53 N.H. 276 | N.H. | 1872
This is an action of contract. To charge the defendant Stillings in this form of action, it is necessary to show, either an actual contract entered into by him, on such circumstances that the law will, by a fiction adopted for the sake of the remedy, imply a contract “ directly against the actual fact.”
Upon the findings of the jury, it is clear that there was no actual contract on the part of Stillings to pay for the corn; there was no engagement to that- effect signified, either by the words or by the conduct of Stillings. A “ contract in fact ” can be proved in only three ways. It must appear that the contract was made by Stillings in person, or that it was made by his duly authorized agent, or that he is estopped to deny the agency of the person making the contract. None of these facts exist here. It is not pretended that Stillings made the contract
This conclusion, however, is not necessarily decisive of the present cash. If the forms of common law actions were “ adapted to the truth of the case,” a defendant could not be held liable in an action of contract except upon proof of an actual contract, “ either express or tacit.” But, by a fiction adopted for the sake of the remedy, the .law, in some instances, allows an action of contract to be maintained to enforce a legal obligation or duty which the defendant has never in fact promised to perform. The law, in such cases, “ implies a promise,” though such implication üaay be “ directly against the. actual fact,” and even against the party’s strongest protestations.” See Metcalf on Contracts 5-10, 163, 164; Sceva v. True, Merrimack, June term, 1873. It becomes necessary, therefore, to consider whether justice requires that Stillings, contrary to his actual contract and intention, should bo compelled to pay the debts contracted .by the Clarks in running tlieir stage. An agreement to share gross returns might be of such a nature as to afford cogent, if not conclusive, evidence per se of an intent to defraud creditors. The present, however, is not such a case. It is to be noticed in the outset, that no fraud in fact is imputed to Stillings. There is nothing to show that the plaintiff put his claim on that ground at the trial.' For ought that appears, the arrangement was made bond fide, and there certainly was a valuable consideration. The obvious purpose was to prevent the ruinous consequences of competition. The results do not appear ; but it is by no means improbable that the share received by each party was larger than it would have been if -competition had been engendered by the absence of such an agreement. And if either party lost by the agreement, it does not appear that Stillings was not the loser and the Clarks the gainers. The case, then, presents an agreement, made in good faith and for a valuable consideration, which need not necessarily have operated to the prejudice of the creditors of the Clarks, and is not shown to have actually prejudiced them. Yet it is contended that the making and carrying out of this agreement is sufficient cause for holding Stillings liable, “ to his last shilling,” to pay the debts contracted by the Clarks, notwithstanding the agreement expressly provides to the contrary. This claim is attempted to be supported on the ground that Stillings, by taking a part of the
If if be argued that it is against the policy of the law to allow a man a chance to share in the receipts of a business without also sharing all its liabilities, the answer is, that the law permits such agreements as’ the present to have full force and effect when the stipulations are known to those dealing with the parties — see 2 Am. Law Review 7, 8, 202; and the intrinsic justice of this legal principle seems to be recognized by the legislative enactments relating to limited partnerships, “ which provide for the public record of the partnership limitations as .a method of making them known to third persons; ” — see, also, as to statutes, Kelly, C. B., in Holme v. Hammond, L. R., 7 Exch. 218, p. 227. It is only to secret agreements of this nature that objection is made; — see Bell, J., in Bromley v. Elliot, 38 N. H. 287, p. 303. So far as the creditors have been misled by the secrecy, it is proper that they should be allowed to insist on the rights which they were led to suppose they should have. They may well claim that, so far as they are concerned, the apparent position of the business and the property must be conclusively regarded as the real position. But, after they have been given every right which they had reason to believe they should have, why should they also be given a further right which they never expected, or had reason to expect, and which frustrates the real intention of all parties ?
Perhaps it may be objected that it will often be difficult to determine how much the secret sharer has received out of the gross receipts: but the difficulty can be no greater, and would often be less, than that ordinarily incurred in the winding up of a partnership, a matter of common equity jurisdiction, where it is necessary to take an account and decree a division of the surplus. Moreover, it cannot be for the interest of the secret sharer to withhold information as to the amount of his receipts, for all doubts on that point would be construed against him.
Stillings, by taking a share of the gross receipts, has hardly placed himself in the position of a devisee who takes a devise charged by the will with the payment of a certain sum. The charge in the latter case is absolute, irrespective of the value of the devise. Only one inference is deducible from the acceptance of the devisee. He is held liable to bear the entire burden, on the ground that a tacit promise to that effect is fairly to be inferred from his conduct. Here, the charge on the share of the receipts is merely to apply that money to pay the debts of the
“ It is, we think, too firmly established to be now questioned, that where a person employs another to make a contract of purchase for him, he as principal is liable to the seller, though the seller never heard of his existence, and entered into the contract solely on the credit of the person whom he believed to be the principal, though, in fact, he was not. It has often been doubted whether it was originally right so to hold ; but doubts of this kind come now too late; for we think that it is established law that, if, on the failure of the person with whom alone the vendor believed himself to be contracting, the vendor discovers that in reality there is an undisclosed principal behind, he is entitled to take advantage of this unexpected godsend, and is not put to take a dividend from the estate of him with whom alone he believed himself to be contracting, and to whom alone he gave credit, and to leave the trustees of that estate to settle with the undisclosed principal, subject to all mutual credits and equities between them. He may recover the price himself direct from the principal, subject to an exception, which is not so well established as the rule, and is not very accurately defined, viz., that nothing has occurred to make it unjust that the undisclosed principal should be called upon to make the payment to the vendor.” Blackburn, J., in Armstrong v. Stokes, L. R., 7 Q. B. 598, 603, 604. But this doctrine, relative to charging originally undisclosed principals, does not establish the liability of Stillings in this case. To lay a foundation for the application of the doQtrine, it must first be made to