40 Miss. 530 | Miss. | 1866
Lead Opinion
delivered the opinion of the court.
This was an action of mdebitainis assumpsit, brought by the defendant in error against the plaintiffs in error, for the sum of $4,013. The declaration contains five counts. The first charges the defendants below, as bankers, for that sum of money deposited by the plaintiff with them, and which they promised to pay; the second is for money lent and advanced; the third is for goods, wares, and merchandise sold and delivered; the fourth is for money had and received; and the fifth is upon an account stated.
And with an aggregate amount of accounts due by defendants from 1st January, 1858, to May, 1862, each of which had been rendered,. 1,263 00
And with errors in inventory of drugs and books bought May, 1862,. 450 00
$5,888 00
And gave defendants credit for principal and interest to May 1, 1862, of balance of note of plaintiff,.$1,850
And commissions on bill of medicines,. 25 1,875 00
Balance due plaintiff,.$4,013 00
The defendants pleaded non assumpsit andpayment, and with the latter plea, filed by way of set-off, a note made by plaintiff and II. E. Sizer to the defendants, for $3,799.60, due 1st January, 1855, having sundry credits indorsed; and an account of goods received by plaintiff to be sold on commission for defendants, amounting to $1,000, and to the plea of payment the plaintiff filed the general replication.
The verdict was for the defendants for $218.37, and they moved to set it aside, and for a new trial on several grounds, which motion was overruled; and hence the defendants bring the case here.
The facts nf the case present several questions of great interest and delicacy, and involving principles of very grave importance to the people in the existing state of the country. Sensible as we are of the great, magnitude of these questions, we have maturely considered them, and now proceed to give the result of our deliberations upon them.
The evidence touching the several points presented is voluminous, but the substance of it will be stated as we come to examine each of them.
The first question for consideration is, whether the action, in
It appears, by the record, that the action was founded mainly on certain funds known as Confederate treasury notes, Mississippi cotton notes, and Mississippi (military) treasury notes, which the plaintiff had from time to time deposited with the defendants, as bankers, during the years 1861 and 1862. From April, 1862, to October in that year, these Confederate and cotton funds are shown to have been worth in the market from two to two and a half for one in gold and silver, and Mississippi treasury notes, due in 1863 and 1864, wei*e worth from five to twenty-five per cent, more than Confederate money, and in December, 1862, they were worth 'about ninety per cent, premium over Confederate money. But, during the time stated in plaintiff’s account, these several funds constituted the only circulating medium of this State, and the defendants, as bankers, kept the accounts of customers by crediting the deposits as so much of whatever kind of funds were deposited, and paid out the same land of funds. A general check was paid by them in Confederate notes, and, if other funds were drawn for, it was designated. It further appears that, in May, 1862, the defendants had on deposit, to- the credit of the plaintiff, in cotton monéy, $828.97; in Confederate money, $1,496.25 ; and had received of him $1,600 in Mississippi treasury notes, which last sum was handed to them by the plaintiff, in consequence of an understanding between the parties that the defendant would accept that kind of funds in payment of the note of the plaintiff, held by them and here set up as a set-off. After receiving this last sum, it appears that the defendants refused to credit it on the note, and also refused to deliver it back to the plaintiff. Their reason for this course will be hereafter considered.
As to the other funds, Confederate and cotton money, on deposit, the testimony is in direct conflict, as to whether the defendants, about May, 1862, or afterwards, refused to* pay the same to the plaintiff upon his demand ; the plaintiff stating the affirmative, and the defendants the negative. It would appear that the jury found that they did refuse to pay or credit the
On this state of facts, the court, at the plaintiff’s instance, instructed the jury as follows :
“ That if they believe, from the evidence, that the plaintiff applied to the defendants to apply his deposits to the payment of the note they held against him, and they refused to do so, and, on such refusal, that the plaintiff demanded that his deposits be delivered to him, and the defendants refused to deliver them, they are liable for their value at the time of such refusal.”
And the court refused to give the following instruction asked for the defendants:
“ 5. Even if the jury believe that Sizer demanded the return of his deposit of Mississippi military treasury notes, and that defendants refused to redeliver the notes, yet, if they also believe from the evidence that defendants have not, in any way, used said notes, or received any value therefor, then, in this action, Sizer cannot recover on this item. His remedy, if any, is not in such an action as this; and on this action the jury must reject that item from their verdict.”
