62 So. 544 | Ala. Ct. App. | 1913
The reporter will set out count No. 5 of the complaint, Avhich contains a copy of the contract sued on and a statement in full of plaintiff’s case. Demurrers were interposed to the count, assigning numerous grounds, but were sustained by the trial court upon only tAvo of such grounds, which, in substance, may be stated as follows: First. That the count shows on its face that plaintiff is a nonresident corporation and Avas engaged in business in this state as to the
Since we are of the opinion that the second of the two named grounds of the demurrer is good, it becomes unnecessary to consider, and we therefore pass over, the first ground, confining our attention exclusively to the second, a decision upon which will sustain the lower court and completely dispose of the case.
Unlawful agreements — that is, those whose objects are illegal, and to which the courts refuse recognition and enforcement — may be placed in two classes, viz. (1) agreements in .violation of positive law, and (2) agreements contrary to public policy. Agreements in violation of positive law are those which are expressly or impliedly prohibited, either by some rule of the common law or by some express statutory provision, and which, of course, also necessarily amount to agreements contrary to that part of the public policy expressed in the particular rule or statute violated. — 9 Cyc. 466.
Public policy, however, is broader than the mere terms of the Constitution and statutes and embraces their general purpose and spirit. Constitutions are
It is settled that, while agreements in reasonable restraint of trade are valid, yet contracts or agreements in unreasonable restraint of trade are contrary to public policy and void, because they tend to the creation of a monopoly. — 9 Cys. 533; 27 Cyc. 891; Arnold v. Jones, 152 Ala. 506, 44 South. 662, 12 L. A. R. (N. S.) 150; Tuscaloosa Ice Mfg. Co. v. Williams, 127 Ala. 110, 28 South. 669, 50 L. R. A. 175, 85 Am. St. Rep. 125; Fullington v. Kyle Lumber Co., 139 Ala. 242, 35 South. 852; 2 May. Dig. 784; 5 May. Dig. 218; 6 May. Dig. 182; U. S. v. Trans-Mo. Freight Ass’n, 58 Fed. 58, 7 C. C. A. 15, 24 L. R. A. 73.
A monopoly, as understood at common law, was an exclusive right granted by the crown to one person, or a class of persons, of something which before was of common right, and which enabled the persons who possessed it to exclude others from the defined activities. —B. Ry. Co. v. Birmingham St. Ry. Co., 79 Ala. 471, 58 Am. Rep. 615. Without such a grant even then, the obtaining by combined action or individual initiative on the part of private parties of the exclusive power to carry on a certain trade or business, etc., and all attempts to. gain control of the market by forestalling, regrating, or engrossing were unlawful and punishable. —27 Cyc. 890. Ala. Political Code, p. 30, note. At a later time, during the reign of James I, there was passed an act of Parliament which by a general sweeping-clause demolished all existing monopolies, with certain exceptions, which had been before created by the crown, and declared them also to be contrary to law and void. —Status of Monopolies, 21 James I.
Monopolies were deemed odious at common law, not only as being in contravention of common right, but
Monopolies in their very nature are opposed to the genius and principles of a Bepublican form of government, and require neither express statutes nor constitutional prohibitions to make them illegal. — Bir. & P. Ry. Co. v. Bir. St. Ry. Co., 79 Ala. 465, 58 Am. Rep. 615. The inadequacy, however, of common-law remedies and common-law punishments for the purpose of dealing properly with modern trusts and monopolies, which in recent decades have multiplied freely, has led Congress and the Legislature of many of the states to enact drastic statutes against all trusts, pools, and unlawful combinations designed to restrain trade and prevent competition, with a view to the destruction of existing ones and the prevention of future ones by punishing their authors positively as well as still punishing them negatively by denying them the aid of the courts in enforcing their contracts.
Section 23 of our Constitution forbids the granting • of exclusive and irrevocable special privileges and immunities by the Legislature, and section 103 thereof, which is a provision new to the Constitution of 1901,. enjoins positively upon the Legislature the duty of providing by law for the “regulation, prohibition, or rea
Said section 7579 of our Code thus provides: “Any person or corporation wlm engages or agrees with other persons or corporations, or enters into, directly or indirectly, any combination, pool, or trust, or confederation to regulate or fix the price of any article or commodity to be sold or produced within this state, or * * * on conviction, be fined,” etc.
Section 7581 reads: “Any person or corporation, domestic or foreign, which shall restrain or attempt to restrain the freedom of trade or production, or which shall monopolize or attempt to monopolize the production, control or sale of any commodity, or * * * shall be fined,” etc.
The Sherman Anti-Trust Act makes illegal, punishing the parties thereto by fine or imprisonment, “every contract, combination in the form of a trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states or with foreign nations,” etc.