appear that Stillings was a principal in the business of the Clarks. This is precisely where the plaintiff’s case labors throughout. If, indeed, all that appeared as to the mutual relations was the fact that Stillings was to share in the gross receipts of the Clarks, that fact, standing alone and unexplained, might justify a jury in finding that Stillings was a principal in their business. But when all the other facts, relative to the agreements and mode of conducting the business, appear, and are viewed, as they must be, in the light of the special findings of the jury, it seems quite apparent that Stillings was not a principal in the business of the Clarks, nor the Clarks principals in the business of Stillings. On the contrary, the two parties respectively continued to carry on their business on their own behalf alone, although they had bound themselves to pay over a part of what they received. See 3 Kent’s Com., 12th ed., 25, note 1, citing cases of “ arrangements for pooling profits.” Various questions may, in other cases, arise as to the practical operation of the rules of law relative to the liability of originally undisclosed principals. Suppose A employs B to make a purchase in B’s name for him (A), upon a secret agreement between A and B that A is not to be responsible to the seller for the price: can the seller, upon subsequently discovering that A employed B to make the purchase, sue A for the price? Can the limitation, that A was not to be responsible, be held nugatory, as being inconsistent with A’s direction to B to effect the purchase ? Or, can the limitation be regarded as
Different opinions have been expressed on the question whether the sharer of gross returns is, by operation of law, liable to third persons asa partner, in'spite of an undisclosed agreement negativing such liability. See 2 Am. Law Review 9, 10, 198; Parsons on Partnership 88, note q.; Story on Partnership, 6th ed., sec. 34, n. 1,; Crompton, J., in Lyon v. Knowles, 3 Best & Smith 556, p. 564; Martin, B., in Hickman v. Cox, 3 C. B. N. S. 523, p. 562; instructions to jury by Parke, B., in Heyhoe v. Burge, 9 C. B. 431, p. 440. (Several of the cases sometimes cited on this point were really decided on other grounds; some of them on the ground that the “ sharing ” was merely a mode of compensating for services openly rendered.) The question has not often been fully considered on general principles. In some instances, the point most discussed is, whether the case of the sharer of gross returns comes within the letter or the reason of a rule of law which has sometimes been supposed to exist in relation to the liability of the sharer of net profits. It has sometimes been supposed to be the rule of the common law, that one who makes a secret agreement with the ostensible manager of a concern that he shall share in the net profits but shall not oe answerable for losses, is, nevertheless, by operation of law, liable as a partner to third persons for all the debts of the concern, although he was never held out as a partner, or relied on as such by those dealing with the concern, and although he has never in fact received any profits. One reason given for the supposed doctrine is, that, if any one takes part of the profits, he takes part of the fund on which the creditor of the trader relies for his payment; or, in other words, that, by taking a part of the profits, he takes from the creditors a part of that fund which is the proper security to them for the payment of their debts.
On the one hand, the letter of “the net-profit rule” has been looked at without regard to its reason. It is said, in substance, that gross returns, though they include net profits, are not literally the same thing; that a participant in gross returns does not participate in profits as profits; and that a division of gross returns is only incidentally a division of profits, not a division of profits as such. This reasoning is extremely unsatisfactory.
O'n the other hand, it is said that the reason of “ the net-profit rule ” applies with much greater force to the sharer of gross returns. Gross returns necessarily include net profits. If the sharer in net profits takes from the creditors the fund upon which they rely for payment, much more does the sharer in gross returns. And, if taking from the fund is sufficient reason for holding the former liable, a fortiori, it is a reason for holding the latter. Net profits “ are only to be ascertained after deducting and providing for all liabilities; but the amount of a share in the gross proceeds would be ascertained, and might be taken away as soon as they were received, without providing for the liabilities.” See O’Brien, J., in Shaw v. Galt, 16 Irish Com. Law 357, p. 373.
This train of reasoning appears to be unanswerable.
If, then, the supposed “ net-profit rule” is founded in reason and is to be upheld, consistency requires that the defendant Stillings should be held liable. If seems, therefore, hardly possible to avoid meeting, in this case, the question whether the supposed net-profit test, “ in its literal and unqualified form,” is a sound rule of law, founded in reason. (It is not proposed, in this opinion, to enter upon the inquiry how far the supposed test has ever been actually adopted as the basis of judicial decision.) The intrinsic correctness of the supposed test has been so often and so successfully disputed, that the views now about to be presented are little more than a mere compilation.
One of the principal reasons urged in favor of the supposed doctrine is that already adverted to, viz., that the man who takes part of the net profits, takes part of that fund on which the creditor of the trader relies for his payment. The short answer to this reason is, that'it is founded on a false assumption. Creditors neither can, nor do, rely on net profits for payment. Net profits “ do not exist until creditors are paid.” Testimony of Commissioner Fane, quoted in Story on Part., 6th ed., sec. 36, note 3. The very fact that net profits are realized “ presupposes that the creditors of the firm are satisfied, or that the partnership assets are sufficient to satisfy their claims.” 2 Am. Law Review 195. And if it were possible in the nature of things for creditors to rely on the net profits as a fund for the payment of their claims, it is not probable that they would do so ; for they must know that the amount of the net profits would generally be insufficient for that purpose.
The argument, that the sharer of the net profits will otherwise receive usurious interest without risk, does not seem very forcible. Usury is punished by the refusal of the law to enforce usurious contracts, or by the imposition of penalties; but it is not customary to punish usury by .compelling parties to perform contracts which they never made.
The only other alleged reason deserving special consideration at this tifne is, that the net-profit rule is necessary to “ protect third persons against the frauds which might be practised, if secret agreements were allowed to be binding on third persons.” See Bell, J., in Bromley v. Elliot; 38 N. H. 287, p. 303. It is conceded i. all hands that, so far as the agreement is known, it. must be binding o, 'll who have knowledge of it — ibid, and see 2 Am. Law Review 7, 8, 202; but it is urged that to allow force and validity to a secret agreement would often work a fraud on third persons. In this view, the liability of the sharer of net profits depends solely upon the secrecy of the agreement.