These instructions present the question, whether the funds received by the defendants, under the circumstances of the case, can be regarded in law as money, to any amount, so as to support the count in the declaration for money deposited, or the other counts for money.
It is insisted, in behalf of the plaintiffs in error, that all or any of these funds are not money in law, but mere specific chattels; and that not hkving been converted into value in money by them, and not having been appropriated to their use, they are not responsible in this form of action, as for money.
Money is defined to be cash, that is, gold or silmer, or the
This principle, as applicable to bank notes, is settled in the leading case of Miller v. Race, 1 Burr. 452, in which Lord Mansfield says : “ They are not goods, not securities, nor documents for debts, nor are so esteemed; but are treated as money, as cash, in the ordinary course and transaction of business, by the general consent of- mankind, which gives them the credit and currency of money to all intents and purposes. They are as much money as guineas themselves are, or any other current coin that is used in common payments as money or cash.” That rule was afterwards affirmed and established in the cases of Grant v. Vaughan, 3 Burr. 1516, and Gorgier v. Mieville, 3 B. & C. 45; .in the last of which it was applied to government bills, and it has ever since been followed in England and in this country.
Not to cite the almost numberless cases in this country, in which it has been sanctioned, we will refer only to the language of Chancellor Kent in Mann v. Mann's Exrs. 1 John. Ch. R. 236, who says, that the term “ moneys extends to bank notes, when they are known and approved of, and used in the market as cash.”
But it may be said, that the rule cannot apply to depreciated government or bank bills — which are not equivalent to gold or silver in the market, though they may pass as the circulating medium — because they are not the true representatives in
The main reason why such notes are considered money, is that, by common consent, they pass from hand to hand as the representatives of value. They are promises to pay value, which, for public convenience, are received by the community on the faith that the promisor will be able to pay the sum promised, and that it will ultimately be paid. They are not the less the circulating medium and substitute for value, because they are depreciated when compared with gold or silver; for they may pass and answer all the purposes of a medium of exchange, notwithstanding they are known to be of less value, at the time, than gold and silver coin. In such circumstances, their real value is still governed in this country by the standard of gold and silver, because the Constitution of the United States, which recognizes nothing as legal tender for the payment of debts but gold and silver, always subjects their real value to that test. Still, they constitute the circulating medium of the country. For the most part, however, though they pass at their nominal value, yet property purchased with them or exchanged for them, in the course of trade, is obtained at a price enhanced to the extent of the depreciation; so that the price at which the article is purchased, and at which the money passes, is really the same in value as if gold or silver were the medium of exchange. Thus, if a horse could be purchased for $100 in gold or silver, but that ceases to be the general circulating medium and bank paper takes its place, which is depreciated fifty per cent, below gold or silver, the same horse cannot be bought for less than $200 in the circulating, medium. The horse is really worth uo more at one price than at the other, $100, which is the real value of the bank paper for which he is purchased. But yet the bank paper is as much a circulating medium and representar tive of value, as the gold or silver. The only difference is, that the article is sold for a higher nominal price in one currency than in the other. But they are both the currency at the respective times, and therefore money, whose real value is to be ascertained by the test of the legal standard.
What shall be money is conventional, and is chiefly governed by natural and artificial causes proceeding from the state of trade and of commerce. By reason of natural causes, or of the exigencies of a country, or of over-action in trade, the circulating medium may, from necessity, be mostly in paper currency, to the almost, if not entire exclusion of gold or silver, and of course depreciated below that standard. This has been frequently exemplified at several periods in the history of the United States, when the entire domestic, business of the country has been transacted in bank paper issued by the authority of the States or of the Federal Government; when gold and silver as a general circulating medium had become rrtterly impracticable, and when nearly every substantial interest in the country would have been destroyed if bank paper had not been adopted as the circulating medium. To say that in such circumstances the rights of parties growing 'out of, and founded on the prevailing currency of the country, were not to be. considered as having been conducted for money, would be to take a very narrow view of the true principles affecting currency, to sanction gross injustice, and to ruin ail the important interests that had accrued from ,the necessities of the business of the country.
