which it had done so; or unless it had received money, or beyond the amount to which it had received money, as thus defined, — it was not liable to plaintiffs, according to the terms of the complaint they had filed in this cause. These instructions were excepted to, and counter charges, intended to obviate the effect of them, were offered, which the judge refus.ed to give; to which, also, the plaintiffs excepted. A verdict for $500, including the sum of $120 in gold, was rendered in favor of plaintiffs ; which they being dissatisfied with, appealed from, to this court.

3. The view we take of the case makes it unnecessary to discuss in detail the various propositions which have been pre*540•sented by counsel for 'appellants. They are answered, or obviated, by the conclusion we have reached, conforming to that of the Supreme Court of the United States in Planters’ Bank of Tennessee v. Union Bank of Louisiana, 16 Wallace, 483. During the war, the former institution forwarded to the latter, among other things, drafts and claims for collection, and a few Confederate bonds for sale; it being understood between the two, that the drafts and claims thus forwarded were payable only in Confederate currency, and that the same might be received for the bonds to be sold. Some time afterwards, in the year 1863, while this currency still had value, a demand was made by the Planters’ Bank, on the Union Bank, for payment of the large sum that should be on its books to the credit of the former. But, owing to the interference of General Banks, commander of the forces •of the United States then in New Orleans; payment was refused ; and a suit was, in consequence, brought after the war, in a court of the United States, by the Planters’ Bank against the Union Bank. At the trial, the plaintiff bank asked, among other charges, that the following should be given to the jury: “If the jury should find, from the evidence, that the defendants received Confederate currency on behalf of the plaintiffs, and entered it to the credit of the plaintiffs, on the books of the bank, and used it in their general business, the defendants thereby became the debtors of the plaintiffs ; and that the measure of the indebtedness was the value of the Confederate currency, in the lawful money of the United States, at the time the credits were entered and the collections made.” This instruction the court refused to give, but .it charged the jury, “that the measure of indebtedness for receipts or collections made by the defendants in Confederate currency, and used by them in their general business, was the value of. such currency at the date of demand of payment made by plaintiffs, and not at the date when such currency was received and used by the defendants in their business.”

The Supreme Court held, that this instruction was correct. “We do not;” says the opinion, “controvert the position, that generally a bank becomes a debtor to its depositor, by its receipt of money deposited by him, and that money paid into a bank ceases to be the money of the depositor, and becomes the money of the bank, which it may use, returning an equivalent, when demanded, by paying a similar sum to that deposited. So, also, a collecting bank ordinarily becomes the owner of money collected by it for its correspondent, and, consequently, a debtor for the amount collected, under obligation to pay on demand, not the identical money received, but a sum equal in legal value. But, it is to be observed, *541this is the rule where money has been deposited or collected, and when there has been no contract or understanding that a different rule should prevail. . . . The Union Bank became the agent of plaintiff, to receive and collect, not money, but Oonlederate notes or promises; and the obligation it assumed was to pay Confederate notes, when they should be demanded. . . . From the nature of the transaction, it is to be inferred, that the intent of the parties was, that the one should impose, and the other assume, only a liability to return to the plaintiffs notes of the Confederate government like those received or collected; notes promising to pay a like sum.”

There was ,no dissent from these views on the part of any of the judges. Having regard to the times and circumstances ; remembering that the regular government was expelled, and kept expelled, by another of paramount force, by which “the Confederate notes were issued early in the war, . . . and became almost exclusively the currency of the insurgent States; . . . and, while the war lasted, had a certain contingent value, and were used as money in nearly all the business transactions of many millions of people” (Thorington v. Smyth, 8 Wallace, 1); a contrary doctrine, one applicable enough in ordinary peaceful times, would be, in the highest degree, unreasonable and unjust. And so entirely do the views of the Supreme Court correspond with-the general understanding of the people of these States, that, as is shown by the evidence in this, cause, plaintiffs are the only persons of the numerous customers and creditors of the defendant bank, who became such in the same manner, and during the same period, and were such at the close of the war, that have insisted it should now make good losses of value produced by irresistible political causes operating upon the currency which only they were entitled to, and upon that of every other person alike.