What are the probable frauds which cannot be remedied save by holding the secret stipulator for a share of the net profits liable to pay the entire debts of the concern, in direct contravention of an agreement that he shall not be so liable ? If his failure to dir U„e the agreement has caused persons dealing with the firm to entertain a reasonable belief in the existence of a certain state of facts, and to act on that belief, he cannot now be permitted to controvert, to the prejudice of such persons, the existence of such facts. If, for instance, A allows B to hold himself out as the sole owner of a stock in trade, and to gain credit thereby, an attachment of that stock in trade by a creditor of B will not be defeated by proof that the stock was. furnished by A, under a secret
The maxim, “ qui sentit commodmn sentiré debet et onus” is not decisive in favor, of the supposed rule. It must be presumed that the secret stipulator for a share of the net profits gives something for the right. (If he does not, there is no consideration, and hence no valid agreement.) If he does pay anything to the ostensible manager, or puts any capital into the concern, he does “ bear a burden ; ” he runs . the risk of losing what he thus pays or puts in. His claim is not enforceable until after all the creditors of the concern are satisfied. Furthermore, notwithstanding this maxim, an agreement to share profits without being liable for debts is not in its nature against the policy of the law. This, as has already been 'said, is evident from the fact that such agreements, so far as they are known to persons dealing with the concern, are allowed full scope and effect. See 2 Am. Law Review 7, 8, 202 ; Bailey v. Clark, 6 Pick. 372 ; Bell, J., in Bromley v. Elliot, 38 N. H. 287, p. 303.
“ It may be said that if this reasoning is right, a man might bargain to receive all the profits of a business and not be liable. The answer is, the thing is impossible. There never was, and never will be, a bona fide agreement by one man to carry on a business, bear all its losses, and pay over all its profits. Should such an agreement appear, it would obviously be colourable.” Bramwell, B., in Bullen v. Sharp, L. R., 1 C. P. 86, pp. 126, 127. In other words, it would be almost impossible to satisfy a jury that even the form of such an agreement was ever entered into ; and, if that fact should be established, the mere making of such an agreement would, under ordinary circumstances, afford cogent evidence of an actual intent to defraud creditors. And participators in that intent would in some form of action (whether in contract or tort is not now material) be held answerable to make good the loss of all who suffered by the conspiracy. We are dealing here only with bona fide agreements. Colorable arrangements will be attempted under any rule or test.
The supposed “net-profit rule” is not needed to reach the case of an ostensible partner. He is liable on the elementary principles of the law of estoppel, because he held himself out as a partner. Nor is it needed to reach the case of a dormant partner who was to participate in the profits and the íosses. He is liable, just as any other undisclosed principal is, under the ordinary doctrines of the law of agency. In such case “ the dormant partner knows he is liable, and means to be.” amwell, B., in L. R., 1 C. P., p. 126.
It is not the least of the objections to the supposed rule, that the hardship of its application to individual cases will lead to the introduction of subtle exceptions to the rule, exceptions “ which aggravate the bulk of the Corpus Juris, and (what is an evil of still greater magnitude) which reduce the body of the law to a chaos of incoherent details.” See 1 Austin on Jurisprudence, 3d ed., 483.
In truth, “ the law as to partnership is undoubtedly a branch of the law 'of principal and agent; and it would tend to simplify and make more easy of solution the questions which arise on this subject, if this true principle were more constantly kept in view.” Lord Wensleydale, in Cox v. Hickman, 8 House of Lords’ Cases 268; S. C., 99 Eng. Com. Law 47, pp. 98, 99. The same great judge said, nearly twenty years earlier, — “ All questions between partners are no more than illustrations of the same questions as between principal and agent.” Parke, B., in Beckham v. Brake, 9 M. & W. 79, p. 98. Sec Cox v. Hickman, 8 House of Lords’ Cases 268; S. C., 99 Eng. Com. Law 47; Bullen v. Sharp, L. R., 1 C. P. 86 ; Re English $ Irish Church & University Assurance Society, 1 Hemming & Miller 85; Shaw v. Colt, 16 Irish Com. Law 357, p. 375 ; Holme v. Hammond, L. R., 7 Exch. 218 ; Kilshaw v. s, 3 Best & Smith 847; Story on Partnership, 6th ed., sec. 49, note 2; cases of “arrangements for pooling profits,” cited in 3 Kent’s Com., 12th ed., p. 25, note 1.
The real and ultimate question in all cases like the present is one of agency. Did the person sought to be charged stand in the relation of principal to the person contracting the debt? Participation in the profits is not decisive of that question, “ except so far as it is evidence of the relation of principal and agent between the persons taking the profits and those actually carrying on the business.” Whether such relation existed is a question of fact. Upon the trial of that question, proof of a right to participate in the profits would be a cogent, and often practically conclusive, piece of evidence to establish the existence
Undoubtedly, in a great majority of cases, persons who would be held liable under the supposed “ net-profit test,” will also be found liable under what I view as the true test. But the present case affords evidence that the difference between the two tests is substantial, and not merely verbal. It is to be borne in mind that, in what has here been said as to the supposed “ net-profit test,” reference is made solely to that test in the “ literal and unqualified form ” in which it is stated in a previous part of this opinion. Whether the test, in that form, lias ever been adopted as the basis of judicial action, it is not my present purpose to inquire. The intrinsic correctness of the supposed test is the only point intended to be here discussed.