If it be true that depreciated paper currency is not to be-considered as money, then the amount of depreciation does- not affect its character, and the smallest rate of discount would
In the best state of currency in the United States, some six years ago, the notes of specie paying-banks in the Southern and Western States were depreciated in New York to the extent of the cost of exchange between that city and the place where the particular bank was located — say Nashville or New Orleans. Suppose a merchant in New York had received for his customer in Nashville, a sum of money in the notes of one of the Nashville banks, then at par there, but at a discount of from one to five per cent, in New York, and had failed to pay it without justification until the close of the war, when the bank proved to be insolvent — could it be said, for a moment, that the merchant in New York had not received money, and that the customer could not recover the value of the notes in New York at the time, as money had and received ? Certainly not; and the same principle appears to apply when the depreciation is great, provided the funds received were current as the ordinary' circulating medium at the time they were received or when default was made. If this be not true, no paper currency can have the character in law of money, unless it be convertible into gold or silver at the time, and especially if it be at a considerable discount, however universally it may be the medium of all the pecuniary business of the country, and however constraining the necessity which caused its adoption as such.
The present condition of the currency furnishes a forcible illustration of the subject. The United States treasury notes and national bank currency are at a discount of near fifty per cent, below gold or silver, and have been more than two hundred per cent, below par during the war, and they are not redeemed at par in gold or silver. Yet they pass generally as the circulating medium; and can there be a doubt that a person receiving such funds for another would be liable for the value of the notes in gold or silver, as for money had and received ?
But this can scaraely be considered an open question in this court. For several years after the financial explosion of 1837, the currency of this State consisted almost entirely of our own bank
Borméll v. Oovmgton was an action of assumpsit on a note payable “in the notes of either of the banks of Natchez or of the Union Bank,” which it appears were depreciated; and.it was held that the plaintiff was entitled to recover the value of the bank notes at the maturity of the note (I How. 322). Of the same character is Abbott v. Agricultural Bank, 11 S. & M. 405. In these cases the objection does not appear to have been directly raised that the depreciated notes were not money, and that, therefore, the paper sued on was not a promissory note. But that point was distinctly made and urged in the cases of Gordon v. Parker, 2 S. & M. 485, and Scott v. Hamblen, 3 Ib. 285; both of which were actions of assumpsit on notes payable, the one in “Brandon money” and the other in “ Citizens’Bank funds,” which, it appears, were depreciated at the time. The notes were sued on as promissory notes for money, and the actions were sustained, notwithstanding the objections here urged; and it was held that the plaintiffs were entitled to recover the value of the depreciated bank notes in gold or silver. These cases appear to be decisive of the question in this court.
We think, therefore, there was no error in giving the instruction for the-plaintiff, or in refusing that asked for the defendants.
The next ground of error insisted on, arises on the fifth instruction given at the instance of the plaintiff below, as follows :
“ If the jury believe that Sizer obtained the $1,600 of treasury notes from Allen to pay Green with, on an understanding with ' Allen that, if Green would not take them, they should be*548 returned to Allen, and tbat Sizer was prevented from returning them to Allen by Green’s retention of them, and tbat thus Sizer lost $1,600 of tbe indebtedness of Allen to bim, then tire Greens are liable for tbe whole of tbe $1,600, in gold or silver.”
Tbe evidence in tbe record in relation to this cptestion is, in substance, tbat Sizer was desirous to pay tbe note be owed tbe defendants, and conferred with J. Green on tbe subject, who agreed to receive payment in those funds, if be would pay tbe whole note. There is a discrepancy in tbe statements of tbe parties as to tbe date of this transaction; Sizer testifying tbat it was, as be thinks, in November, 1862, and Green testifying positively tbat it took place in April, 1862. Tbe latter statement appears, by other circumstances, to be correct. It appears tbat one Allen was indebted to Sizer, in a note for gold or silver, and tbat, shortly after this interview with Green, Sizer called on Allen and got from bim $1,600, in Mississippi treasury notes, which be agreed to credit on tbe note of Allen, provided be could use them towards the payment of his note to Green; and, if he could not so use them, Sizer was to return the notes to Allen. Sizer then took these notes to tbe banking bouse of tbe defendants, and delivered them to J. Green as a special deposit, and they were so entered by Green on tbe banking books. A few days thereafter Sizer came to tbe office of tbe defendants, and said be could not raise the balance of his note in Mississippi treasury notes, but proposed to pay the same with other funds — cotton and Confederate money — then to his credit with defendants; which proposition Green refused. Sizer states that he demanded that the $1,600 should be credited on his note, which Green refused; and that he thereupon demanded all his deposits, which Green refused, saying that he intended to hold them as a security for the note of Sizer. Green denies that he demanded payment of tbe other deposits, but admits that he demanded the Mississippi treasury notes obtained from Allen, and that he refused to deliver them, and retained them as a security for Sizer’s note. But they were not credited on that note, and were never paid back to Sizer.
