154 Mass. 92 | Mass. | 1891
The plaintiff and the defendant corporations, which had been engaged in litigation with each other as to the alleged infringement of a patent owned by the plaintiff, supposing the validity of the patent fully established, and believing that they would be able practically to control the profitable manufacture of fish glue, entered into a contract with each other by which the defendant was to pay a certain sum for damages, and one half of the costs of the suits, and was to be allowed the use of the patent. Each party was to conduct its own establishment, and they were to unite in the purchase of fish skins, an article of which the supply was limited and from which the fish glue is manufactured, so that there should be no competition between them. The "plaintiff was to fix the price of all skins purchased, and the parties were to have certain places assigned to them by two persons named, of which they were respectively to have the product. From the proprietors of certain other places mentioned the defendant was to have the entire product, and to allow the plaintiff to receive from it one third thereof, and the two parties were to divide equally between them the skins which might be obtained from new producers. They were both to sell the glue at the same price, to be agreed upon from time to time, and the contract contained other stipulations the effect of which was to prevent competition between them. The contract was made in February, 1884. After they had conducted the business in this manner until early in 1887, it became evident to both that the patent was invalid, although no formal judgment was rendered declaring it so. Thereupon, Brooks, the manager of the defendant company, made a large number of what are known as the long term contracts, for the purchase of all skins to be produced until the year 1900, with nearly all the producers of fish skins known to the parties. The plaintiff received its share of these skins, and no difficulty arose between the two' companies until early in July, 1890, when the defendant notified the producers of skins by whom the plaintiff had been supplied up to that time not to deliver it any more skins, and also notified the plaintiff of its abandonment of the contract. Until then the parties had gone along under the contract as modified by mutual
The original purpose of the contract was to regulate the business of manufacturing a product under what was supposed to be a new invention, on which letters patent of the United States had been issued, whereby an article then nearly worthless might be converted into an article of large value. The use to which the fish skins were put under this invention gave them their market value. The plaintiff and the defendant sought to unite with each other in the purchase of the raw material, so' that they might not be tempted to overbid each other and thus to raise it to an unreasonable price, and also to agree on the price at which the manufactured article should be sold, so that they might be secure in a reasonable profit. Even if they hoped for gain by their joint exertions, or by the possession of a patent as to the value of which they were subsequently disappointed, their contract had no relation to an article of prime necessity, or to staple commodities ordinarily bought and sold in the market, but to a particular article, of which both were manufacturers under the same process, and to an article used in the manufacture which was of little value for any other use. That the agreement was not obnoxious to the objection made by the defendant is shown by the case of Central Shade Roller Co. v. Cushman, 143 Mass. 353.
The next inquiry is whether the contract is incapable of en
If it should be held that the right to use the patent formed so large a part of the consideration for the defendant’s undertaking that, after the discovery of the mistake of the parties in this particular, a court of equity would decline to decree specific performance against the defendant if it had seasonably sought to avoid the contract on the ground of mistake, there are reasons why such a defence should not avail the defendant in this case. After both parties knew that the patent was void, the defendant still chose to avail itself of the benefits of the contract,
The next objection of the defendant is, that, even if it violates its contract, it is not shown that the plaintiff has not an adequate remedy at law. The only remedy which the plaintiff could have at law would be by a recovery of damages for the failure of the defendant to deliver, or to allow those to deliver with whom it had made contracts in its own name but for the benefit of both, the due proportion of fish skins to the plaintiff. It sufficiently appears that the principal market for them is in Gloucester, that most of the skin producers there are under contract with the defendant, and that fish skins are of very limited production. “ If the plaintiff is unable to obtain skins produced by firms which have contracted with the defendant,” it is found that “ it will be very difficult, if not impossible, for it to carry on its business.” This continuing injury, leading to difficulties in the management of the plaintiff’s business, and possibly to its utter destruction, is one that could not be measured in damages. It would be practically impossible to estimate the amount of the injury, or to repair it. The plaintiff’s property invested in the manufacture must lose a considerable, but uncertain, amount of its value. The injury thus threatened would be practically irreparable. Florence Sewing Machine Co. v. Grover & Baker Sewing Machine Co. 110 Mass. 1, 11.
It is urged that, if the plaintiff is entitled to any relief at all, it should be compelled to take its proportion of the waste as well as of the skins, including in the computation the waste and skins of George Perkins and Son. In addition to the fish skins,
The defendant further contends, that, if the plaintiff had a right to have the contract specifically enforced, it has lost it by
Decree accordingly.