Upon the foregoing views, the literal terms of the reserved case would justify the court, not only in setting aside the verdict for the plaintiff, but also in rendering judgment for the defendant Stillings. But I am inclined to give the plaintiff another opportunity to try the case upon the facts, in the light of the opinion now expressed as to the law. There is some reason to believe that, at the late trial, the plaintiff’s counsel and the presiding judge both assumed the “ net-profit tost ” to be unquestionable law; and that this position was not seriously controverted by the defendants’ counsel. If the “■ net-profit test ” were law, logical consistency would, as has already been said, require that Stillings should be held liable here upon the admitted facts of the case. Under the misconception as to the law, which seems to have been tacitly adopted by all parties at the trial, the plaintiff’s counsel might have supposed themselves sure of success on the admitted facts, and thus have failed to present their case fully on the controverted facts. It is conceivable that the plaintiff’s counsel might have made, a stronger case as to the authority in fact given by Stillings to the Clarks, or that they might have introduced evidence on the question of estoppel, if they had understood how essential it was to succeed on one or the other of these issues of fact. Under all the circumstances, I am disposed to give tlie plaintiff another opportunity to try the questions of fact,— although, if the findings at.the new trial are like those at the former trial, the defendant Stillings will, in my opinion, be entitled to judgment. The verdict should be set aside.
Doe, J. When Judge Story had written his treatise on agency, he began his commentaries on the law of partnership thus: “ Having completed our review of the law of agency, we are naturally conducted, in the next place, to the consideration of the law of partnership; for every partner is an agent of the partnership, and his rights, powers, duties, and obligations are, in many respects, governed by the same rules and principles as those of an agent. A partner, indeed, virtually embraces the character both of a principal and of an agent. So far
i£ The authorities are uniform in maintaining the doctrine that, where the principal is unknown to the vendor at the time of a sale, he may, upon discovering the principal, resort to him for payment, although, in the absence of such knowledge, the credit may have been given to the agent alone, and his individual note alone have been taken for the debt. Story on Agency 291; Paterson v. Gandasequi, 15 East 62 ; Raymond v. Crown Eagle Mills, 2 Met. 324; Thomson v. Davenport, 9 B. & C. 78. The same principle, which seems to have been uniformly applied to the case of principal and agent, is equally applicable to that of an individual partner and his firm. Each partner is an authorized agent for the firm; and if the individual partner obtain money or goods on his own credit for the use of the firm, without disclosing the interest of the partnership in the transaction, the debt contracted i's the debt of the firm, notwithstanding the note of the individual partner alone may have been given and taken therefor.” Tucker v. Peaslee, 36 N. H. 167,176 ; Parr v. Wheeler, 20 N. H. 569, 575. “As the defendants were partners, they were both liable to the plaintiffs, notwithstanding at the time of the sale the plaintiffs supposed that they were giving credit to Smith only. In purchasing the goods, he was the authorized agent of the copartnership, * * and the plaintiffs * * may well sustain an action against those who were in truth the purchasers. Smith v. Smith, 27 N. H. 244, 253.
When A authorizes B to make a contract in his behalf, the contract is, in a certain sense and for some purposes, the contract of A. In contemplation of law he makes it. Whether he makes it personally, by the exercise of his own mind, hand, or voice, or instrumentally by the mind, hand, or voice of his agent B, is immaterial so far as his own liability is concerned. He is as much the principal in one case as in the other. So he is equally a principal whether he is sole principal and B his agent, or whether B is a joint principal with him as well as his agent. If they are partners, B makes the contract as a principal, and also as agent of A. If we say he makes it as an agent of the firm, we mean that he makes it as agent of A, and also as agent of himself. And as the contract is equally A’s contract, whether B is merely his agent, or his agent and also a joint principal with him,'so in each case A is equally bound, whether he is or is not known to the other contracting party to be a principal. The cases in which A is not liable because the other contracting party, knowing him to be a principal, elects not to contract with him, stand upon the ground of othe election thus made by the other party. Without reference to that exceptional class of cases, and with sole reference to the general question raised in this case, if B is agent, A is liable because he is the principal: if B is a joint principal as well as agent, A is liable because he is a principal: if A is known to the other contracting party to be a principal, he is
In the case supposed by Brother Smith (ante, pp. 286, 287), where A employs B to make a purchase in B’s name for him (A), upon a secret agreement between A and B that A is not to be responsible to the seller for the price, a difficulty arises from an ambiguity in the terms, “A employs B to make a purchase in B’s name for him (A).” If this means that A is the principal and B his agent, A is liable because he is the principal. Edmunds v. Bushell, L. R., 1 Q. B. 97. If it means that B, as principal, is to buy the property of C, and then sell it to A, A is not liable to C because he is not the principal. The question of A’s liability is the question whether, in the contract of purchase from C, A is in fact the principal and B liis agent, or whether B is the principal, who, after he has bought, the property of C, is to sell it to A; whether the title passes directly from C to A, or from C to B and from B to A; whether there are to be two successive purchases of the same property, or only one; whether (in the contract of purchase from C) A or B is the purchaser. This depends (so far as A’s liability is concerned, and aside from fraud and estoppel) upon the understanding between A and B. If they understand the title passes directly from C to A, and not through B as an intermediate, purchaser, A is the principal, B is his agent, and A, as the purchaser, is bound to pay C for the'property which he buys of O. A’s denial of the fact that he is the purchaser, has no more effect than his denial of any other fact; an agreement between him and B to deny the fact, does not alter the fact; A, being the purchaser, is‘responsible as the purchaser for the price; he is liable upon the fact, and is not discharged from his liability by an understanding between him and his agent that the fact should not be disclosed or should be denied. A purchase of goods is a sale; and a sale is something more than the vendor’s parting with his property. It includes payment made, promised, or in some way provided for by the other party to the contract. The buyer, i. e., the principal who buys, is necessarily a payer, unless the vendor agrees he shall not be. If the agreement between A and B is made known to C during the negotiation, and he expressly or impliedly agrees not to look to A for payment, he is bound by his agreement; but ho is not bound by a secret agreement between A the purchaser and B the purchaser’s agent, that A is not to pay C for property bought by A of C. When C discovers that A is the buyer, lie is not deprived of all the benefit of that fact by the undisclosed agreement inter alios that A is not to pay for what he buys. That agreement does not make the agent B the purchaser in fact, nor relieve the purchaser A from his part of the contract of purchase made with O. The agent, holding himself out as the purchaser, is estopped to deny, as against the vendor 0, that he is the purchaser. But the secret agreement between the real purchaser and liis agent, that payment is to be made by the latter and not by the former, is no part of the contract of purchase: it is merely an extraneous executory agreement inter alios to which the vendor is not a party.