4. It results from what we have said, and from the fact that, when demand was made by plaintiffs of defendant, Confederate currency had no pecuniary value whatever, that the judgment they obtained included all they were entitled to recover from the defendant. No benefit can accrue to them in this cause, by a decision of the other questions that have been presented, and we, therefore, refrain from discussing them. Let the judgment of the Circuit Court be affirmed.

Beickell, C. J., hot sitting.

' Note by Reporter. — On a subsequent day of the term, the following opinion was delivered :

*542STONE, J.

The uses of banks and banking institutions, in the commerce of the world, are too well known to require discussion. They furnish, without compensation, and without direct profit, a safe and convenient depository of the moneys of the public, not wanted for present use or disbursement. Their safes and strong vaults, for the safe custody of valuables, are preferred to the most watchful supervision and protection the most prudent man can exercise or bestow. So well known has this fact become, that trustees may deposit trust funds in banks of good standing; and if they do so, any loss resulting therefrom will be regarded as the loss of the beneficiary, provided the deposit is made to the credit of the trust account. — Story’s Eq. Ju. §§ 1269 et seq.

The war between the sections, commencing in 1861, produced, in many respects, a state of things rarely met with in the history of the world. The several States composing the Union had theretofore' existed under one common, recognized head. To the extent of the powers conferred on the Federal government, we were one government. Our lawful money, and money standard, were one; and, as a rule, money current in one State, was current in all the others. Commercial dealings between the several States were very large, and remittances from one section to another were mainly conducted through banks. Coin had alone been declared a legal tender, and the expense and inconvenience of its transmission had forced it to give place to the less expensive, less hazardous method, of remitting in bank exchange. The war changed all this. The States which attempted to set up a separate government, under the name of the Confederate States of America, must necessarily provide a currency for themselves. A colossal war ensued, which raged for four years. All great wars are fought on credit; and the seceding States, having at the beginning no exchequer, must, of necessity, rely on its bills of credit, to procure the sinews of war. Treasury-notes of the Confederate States were issued in immense volume, and very soon became the sole circulating medium within the Southern lines. Being issued, as they were, on the faith of a government whose existence was denied and resisted, and could only be maintained by the termination of the struggle successfully to the arms of the South, the value of such treasury-notes was, of course, contingent. Still, being the only circulating medium we had, they served the purposes of money. They purchased and paid for property of every description, were received in payment and discharge of debts, and, while they had life, answered all the purposes of money. They even discharged trust obligations, when received in good faith; and, when that cur*543rency perished in the hands of the trustee, for want of an opportunity to invest, or otherwise dispose of it, if there was no evidence of bad faith in the trustee, we have held that the debt is discharged, the trustee relieved of legal liability, and that the loss falls on the beneficiary. — High v. Snedicor, 57 Ala. 401; Horn v. Lockhart, 17 Wall. 570; Waring v. Lewis, 53 Ala. 615; Baldwin v. Hatchett, 56 Ala. 561; Hutchinson v. Owen, 59 Ala. 326; Van Hoose v. Bush, 54 Ala. 342.

During the war, banks, located in the Confederate States, were compelled to receive and pay out Confederate treasury-notes, or do no business whatever. The volume of such notes in circulation was very large — increased by the heavy depreciation they were constantly subjected to. Having so little purchasing power, it became necessary to make up in quantity what was wanting in value. A large per cent, of this immense volume of Confederate treasury-notes, amounting to hundreds of millions of dollars in nominal value, was passing in and out of the banks; and it is safe to conjecture that, at no time during the closing years of the war, was there less than hundreds of millions of this currency in the vaults of the various banks. At the close of the war, by the surrender of the Southern armies, the Confederate States, as a separate government, ceased to exist, and the immense volume of its circulation became valueless.