It is again contended that in this form, of action, the plain
As to the plaintiff’s right to recover, in the form of action, it is above shown that he was entitled to recover, at all events, the market value of the funds. But a party may be entitled to recover more under certain circumstances ; and this appears to present a case of that sort.
It appears, by the evidence, that the defendants had agreed to receive the kind of funds afterwards delivered to them by the plaintiff in the payment of his note, and at par; and in consequence of that agreement, that the plaintiff delivered them the $1,600; that after receiving the funds they refused either to deliver them back or to give him credit on his note for -the amount, but kept the funds in their hands until they became of no value. Now it is clear that the plaintiff had the right, under the circumstances, to treat the funds as received under the agreement, or converted to the use of the defendants. Whether they were so actually used to the defendants’ benefit or not is immaterial as to the rights of the plaintiff. They had agreed to receive them at par ; he had paid under that agreement. If the agreement was not complied with by him in paying a part of the debt due in the funds agreed on, it was his right to have his funds returned to him when the defendants objected that the whole sum was not paid, as agreed on ; and by refusing to return him the funds paid, they became responsible as for so much money had and received for the plaintiff’s use, and they took the hazard of the loss occasioned by the subsequent depreciation of the funds. Otherwise they would be permitted to- take the benefit of their own wrong, and to cast on the plaintiff' a loss which had resulted entirely by their own wrongful act. Under such circumstances he is entitled to treat the funds as converted to the use of the defendants. The case of Pickard v. Banks, 13 East. 20, is an authority to show that in such a case the action for money had and received will lie.
The bill of particulars filed with the declaration shows a case of mutual credits between the parties, and the action was brought to recover the balance due the plaintiff. The defendants pleaded payment, and set off the note of the plaintiff in bar of his claim, and the plaintiff replied, denying the payment. This plea of set-off is, in law, a cross-action, asserting the defendants’ right to recover the amount of the plaintiff’s note set up in the plea. Upon a general traverse of that demand — which was the legal effect of the plaintiff’s replication — the question is, what sum were the defendants entitled to recover in their cross-action. In determining that question, it is clear that the plaintiff’ was entitled to credit for all that he had paid on that claim; and, if. it appeared that the plaintiff had paid certain funds which the defendants had received in consequence of an agreement between them, and which were retained, and refused to be returned to the plaintiff on his demand until they becaxiie worthless, especially if the plaintiff had to pay the full value at par of the funds in obtaining them, there cannot be a question that the plaintiff would be entitled to credit for the sum received by the defendants. For-, after the funds were paid, they were either the funds of the defendants or of the plaintiff. If of the former, they should have been credited as agreed; if of the latter, the refusal to return them on demand renders the defendants liable for all the actual loss which the plaintiff has sustained as the result of the wrongful detention.
Upon either of the above views the instruction was right.
We come now to consider the objections urged to the action of the court in granting thq fourth instruction in behalf of the plaintiff, and in refusing the jvrst¡ second,, and fowrth instructions asked in behalf of the defendants.
These instructions present for our determination the very important questions, whether contracts of an executory nature, founded on the consideration of what is commonly called Con
The argument in support of this view has been directed entirely to the power of the Confederate and State governments to issue the notes in question, in opposition to, and independently of, the rights and powers of the United States under the Constitution.
We do not consider it necessary in the present case to decide whether the issue of those notes by the Confederate and State governments rendered them valid in law, in point of the right and power of those governments, in the condition in which they were then placed, to issue them. That is a question of very grave moment, which we do not think necessarily involved in this case. The true question here is, whether, after they were issued and had passed into circulation, they could become the foundation of any legal right in the hands of a person who had received them in good faith and in the course of his lawful business, as currency, and upon which he could make a valid contract.
It appears by the record, that the notes in question consth tuted the only currency of the State at that time, and passed from hand to hand, as money, in the pecuniary transactions of the people; and that those received by the plaintiff, were received by him in due course of business as money, without any participation on his part in their illegal issue, and upon no consideration of aid, on his part, to the rebellion; that they were afterwards deposited with the defendants upon a contract,, express or implied, that they were to be paid back by them to
It is not pretended that these funds were, in fact, of no actual available value when they were received by tbe defendants, and were refused to be paid over to tbe plaintiff; and, on tbe contrary, it is shown that they were available to him, to a considerable actual value in gold or silver. But it is contended that, because they were illegally issued originally, they could never be tbe foundation of a valid contract in a transaction between private citizens.