The question whether A is a principal and B his agent, that is, whether A authorizes B to make the contract in his behalf, is often a difficult question of.fact. And if B is a principal, the question whether A is a principal is the same, and may be as difficult, as it would be if B were not a principal. If B is a principal, the question whether A is a principal is called a question of partnership : if B is not a principal, the question whether A is a principal is called a question of principal and agent, or agency. The legal character of the question whether A is a principal, is not altered by the circumstance that B is or is not a principal, nor by the circumstance that it is called in one case a question of partnership, and in the other a question of agency. And as that question is not affected by the name given it by the tribunal called upon to decide it, so it does not depend upon the name given it by A or B, or both of them. Through all forms and words, all arrangements simple or complicated, all pretences true or false, all contrivances honest or fraudulent, the law requires the tribunal to search for the substance, the meaning, the understanding, and the fact; and this duty is the same whether B is a principal or whether he is not.
Not only is A liable as a principal when, as a matter of fact, he is a principal, whether B is or is not a joint principal with him, and whether A is or is not known by the other party to be a principal, — he may also be liable when, as a matter of fact, he is not a principal. The common-law rule, generally called the doctrine of estoppel, is applicable, and is applied to the liability of A as a principal in a contract made by B. If B is held out by A, or by his direction or consent, as his agent, A is liable as a principal: he is estopped to deny the existence of the state of things which he directly or indirectly induces another, or causes another to be induced, to believe in and act upon. Though not a principal in fact, he is a principal in contemplation of law, because he is estopped to deny that he is a principal. Being estopped in law to deny that he is in fact a principal, is, so far as liability to creditors is concerned, practically the same as being a principal in fact. Causing another to act upon the belief that he is a principal, and that B is authorized to make a contract in his behalf, that is, is his agent for that purpose, he is estopped to deny the existence of the relation of principal and agent between himself and B, — in other words, is estopped to deny B’s authority, — without regard to the question whether B is or is not a joint principal or copartner. The estoppel operates in the same manner and with the same result, whether B is an agent merely — Hatch v. Taylor, 10 N. H. 538 ; Towle v. Leavitt, 23 N. H. 860, 374 — or an agent and also a joint principal. Smith v. Smith, 27 N. H. 244, 252. " If A holds B out, or authorizes B to hold himself
Here are two general elementary doctrines of the ancient common law, holding A liable as a principal on a contract made by B: — 1. The doctrine of the liability of an actual principal, disclosed or undisclosed ; 2. The doctrine of estoppel, which under certain circumstances makes a man a principal in law when he is not a principal in fact. The latter doctrine, applied to this subject, is merely one of the methods of ascertaining whether A is a principal. Both doctrines constitute the single doctrine of the liability of a principal. If A is in fact a principal, he is liable because he is a principal: if by the process of estoppel in law he is a principal, he is liable because he is a -principal. And each of these doctrines or parts of a single doctrine has a legal operation and effect irrespective of the question whether B is or is not a joint principal or copartner with A. The application of these doctrines to the question of A’s liability does not render it necessary to determine whether the question is one of agency or partnership, that is, whether B is as agent merely, or an agent and also a principal, because, whether B is or is not a principal, A is equally and for a single reason liable as a principal disclosed or undisclosed, and is equally and for a single reason estopped to deny that he is a principal. He is liable because he is a principal, or because he holds himself out or suffers himself to be held out as such. He is none the- less nor for a different reason liable when, B being a principal, the question of A’s liability is called a question of partnership: he is none the more nor for a different reason liable when, B not being a principal, the question of A’s liability is called a question of agency: and the test of his liability is not more ambiguous nor anywise different when, it being uncertain whether B i's or is not a principal, it is consequently uncertain whether the question of A’s liability is to be called a question of partnership or a question of agency. If it is never settled whether B is a principal, and it is consequently never known by which of its possible names the question of A’s liability is to be called, that question can be settled notwithstanding it is an anonymous one; and it must be settled on the same legal grounds as if its name were known. So far as the general legal test of A’s liability is concerned, the two names of the question are synonymous. These legal rudiments every one expresses in language most satisfactory to himself. There is a choice of words. For instance, when B is a principal, and the question is whether A is liable as a copartner or joint principal with him, some may use the word “ partner,” and others may prefer the word “ principal: ” whichever term is employed, the same thing is meant, and the same idea is accurately conveyed. But the use of some words in indefinite, ambiguous, and ipposite senses has involved the authorities in some apparent uncerainty and confusion. When A and B are not partners in fact, but are liable to certain creditors as partners in law by estoppel, they are partners as to those creditors, though not partners as between themselves : but the phrase “ partners as to third persons though not partners inter
If C is first paid, he takes part of the fund on which D relies for payment: if D is first paid, he takes part of the fund on which O relies for payment: but the one first paid does not, by the act of receiving payment, become liable to the other for taking part of the fund on which they both rely. That is not the fund of which A is to have one ninth; and he is not liable to O and D for not taking a share of the fund on which they-rely. The fund of which A is to have one ninth is the $900 left after'C and D are paid : on that fund G and D do not rely; and A is not liable to them for taking a part of the fund on which they do not rely. He is a creditor, though a deferred one; and, as
But if A, as a joint principal and copartner, and not as creditor, is entitled to one ninth of the profit, it is net profit that is meant; and if he is entitled to a part of the net profit, he is liable to C and D, not because lie"is entitled to a part of the fund on which they rely, — for they do not rely on the net profit; he is liable to them because lie is a principal. If he is a principal, “ the profit ” of which he is to have a part means the balance of gross profit left after paying all creditors : if he is a creditor, “the profit” means the balance of gross profit left after paying all creditors but himself. Whether, in a particular case, “ the profit” carries the one meaning or the other, depends on the question whether he is a principal or a creditor, which is the first, last, and only question in the case. We cannot know in what sense “ the profit” is used by the parties until we discover whether A is a principal or a creditor. How can that be a method of answering a question, which is a deduction from the answer, and cannot be known until the answer is obtained ? If A is a creditor, he is none the more and none the less a creditor by reason of his being entitled, as a creditor, to one ninth of “ the profit: ” if he is a principal, he is none the more and none the less a principal by reason of his being entitled, as a principal, to one ninth of “ the profit.” When A and B agree that A shall have one ninth of “ the profit,” they may mean that he is to have it in the capacity of, and by virtue of his being, a creditor: they may mean that he is to have it in the capacity of, and by virtue of his being, a principal. The question is, Which do they mean ? The sliaring-profit test merely repeats that question without answering it. As A may be entitled to one ninth of a fund called “ profit,” either in the capacity of a creditor or in the capacity of a partner, his ambiguous right is not a test of the capacity in which he holds it. Taking part of “ the profit ” is no more the test of his being a partner than it is the test of his being a creditor.