The rule is clearly settled, that in the ordinary transactions of banks, when they receive moneys on general deposit, the money thereby becomes the property of the bank, and the bank becomes debtor to the depositor for the amount, as so much money had and received; and any subsequent loss of the money, or destruction of its value, falls on the bank. The depositor is only a creditor; and if the bank fail, and be unable to pay its debts in full, he comes in only as a general creditor, and must be content to receive his pro rata of the assets. This, -we say, is the general rule. But, as we have said, our war was attended with uncommon results. Its end in our overthrow left us where we were before the attempted separation; citizens, and part and parcel of the same government, against whose authority we had fought in deadly conflict. For four years we had denied the authority of the United States government to control us in any respect — had denied that we were under the provisions of the constitution of the United States; and the Confederate treasury-notes were* issued, and put in circulation, to aid us in vindicating our claim of separate governmental existence. Being conquered, we wefb remitted to our allegiance to the government of the United States ; and the question naturally came up, in what light must contracts and transactions be *544viewed, which were based on Confederate treasury-notes as a.currency. They had been issued in hostility to the government of the United States, and must be passed on by courts of. the United States, or State courts acknowledging allegiance to the constitution of the United States. It was contended that, inasmuch as this currency was issued to aid in the overthrow of Federal authority in the seceding States, it was against public policy to uphold any transaction based upon it. Wiser counsels prevailed, and the courts adopted conservative rules, .which, while they vindicated the dignity and rightful authority of the Federal government, abstained from declaring void any contract or transaction which did not, in its direct aims and results, antagonize that authority. The issue of such currency, they held, was unlawful, because it was aimed against the Federal authority. Being in circulation, however, and the only circulating medium the people had, or could have, they were forced to its use by the presence and power of an organized force, having and exercising the powers and functions of government, and they were left without option in the premises.

Confederate treasury-notes must be used, or the people were left without money, or any thing to take its place. So, contracts between individuals, based on that currency, and having in them no element of aid to the Confederate struggle, whether executed or executory, were not held invalid on that account. — Thorington v. Smyth, 8 Wall. 1; Horn v. Lockhart, 17 Wall. 570. “The existence of a state of insurrection and war did not lessen the bonds of society, or do away with civil government, or the regular administration of the laws.' Order was to be preserved, police regulations maintained, crime prevented, property protected, contracts enforced, marriages celebrated, estates settled, and the transfer and descent of property regulated, precisely as in time of peace.”

Ours was a peculiar form of government, and the struggle and attempted separation raised questions somewhat novel. We had, and have, a Federal government, supreme, sovereign, and paramount, in all powers and governmental functions conferred upon it. All other powers of government, and they were many, were reserved to the States respectively, or to the people. Each was sovereign, within its appointed sphere. The object of secession was to renounce and throw off the Federal power, and only the Federal power. The power, jurisdiction, and autonomy of the secediug States, were not attempted to be changed. These were to be exercised as theretofore, with the single exception that they sought to establish a confederated union among and within themselves, independent of the larger and more comprehen*545sive union from which they attempted to secede. This being the case, it would seem that all legitimate acts of State authority and government, done in preservation of life, liberty and property, contributing to individual comfort and happiness, and relieving social wants and social necessities, should be upheld, so long as they rendered no aid to the attempt to establish a separate government; and such we understand to be the weight of the judicial rulings on this troublesome question.