Conceding, for tbe purpose of tbe present case, that tbe issue of these notes was an unauthorized and illegal act, yet it is so in but two points of view :
1. In setting up a power in opposition to tbe authority of tbe United States.
2. In giving aid and support to tbe military operations against tbe government of tbe United States.
As to tbe former, it is manifest that tbe conduct of tbe plaintiff does not bring him within its condemnation. Tbe position of tbe Confederate States, severally or unitedly, in opposition to tbe United States, was taken before tbe notes in question were issued. Whatever right or power they bad to set up a government independent of that of tbe United States, bad been already put into requisition. Tbe step bad been taken, and a government was formed, which claimed to be independent, and which proceeded, in point of fact, to exercise all tbe powers of a separate and independent government. And tbe issue of these notes was in tbe exercise of one of those powers. Of course, tbe plaintiff in receiving tbe notes, after they passed into circulation as money, and in treating them as such, could have been in no wise inculpated in any public wrong that may have been committed in tbe effort to set up an independent government, since that bad already been set on foot before they were issued.
As to tbe.second, there is nothing to show that tbe reception of the notes by the plaintiff and bis treating them as money, bad .any connection with tbe rebellion. Tbe notes were in circulation, and tbe medium of exchange in tbe private transactions of
But it is said that in receiving and passing these notes, aid was given to the rebellion, because they were necessary to the mamtenance of it, and that that object was promoted by receiving them in the private transactions of individuals.
This is an assumption which is not established. The bonds of governments, which do not circulate as currency, are frequently more valuable in the market than the ordinary currency of the government, or the other circulating medium of the country. This was the case with Confederate bonds during a considerable period of the war, and is now the case with the United States bonds. G-overnments usually conduct all their financial operations by means of loans, public securities, and other currency than their own issue. It does not, therefore, appear that the maintenance of the rebellion absolutely depended on the issue of this currency. But the policy of issuing the notes under consideration was intended in a great degree, on the part of the Confederate government, to supply a circulating medium for the country, in order that its domestic business might be carried on.
But whether this was the purpose for which the currency was issued or not, it, in fact, became the representative of the private property, debts, and contracts of out citizens, after it was issued, simply because, from necessity, these notes were the substitutes for value, and not because the citizen in receiving them was in any way actually implicated in giving aid to the
The error on which the objection under consideration proceeds, consists in not correctly estimating the office and character of a circulating medium. We have repeatedly said above that it is the representative of value. It represents property and stands in the place of it in the dealings of men; and that is its principal office. For it, the planter sells his cotton, the trader his stock, and the merchant his goods. It is the form in which value and property are estimated in such dealings. It is, therefore, entitled to the same benefit of legal protection in the contracts of individuals as the property it represents would be entitled to if the property had been exchanged in specie; and if the use of the property in such a transaction would not be unlawful, so the employment of the medium in the place of it would not be. Thus, if a man purchase a horse, and instead of giving a bale of cotton or a hundred bushels of corn for it, he gives so much of the circulating medium, in use at the time, as is considered of equal value with the bale of cotton or hundred bushels of corn, the purchase is valid unless it be prohibited by law. For the contract is as valid when one medium of exchange is used as the other, provided neither be in violation of any positive law or declared public policy; because in either form, it is property, and as such is entitled to protection on principles of natural justice. When there is no positive law forbidding the use of the particular circulating medium, and when it does not appear that the party in the act of receiving or using it, was engaged in any purpose clearly and positively in contravention of public policy, the act cannot be condemned as illegal.