In the supposed case, where A is a creditor and not a partner, there are three different profit funds, or one profit fund of three different amounts and with three different names, — 1, $1,000 gross profit, out of which, as well as out of the other $10,000, proceeds of. the flour, the general creditors are to be paid; 2, $900 deferred creditor fund left after payment of the general creditors C and D ; 3, $800 net profit, left after payment .of the general creditors C and D, and the deferred creditor A. An agreement of A and B that A is to have one ninth of the profit, means either that A is to be a deferred creditor entitled to one ninth of the gross profit left after payment of the general creditors as compensation for his services, or that he is to be a joint principal and copartner with B, entitled to one ninth of the net profit. In the former case, “ the profit ” means neither the gross profit nor the net profit, but the $900, of which the $800 left after payinent of A is the net profit of
If A is clerk and creditor, he receives $100, not as his share of the profit of a business in which lie is a joint principal, but as compensation for his services in a business in which B is sole principal: he receives one ninth of the profit, not as profit, but as payment of a debt. If A is a principal, he owns one ninth of'the profit as profit, and does not receive it as payment of a debt. The distinction between taking profit as profit, and taking it not as profit but as payment of a debt, is a familiar one, firmly established by the authorities, but not always explained as clearly as it might be. It is the distinction between a partner and a creditor obscurely expressed. Taking a share of the profit as profit, is taking it as his profit — as the profit of his flour business — as the profit of a principal, — taking it in the capacity of a principal trader —an owner of the profit — a partner: taking a part of the profit as payment of a debt, is taking it in the capacity of a hired man or other creditor. If A is clerk and creditor, we mean by his share of the profit what is his when it is paid to him by his employer, but, until then, is his in a figurative sense only. If he is clerk and creditor, what is called his share of the profit belongs, as a matter of absolute legal title, exclusively to B until he pays it to A, and then belongs exclusively to A: it does not, at any time, belong to A and B in common, or in any manner indicated by the ordinary signification of the terms “ share of a partner.” But, if A is a joint principal, his share ” is “ the share of a partner ” in the net profit. The indiscriminate use of the word “ share,” signifying the amount of his wages and debt if he is a clerk and creditor of B, and signifying his ownership of a part of the profit in common with B, if he is a principal, is a cause of confusion. The distinction between the two significations of “ share,” is the distinction between a creditor and a partner.
If A, by agreement with B, is to have “ a share of the profit,” meaning a part of the profit left after the payment of all debts, he is necessarily a principal, because he is either a principal or a creditor; and a creditor cannot be entitled, as a creditor, to a part of what is left after he is paid. Whether he is a principal or a creditor depends upon the agreement between him and B. If they agree he shall have a part of “ the profit,” what do they mean by “the profit” ? If they mean the profit left after the payment of all creditors, they mean that A is not to be one of those creditors; and, not being a creditor, he must be a principal. But how are we to know whether tliey mean “ the profit ” in that sense, until we ascertain whether, in their meaning, A is to be one of those creditors whose payment is the prerequisite and test of “ the profit ” in that sense ? Put this in what form we may, it is all a reasoning in a circle, or a begging of the question, or a substitution of one of two synonymous questions for the other.
What difference whether A is to receive one ninth as wages, or horse hire, or store rent, or interest of money loaned ? How can a debt due him for one thing make him a creditor, and a debt due him for another thing make him a partner? What he is to receive as compensation for his own work or the work of his horse, for the use of his store or the use of his money, for knowledge and skill sold to B or for goods sold to B, — what he is to receive in the capacity of a creditor he is not to receive in the capacity of a partner. All this is merely saying, if he is a creditor, he is a creditor; if he is a partner, he is a partner. The question all the time is, whether he is a creditor or a partner; and to say the question is, whether he is to receive a part of the profit in the
In the supposed case, A is either a creditor or copartner of B. He is to receive a part of what they call “ profit,” in the capacity either of creditor of partner. The combined authorities establish a sharing-profit test in this sense: if A is to have something in the capacity of a creditor, he is a creditor; if he is to have it in the capacity of a partner, he is a partner. The discussions of the last ninety-eight years began with that; and they have ended where they began. The difficulty now is, not to ascertain the result, but to discover what disputed point was supposed to be involved in the debate, — a difficulty not unfrequently found at the close of protracted controversies.