There being thus both a state and national law prohibiting unlawful combinations in restraint of trade— the one law relating to intrastate, the other to interstate, commerce — it is immaterial as to which character
The test which is laid, down for determining- Avbether a contract is in reasonable or unreasonable restraint of trade is: Does it merely afford a fair protection to the interest of the party in AAdiose favor it is made, without being so large in its operation as to interfere with the interest of the public? — McCurry v. Gibson, 108 Ala. 453, 18 South. 806, 54 Am. St. Rep. 177. Dealing more fully Avith this latter proposition, it is Avell said by the United States Circuit Court of Appeals, after reviewing the authorities, speaking through Sanborn, J.: “It clearly appears that when -the Anti-Trust Act was passed the rule had been firmly established in the jurisprudence of England and the United States that the validity of contracts restricting competition was to be determined by the reasonableness of the restriction. If the main purpose or natural and inevitable effect of a contract Avas to suppress competition or create a monopoly, it Avas illegal. If the contract imposed a restriction that was unreasonably injurious to the public,- or a restriction that Avas greater than the interest of - the party in AAdiose favor it Avas imposed demanded, it Avas illegal. But contracts made for a lawful purpose, Avhich Avere not unreasonably injurious to the public welfare, and AAdiich imposed nn beaAder restraint upon
From Am. & Eng. Ency. Law we cull the following-definitions, drawn by it from the decisions of the various courts, to wit: “While a monopoly, in its strict sense, is an exclusive right, granted by the state to a few, of something which was before of common right, yet the term, as now understood, is not confined to such narrow limits, but embraces any combination the tendency of which is to prevent competition in its broad and general sense and control prices to the detriment of the public. A trust is a contract, combination, confederation, or understanding, express or implied, between two or more persons to control the price of a commodity or service, for the benefit of the parties thereto, and to the injury of the public, and which tends to create a monopoly.” — 20 Am. & Eng. Ency Law, p. 846, citing the authorities'. “A pool is defined as an organization of persons or corporations formed mainly for the purpose of regulating the supply and price of commodities.” — 22 Am. & Eng. Ency. Law, p. 942, citing authorities. See also Words & Phrases, under appropriate titles on these subjects.
With these principles and definitions in mind, we will undertake an analysis of the contract here presented by dividing it into its component parts as to the things-done and the things agreed in it to be done, and consider each separately and then the contract as a whole,
The contract, as will be observed, is unilateral in form, being signed only by the defendant, and became a contract alone as the result of plaintiff’s acceptance of it, which presumably was done at the place at which it was signed by defendant — Penrode, Ala. — as its nature and form are such as to "suggest that the defendant’s signature thereto was procured either through the solicitation and instrumentality of a traveling agent sent by plaintiff, armed in advance with the contract, to see defendant, which is most probable, or by the plaintiff’s mailing from its headquarters in Atlanta to the defendant at Penrode, Ala., the contract for signature and return. It expressly binds the defendant to do certain specific things therein enumerated, to wit: First. To take and pay for one share of stock of the plaintiff corporation of the value of flO, payable 10 percent, monthly. Second. To make all car load shipments of peaches, grown by defendant, through plaintiff corporation, and pay 10 per cent, of the gross sales thereof as total commission charges for handling and selling same, to be divided, we infer, between plaintiff and the sales broker or commission merchant at the market to which plaintiff might direct defendant to make the shipment, and in such proportion as plaintiff and said broker, might agree. Third. To pay plaintiff a commission of 5 per cent, of the gross sales on all orchard and other sales f. o. b. defendant’s railroad station, which we construe to mean such a commission on all sales made by defendant to purchasers of the fruit on the trees and all such other sales as were made by defendant, but not through plaintiff, as required in section 2, herein-before enumerated. These several promises to plaintiff on defendant’s part were conditional, however, and were
For the share of stock the defendant, as seen, was to pay plaintiff $10, its full value, as stated in the contract, and for plaintiff’s services and those of its agents, the commission merchants, in handling and selling the car loads of fruit shipped through plaintiff, the defendant was to pay a total commission of 10 per cent, which apparently is an adequate quid pro quo in return for the service named. What consideration, then, was there moving defendant to agree to pay plaintiff 5 per cent, of the gross sales of all peaches not shipped or sold through plaintiff, and with reference to which disposition plaintiff performed no service, or for which commission he was to give no consideration in return? Could not the defendant ordinarily buy stock in most any corporation, either from the corporation itself or some of its shareholders, by paying its full market value, and without the necessity of promising to give in addi
The conclusion cannot be escaped that when plaintiff succeeded in getting said required number of peach growers, inclusive of defendant, each to become a member of its corporation or exchange and to execute a contract like that here under consideration, which plaintiff alleges it did do as the necessary averment of the performance by it of a condition precedent to its right to maintain an action on this contract, which, as seen, is so conditioned as not to be binding on defendant until plaintiff did do this — that is, did get at least 60 per cent, of the fruit growers into the association — plain
. Looking at the substance and not the form of these several contracts betAveen plaintiff on one side and these 60 per cent, of the peach growers on the other, who thereby became members of plaintiff association, it amounts to nothing more nor less than an agreement or combination betAveen them to place the disposition and sale of their crop each year in the hands of a joint agent, plaintiff, for the purpose of avoiding, as far as possible, competition among themselves, and thereby to raise the price of their products, and with the evident design and intent on their part and that of plaintiff, plainly contemplated in the contract, to get as many other groAvers into the arrangement as possible; it being both to their interest and to that of plaintiff, Avhose commissions would thereby be more, to do so.
In the case of Ford v. Chicago Milk Shippers Ass’n, 155 Ill. 166, 39 N. E. 651, 27 L. R. A. 298, the court, dealing with a state statute almost identical with ours and a state of facts similar in many vital respects to that here, though stronger there, said:- “Appellee,” the
This contract, and the like ones made by plaintiff with the other peach growers as the performance of a condition necessary to the life of this one, stifles and destroys, as seen, competition between at least 60 per cent, of the peach growers in the sale of their products, was designed for the purpose of enhancing prices, and contemplated the getting of as many other growers into the combination as plaintiff might be able to. The restraint upon trade is, of course, not so farreaching and the ability to fix prices not so commanding as it would, have been had all the peach growers, instead of 60 per cent., signed such contracts with plaintiff and become members of its exchange; but, so far as this restraint and ability goes, it is of precisely the same character ’ and produces the same class of results, and is subject to. the same legal objection. Courts will not
That such is the object and tendency of the present contract seems to us clear, and the judgment of the lower court is therefore affirmed.
Affirmed.