■ We may test the legality of receiving and passing such funds, by considering whether the party would be guilty of any offense in law, by such acts. He would clearly violate no positive law, where there is no criminal participation; for he has only exercised his right over his private property as a citizen might lawfully do, without in any way involving himself in the existing war. If the act were done with the intent to aid the rebellion, it might be criminal on account of the intent, and he
These notes, then, stand on the footing of private property; and as well might it be said that specific private property, in this State, was not a sufficient consideration for a contract during the war, as to say that these notes, which were received without any illegal taint, could not form a valid consideration for a contract. Bor the private property of the citizen of the Confederate States was essentially the material resource on which the rebellion and the success of the whole cause depended. It was the source from which revenue, the sinews of war, was raised. It was impressed to supply military resources; it was used in every way that the exigencies of the cause required, for its purposes of civil and military finance; and it was the basis on which the resources of the war absolutely rested. It was under the actual power of a subsisting government; and whether rightful or wrongful, is immaterial, since the citizen was compelled to submit to its authority. It was, m fact, the potential government, which, for the time being, controlled his rights, his property, and his action. The same necessity and control gave rise to the existing circulating medium. The citizen was powerless to resist its operation. No one will contend that a contract, during that period, founded on the sale of a piece of personal property, would be illegal, because it was founded on that which constituted a part of the material resource by which the rebellion was sustained; and, upon the same reason, a contract founded on that which under the same exigency was the representative of the property, cannot be illegal.
If it be true that these notes were necessarily illegal and void in the hands of a bond fide holder for value, because they emanated from governments in rebellion, and having no rightful authority to issue them; upon the same principle, all hinds of personal property ever in the possession of the hostile government would be contraband in the hands of a subsequent
This war, on the 'part of the United States, was directed against the political status of the seceded States, and not against the private rights and property of the individual citizen. The right of such property was not disturbed by the war, unless it was actually seized and appropriated to the use of the United States, and the right of the owner positively divested. As a general policy, it was not further interfered with; and as matter of legislation, no policy, beyond that just referred to, was declared by the United States in regard to it. The private debts and credits subsisting between private individuals in their domestic pursuits, were likewise not the subject of the action of the government, unless they were actually seized and appropriated.
Since the termination of the war, there is no reason of public policy which demands that rights of private property, acquired during its existence, should be disturbed; and there are strong-reasons of justice and sound policy why they should be treated as fixed rights, and should have the- protection of law. As between individuals, this is consonant to justice; as to the government, it does not endanger the public safety; and as to society, it tends to promote peace and quiet among its members, by protecting private rights honestly acquired.
In the case of Dick v. Boylan, at this term, the following language is used by this court, and is pertinent to the question before us here:
“ In a state of war, the citizen being compelled to submit for the time to the party having the possession and .control 'of the*557 territory in wbicb be resides, becomes subject to its dominion ; his property and person are governed by its laws, and without regard to the international strife ; his private rights, under the municipal law to which he is thus subjected, must o'emain the same, no matterr what may be the resxbt of the struggle. * * * The subsequent resumption of authority by the form,er sovereign ca/rmot change the character of past transactions, or deprive the citizens of rights vested under the laws of the territory while it was possessed and governed by the enemy as their territory.”
By the result of the war, the notes issued by the Confederate government have become valueless, because that government has ceased to exist. But this does not render void private contracts made in good faith, and founded on them during the war, and having no connection with the rebellion. The principle is thus laid down by Rutherforth. Speaking of the consequences of the destruction of a State, he says:
“ The debts of a society are cancelled when the society perishes; and though the members, whilst the society subsisted, were jointly bound to contribute towards the payment of the public debts, this obligation will cease when the society subsists no longer. Sut the destruction of the society does not cancel any debts which the members of it had contracted as individuals upon their own primate account.” Rutherforth’s Inst., book 2, chapter 10, section 13.
It is the policy of governments to maintain the inviolability of contracts between individuals, because it tends to promote morality and public virtue; and the obligation of such contracts will never be interfered with, unless they manifestly appear to have been entered into in contravention of positive law, or of some high principle of public policy. But such violation will never be presumed.
The rule in relation to the validity of contracts which emanated remotely or consequentially from illegal acts, is stated with great clearness in the case of Toler v. Armstrong, 4 Wash. C. C. R. 297, by that eminent jurist, Justice Washington, as follows:
“ Does the taint in the original transaction infect and vitiate*558 every contract growing ont of it, however remotely connected with it» This would be to extend the rule beyond the policy which produced it, and would lead to the most inconvenient consequences ; carried out to such an extent it would deserve to be entitled a rule to encourage and protect fraud. So far as the rule operates to discourage the perpetration of an immoral or illegal act, it is founded in the strongest reason, but it cannot be safely pushed further. If, for example, a man who imports goods for another, by means of a violation of the laws of his country, is disqualified from founding any action upon such illegal transaction, for the value or freight of the goods or .other advances made on them, he is justly punished for the immorality of the act, and a powerful discouragement from the perpetration of it is provided by the rule. But after the act is accomplished, no new contract ought to be affected by it; it ought not to vitiate the contract of the retail merchant, who buys these goods from the importer; that of the tailor, who purchases from the merchant, or of the customers of the former, amongst whom the goods are distributed in clothing — although the illegality of the act was known to each of these persons at the time he contracted.