“ Sharing profits,” with the qualification “ as a principal and not as a creditor,” is useless as a legal test, because the qualification is a mere repetition of the question -for the solution of which a test is sought: without that qualification it is useless because it is equivocal. In its literal and unqualified form, as shown by my Brother Smith, it is not consistent with, and cannot be founded upon, the general rules of law. If in that form it could be and were a test, it would exist as the creation of arbitrary and absolute authority. In examining the authorities, it is an advantage to begin with the supposed test wholly severed and detached from dim and indeterminate generalities, and placed apart by itself in contrast with the primary principles upon which the law of partnership liability is based. If we find an authority urging that an undisclosed principal or secret partner should be liable, we know that is accomplished without a sharing-profit test: if we find an authority working out a liability by estoppel, we know a sharing-profit tost in that matter is irrelevant. If we find authorities apparently presenting or recognizing a sharing-profit test, the first question will be, In what sense is the test announced, and what is the meaning and effect of its exceptions and qualifications ? If, upon a careful scrutiny, the so-called test of sharing profits, enveloped in and consolidated with its mass of exceptions and qualifications, when compared with the elementary doctrine of the liability of a principal disclosed or undisclosed, is found to be nothing more than a badly executed copy or paraphrase of that doctrine, or a. fao-simile in disguise, the question in this case will be reduced to one of those contentions about words, which is not a legal controversy.
It has been supposed that a sharing-profit test, with divers exceptions, qualifications, and explanations, was, at one time, established by the
The civil law seems to have been largely the source of the common law of partnership ; and it is agreed, by competent persons who have made due investigation, — Story on Part., secs. 37, 50, 51, 62 ; Parsons on Part. 88; 2 Am. Law Rev. 6, 7, — that the authorities of the civil law do not contain a sharing-profit test of partnership liability. No one seems to have supposed that such a test came, into England from the continent. If it had been a rule of the civil law, that fact would probably have been discovered in the researches, and asserted in the discussions that have occurred in England during the last thirteen years. The English cases on the subject begin in 1775 ; at least, none have been found of an earlier date. They do not refer to such a test as a civil law doctrine adopted in England, or as having been in any way established or recognized by any common law authority before 1775. We may safely conclude that, if there is such a test, it originated in Westminster Hall, and was not fabricated before 1775. And, as nearly if not quite all the important common law rules that have been introduced within the last hundred years can be traced to the time and place of their origin by authentic records, and as a sharing-profit test, if it ever existed, has been introduced within that period, we should expect to find, with a satisfactory degree of certainty, when, where, and by whom it was introduced, on what occasion, under what circumstances, for what purpose, in what signification, and with what exceptions, qualifications, and explanations.
Of Bloxham v. Pell, a nisiprius case, we find an account in Grace v. Smith, 2 Wm. Bl. 998, 999. It was tried before Lord Mansfield, in the King’s Bench, at the same sittings at which Grace v. Smith was tried before DeGrey, C. J., in the common pleas, March 7, 1775. Pell and Brooke had entered into a partnership for seven years, but at the
Pell was either a creditor of Brooke, or a joint principal with him. If he was a creditor, his contract was usurious and criminal; and Mansfield held that he should not be allowed, even in self-defence, to claim the position of a criminal creditor, and that, there being no other position he could occupy but that of a principal, he must be considered as a principal. In Hoare v. Dawes, 1 Doug. 371, 372 (in the year of 1780), Mansfield repeated the same peculiar theory, saying of “ dormant partners” (meaning undisclosed partners), “they are liable when discovered, because they would otherwise receive usurious interest without any risk.” Although this process of turning all creditors having usurious claims against any person into joint principals, copartners, and codebtors, liable with their debtor to his other creditors, was repudiated by the court in Grace v. Smith, when Bloxham-v. Pell was cited and much relied on by the plaintiff; and although it never was law and has nearly passed into oblivion, it is still of some value as showing what erratic ideas of partnership liability could prevail in high places. When Mansfield could think an undisclosed partner is liable for the debts of the firm of which he is a member, not for the siulple reason that he is a member (that is, a principal), but because, if he were not liable, his profits might be more than a creditor’s legal interest, it would not be surprising if other judges were found entertaining, or, at least, reported as expressing, loose notions on the same general subject. Bloxham v. Pell is also of value, because it exhibits the positions of a partnership principal and a partnership creditor in striking contrast, and cogently presents the alternative of forcing a defendant into the one position or the other, without any reference to a sharing-profit test, as to which Mansfield’s erroneous usury test affords no light.
The case Grace v. Smith, 2 Wm. Bl. 998, was, in its facts, very similar to Bloxham v. Pell; but DeGrey, instead of making the defendant a partnership principal by Mansfield’s usury test, left the case to the jury, who found a verdict for the defendant. What instructions were
“ DeGrey, Chief Justice. The only Question is, What constitutes a secret Partner ? Every Man who has a Share of the Profits of a Trade, ought also to bear his Share of the Loss. And if any one takes Part of the Profit, he takes Part of that Fund on which the Creditor of the Trader relies for his Payment. If any one advances or lends Money to a Trader, it is only lent on his general personal Security. It is no specific Lien upon the Profits of the Trade, and yet the Lender is generally interested in those Profits; he relies on them for Repayment. And there is no Difference whether that Money be lent de novo, or left behind in Trade, by one of the Partners who retires. And whether the Terms of that Loan be kind or harsh, makes also no manner of Difference. I think the true Criterion is, to inquire whether Smith agreed to share the Profits of the Trade with Robinson, or whether he only relied on those Profits as a Fund of Payment: a distinction not more nice than usually occurs in Questions of Trade or Usury. The jury have said this is not payable out of the Profits; and I think there is no Foundation for granting a new Trial.
“ Gould, Justice, same Opinion.
“ Blackstone, Justice, same Opinion. I think the true Criterion (when Money is advanced to a Trader) is, to consider whether the Profit or Premium is certain and defined, or casual, indefinite, and depending on the Accidents of Traffe. In the former Case it is a fyan (whether usurious or not is not Material to the present Question), in the latter a Partnership. The Hazard of Loss and Profit is not equal and reciprocal, if the Lender can receive only a limited Sum for the Profits of his Loan,*303 and yet is made liable to all tlie Losses, all the Debts contracted in the Trade, to any Amount.
“ Nares, Justice, same Opinion.