But, in carrying out this principle, many vexing questions arose, and continue to arise. In theory, and in fact, we have all the while been under the power and restraint of the constitution of the United States. Such is the legal sequence of the result of the war. Contracts for the payment of money, expressed as so many dollars, were frequently entered into during the war, fixing a time of payment which fell due after the downfall of the Confederacy; Dollars have a defined value under the constitution and laws of the United States. Treating such contract as one for the payment of money, and treating the parties as governed by the constitution and laws of the United States, the promissor would be held to pay the given sum in current, legal money of the United States. But, when it was shown that' the contracting parties were domiciled in the section controlled by Confederate authority, where only Confederate currency circulated, the presumption arose, at once, that the parties did not probably contract in reference to dollars of the United States currency; and that presumption was made conclusive, when it was shown that the price promised, if exacted in the lawful money of the United States, would be, perhaps, tenfold the actual value of the property purchased. Hence, courts were compelled to hold, what was in fact the case, that the contract was made in reference to Confederate currency, and that the price agreed on was a Confederate valuation. But, from any legal stand-point, courts, recognizing the authority of the United States government, could take, Confederate treasury-notes- were not money ; and if money, they were a grealty depreciated currency. They were, then, either a depreciated money, or they were not money, but a commodity or chattel. Considered as depreciated money, the promise was to pay so much depreciated, or uncurrent money. For a breach of such promise, the measure of recovery is the value, in lawful money, of the uncurrent money at the time of the breach. The measure of recovery is the same, on the breach of a contract to pay specific chattels. — Moore v. Fleming, 34 Ala. 491; 22 Ala. 512; Bozeman v. Rose, 40 Ala. 212; McGehee v. Posey, 42 Ala. 330. But, *546at the time of the breach, the currency or chattel (Confederate treasury-notes) had ceased to have any value, actual or conventional. Applying the rules above, there could be no recovery for the breach of such a contract. The courts established, as the measure of recovery in such case, the value of the property which was the consideration of the promise; thus ignoring the express stipulations of the contract, and treating it as an implied one. — Herbert v. Easton, 43 Ala. 547; Riddle v. Hill, 51 Ala. 224; Erwin v. Hill, Ib. 580; Whitfield v. Riddle, 52 Ala. 467; Tkorington v. Smyth, 8 Wall. 1; Stewart v. Soloman, 4 Otto, 434; Hill v. Erwin, 60 Ala. 341. This ruling can not be reconciled with principles long established, but it was considered a necessity, to prevent gross injustice. Other rulings, growing out of the war, have been equally a departure from principle, but we will not enlarge this opinion by stating them. The cases of Myers v. Zetelle (21 Grat. 733), and Ferguson v. Lowery (54 Ala. 510), are strong and eloquent arguments in favor of generous, liberal rulings, in all cases where the results of our civil war, viewed a posteriori, have entailed a seeming liability on agents and trustees.

We have dwelt so much at length on these principles, not because they bear directly on the question before us, but because they demonstrate that well-settled principles of law, applicable to society in its normal conditions, must be departed from, when their enforcement would lead necessarily to a great and general evil. We have said that, at the downfall of the Confederacy, there had accumulated in the banks, in the natural course of dealings, perhaps hundreds of millions in Confederate currency, deposited and not drawn out. When the flag of the Confederacy went down, to be unfurled no more, that vast volume of a circulating medium became waste paper, representing nothing. A deposit in bank, while, as a general rule, it is attended with the incidents pointed out above, is nevertheless a peculiar species of contract. It is not like an ordinary ‘ bill receivable,’ but is classed as the depositor’s cash on hand. It is subject to his draft and control at any moment, and he is not expected to give notice of his intention to draw. The bank is expected to be at all times ready to meet its customers’ cheques, drawn on deposits, and its ■ credit is seriously impaired, if not ruined, if it fail to do so. It does not stand in the category of an ordinary debt between man and man, for money had and received. These considerations, if the question were for the first time presented, would cause us to hesitate long before declaring the bank liable for a deposit • which thus perished on its hands. We are glad the way has been blazed *547out for us by that distinguished tribunal, the Supreme Court of the United States. ¥e cheerfully follow the decision 'in Planters' Bank of Tennessee v. Union Bank of Louisiana, 16 Wall. 488, because, in our opinion, it leads to a wholesome and just result.

midpage