“ I understand the rule, as now clearly settled, to be, that where the contract grows immediately out of, and is connected with, an illegal or inymoral act, a court of justice will not lend its aid to enforce it. * * But if the promise be unconnected with the illegal act, and is founded on a new consideration, it is not tainted by the act, although it was known to the party to whom the promise was made, and although he was the contriver and conductor of the illegal act. Thus, if A should, during war, contrive a plan for importing goods from the country of the enemy, on his own account, by means of smuggling •or of a collusive capture, and in the same vessel should be sent goods for B, and A should, upon the request of B, become surety for the payment of the duties, or should .undertake to become responsible for expenses on account of a prosecution for the illegal importation, or should advance money to B to enable him to pay those expenses ; these acts constituting no part*559 of the original scheme — here would be a new contract upon a valid and legal consideration, unconnected with the original act, although remotely caused by it; and such contract would not be so contaminated by the turpitude of the offensive act, as to turn A out of court when seeking to enforce it, although the illegal introduction of the goods into the country was the conse; quenee of the scheme projected by A in relation to his own goods.”
This-able and lucid exposition of the law shows the true distinction between contracts which are illegal, and such as are legal and valid, when founded on, or connected with, an illegal transaction ; and states the rule to be, that, in order to render such a contract illegal, it must grow immediately out of, and be immediately connected with, the original illegal or immoral act, and not be founded on a new consideration; and further, that a subsequent sale of the subject of the illegal act after the original act is consummated, and a contract founded thereon, will be valid. It was affirmed in the Supreme Court of the United States, by Chief-Justice Marshall, in 11 Wheat. 258, after elaborate argument by distinguished counsel; and it has been repeatedly recognized by this court. Wooten v. Miller, 7 S. & M., and Kountz v. Price and Dixon, at last term.
This case appears to come fully within these principles. The contract here was founded on a new consideration, not connected with the alleged original illegal act, and- between new parties. No ingredient of an illegal nature is shown, except that it was founded on the notes illegally issued, as is assumed, but with which the plaintiff had no connection. ITe merely received the subject of the illegal act for a valuable consideration, and in the course of his lawful business, without any connection on his part with the act of illegal issue. This appears to be analogous to the case put by the learned judge in the case of Toler v. Armstrong, of a retail merchant who buys goods from the illegal importer, or of any other person who subsequently acquires aright to them, and founds a contract on them.
It is urged, that the plaintiff was bound to know that the notes were issued in aid of the rebellion and were void, and
The case of Kennett v. Chambers, 14. How. (U. S.), relied on in behalf of the plaintiffs in error, is not in conflict with the principle above stated, and is not in point; for that was a suit to enforce an illegal contract by the party who had done the original illegal act.
Again, it is insisted that the notes in this case stand upon the same footing as counterfeit notes, and are to be governed by the same principle.
. But the distinction is very manifest. Counterfeit notes are founded wholly in fraud, and are entitled to no credit or value. It is the deception alone that causes them to pass, and they are of no value, either intrinsically or in the market, by consent founded on a knowledge of their true character. But notes issued by existing corporations, and which are what they purport on their face to be, and are recognized in the market as money, have a value in fact, which gives them the character of money, though they may afterwards prove to be unavailable. This distinction is recognized in many cases, in which it has been held, that a payment in the notes of a bank, supposed by both parties to be of specie value at the time, but which were depreciated'in consequence of the failure of the bank to redeem its issues — which fact was unknown to the parties at the time of payment — was a valid payment. Scruggs v. Gass, 8 Yerger, 175 ; Bayard v. Shunk, 1 Watts and Sergt. 92; Lourey v. Murrell, 2 Porter, 280.
Prom the foregoing views, we are of opinion that there is no error in the action of the court below, upon the instructions under consideration.
In coming to this conclusion we cannot disregard the fact that a vast amount of the rights and property of our citizens depends on contracts founded on considerations like that of the case before us; nor can we overlook the circumstances under
Under such circumstances, to hold that all such contracts were illegal and void, and that the parties acquired no legal rights under them, would be alike contrary to settled rules of law and to sound public policy.
The next objection raised to the rulings of the ' court is that the Mississippi treasury notes were hills of credit, and void under section 10, of article 1, of the Constitution of the United. States; and, to the extent of the amount of them involved in this case, that they could not constitute a lawful consideration for the contract sued on. This objection is based on the authority of Craig v. State of Missouri, 4 Peters.
If it be conceded that, at the time' these notes were issued, the Constitution of the United States was in actual force in this State, and that the powers of this State were governed by it, in the peculiar circumstances of its condition at the time, yet it is clear that these notes are not embraced within the prohibition of that constitution.
They were issued under the ordinance of the State convention of 26th January, 1861, which authorized them to be issued solely on a loan of money to the State, and as evidence to the individual of the indebtedness of the State for the loan. They were not authorized to be issued as a circulating medium, and that was not the policy contemplated by the measure. That
A question appears to have been raised in the court below, as to the validity of the notes referred to as “ cotton money ” issued by this State, and as to the right and power of the State to issue them. But that question has been waived by the counsel for the plaintiffs in error here; and nothing we have said above is to be considered as an intimation of an opinion on that point.
The last ground of error insisted on is the sixth instruction given by the court at the instance of the plaintiff.
This instruction, as it appears in the record, is unintelligible, and some of the words of it would appear to have been omitted in transcribing it. As stated in the record, it declares no rule which could have misled the jury, or worked to the defendants’ prejudice. We cannot, therefore, determine whether the instruction as given was correct or not.
But, as well as we are' able to understand it, it appears to be immaterial, when considered with reference to the facts of the case and the verdict of the jury, under the view we have taken of the leading features of the case; and it could not have woi-ked to the prejudice of the defendants.
As stated by counsel, it had reference to certain accounts of the plaintiff against the defendants, severally as well as jointly, which the defendants had agreed, before the accounts were con
The objection to the instruction is, that it authorized the jury to allow the plaintiff for the aggregate amount of these accounts, although the particulars of several of them were not specified or proved, which the defendants were entitled to under their agreement, and which was necessary in order to enable them to adjust the several sums between themselves.
If this view be correct, yet it does not appear, and is not probable, that the defendants were prejudiced by the instruction.
It appears that the balance due the defendants on the 1st January, 1862, on the note of the plaintiff, after deducting credits indorsed, and $450 which should have been credited on the note for error in the original amount, amounted to about $3,103.
The value of the Confederate and cotton money at the value proved amounted to about. $1,100
The State Treasury notes at $1,600, and the accounts produced, $525,. 2,125
$3,225
The verdict was for $218 for the defendants. It is not clear
Upon tbe whole, it appears to us from tbe evidence, that there is nothing on this point in the verdict of which tbe plaintiff in error can complain.
Tbe judgment must be affirmed.
Dissenting Opinion
delivered tbe following dissenting opinion :
I do not concur with tbe majority of tbe court in tbe opinion that tbe value of depreciated bank paper, left on special deposit with a banker, may be recovered of him im, cm action for money had cmd recevoed Toy the depositor as money.
On tbe contrary, I hold, first, that under tbe count for money bad and received, nothing but wbat tbe law regards as money can be recovered.
Second. That the word money means gold and silver, or tbe lawful circulating medium of tbe country, known, approved, and used in tbe market as cash. . Coke Lett., page 207 (a); 1 Johns. Ob. R. 235, Mam/n v. Jfann’s Exrs.
Third. That bank notes in legal contemplation are regarded as money so long, only, as they re]3resent gold and silver. But when they cease to be tbe representative of gold and silver, and only pass from band to band, at a fluctuating depreciated rate, they are no longer regarded in law as money, but as a commodity, or property fluctuating in price, and not therefore possessing tbe quality of money as-a standard of value.
Fourth. That uncurrent bank notes, received by a banker on special deposit as such, and not on general deposit as money, cannot be recovered as money in an action for money bad and received by tbe depositor against tbe banker.
Sixth. That the refusal to receive uncurrent or depreciated bank notes on general deposit by a banker, is equivalent to a refusal to receive or treat them as money, which cannot be negatived by the fact, that some, or even all other persons may receive and pass them at a depreciated rate, in the absence of any other currency.
Seventh. That such special deposits cannot be construed into an agreement to receive or treat them as money, but is evidence of a contrary understanding. ■
I concur in the opinion on the other parts discussed and decided.