“Rule discharged
The question of fact which the jury had answered in favor of the defendant was, whether the defendant Smith was a creditor or a copartner of Robinson. Whether a partnership relation between them was disclosed or undisclosed, wrns, as the law is now settled, an immaterial question ; and DeGrey’s remarks concerning a “ secret partner” were made, apparently, because, in 1775, the liability of an undisclosed partner was not so well understood as it now is, and it was thought necessary to give some other reason for holding such a partner liable than the fact that he is a partner. DeGrey begins by suggesting this other reason : “ Every man who has a share of the profits of a trade, ought also to bear his share of the loss.”. This is a free translation of a rule of the civil law, and must be presumed to be given with the civil law signification of the original, which has no reference to a sharing-profit test of liability to partnership creditors, but is based upon the admitted fact of partnership, and is a presumption regulating the rights and obligations of acknowledged partners, as between themselves, “ in the absence of all contrary stipulations.” Story on Part., secs. 19,20, 24, 25, 26. “Sicuti lucrum, ita damnum quoque commune esse oportet. 1. 52, sec. 1, inf. eod. Soeietas chm eontrahitur, tarn lucri, qudm damni eommunio initur. 1. 67 eod.; l. 52, sec. 4, inf. eod.;” 1 Domat (2d Eng. ed.) 142.
Potliier, treating of “ what natural equity requires in the contract of partnership,” as between the partners, gives this as the “ First Rule: ” “ In order that the contract of partnership may be equitable, it is generally necessary that the share assigned by it-to each of the partners, in the anticipated profits, should be in proportion to the value of what each of them has brought into the partnership; ” — and this as the “ Second Rule: ” “ Generally, each of the partners ought to bear the same proportion of the losses of the partnership, as he ought to have of its profits in case it is prosperous.” Potliier on Part. (Tudor’s translation) 11, 15. The subject is fully discussed in Story on Part., cli. 3. In 1788, Lord Loughborough (DeGrey’s successor), thinking it necessary to give some other reason for the liability of “ the secret partner ” to the partnership creditors than the fact that he is a partner, said the reason is, “ that, if a partner shares in advantages, he also shares in all disadvantages.” Coope v. Eyre, 1 H. Bl. 37, 48. And when DeGrey, speaking of the liability of “ a secret partner,” as if it were something different from the liability of a known partner, or must stand on some peculiar ground, or needed the support of argument on account if the non-disclosure of the partnership relation, said, “ Every man who has a share of the profits of a trade ought also to bear his share of the loss,” we can understand his argument, though it would be considered an unnecessary one at the present day. A part
The third sentence, “ And if any one takes part of the profit, he takes part of that fund on which the creditor of the trader relies for his payment,” connected with the preceding sentence as it is by “And,” was probably intended as a mere continuation of the previous reasoning for holding “ a secret partner ” liable, notwithstanding the secrecy or non-disclosure of the partnership relation. The reporter’s minute of the oral opinion appears to be abbreviated and imperfect; and ho absurd meaning ought to be put upon it by strict construction or verbal criticism. The reported third sentence, read by itself without the connecting “And,” and without reference to the context or the subject of the liability of “ a secret partner ” of which the chief justice was speaking, can be made to mean and has been supposed to mean, that, “ if any one,” principal or creditor, takes a part of the profit, he is liable as a principal to all the creditors because he takes part of the fund on which they rely for payment. In regard to this interpretation, it may be remarked, in the first place, that a partner, disclosed or undisclosed, is liable to the creditors whether he takes a part of the profit or not; but, in the time of DeGrey, it was thought necessary to say that an undisclosed partner was liable because it was just, as between him and his copartner, in the absence of express stipulation to the contrary ; that, having a share of the benefit, he should bear a share of the burden. In the second place, the net profit is the balance of gross profit left over and above the capital after deducting all losses and expenses, and paying all creditors ; and upon that fund it is impossible for the creditors to rely. They cannot rely for payment on what is to be left, or what is left after they are paid. That is the only fund they do not rely on.
If it were possible for a ci’editor to rely for payment upon, and to be paid out of, what is left after he is paid, what predicament would he he thrown into by receiving payment out of that fund ? According •to one interpretation of the report of DeGrey’s opinion, by taking part
If, by the true interpretation of DeGrey’s opinion, Grace v. Smith were an authority for such an impossible transformation, it would be sufficiently disposed of without going any further. The first three sentences of the fragmentary report of the dicta of DeGrey are the foundation on which all the authorities supposed to favor a sharing-profit test are based. That case is, and is regarded by all the authorities as, the one in which the supposed test originated ; and it should have been treated as the leading case instead of Waugh v. Carver. The whole argument, so often reiterated from 1775 to the present time, in favor of such a test, has been a mere repetition of'the supposed meaning of the reported remark of DeGrey, — ‘-And. if any one takes part of the profit, he takes part of that fund on which the creditor of the trader relies for his payment.” Who is “ any one,” and what is “the profit”? A creditor is “ any one; ” and the balance left, over and above the capital, losses, expenses, and debts of every kind, is “ the profit” in a certain sense. If it is urged that DeGrey meant that creditor A should be liable to other creditors because he- is paid or is to be paid out of what may be left after he is paid ; that this doctrine was approved by the English authorities from 1775 to 1860, and by the American decisions to the present time; and that it is a settled rule of law which nobody but the legislature can change, — it is answer enough to say, that neither DeGrey, nor any one else, could have meant any such thing ; that, if DeGrey and everybody else have inadvertently used a formula which, upon investigation, is found to be capable of no other meaning than that, it is certain they did not use it in that sense, and, therefore, we have their authority for not using it in that sense; that, if they did not irse it in any other sense, we cannot, upon their authority, either use it in any other sense, or use it at all; and that, if they did use it in some other sense, we are not called upon to accept or reject that other sense before it is discovered. To use the formula in a sense in which we know the authorities could not have intended to use it, would be an irreverent and revolutionary perversion and overthrow of precedent. If it could be shown that DeGrey, and all the venerated authorities of the last hundred years, meant that creditors rely for payment on what is left after they are paid, it would require no great courage, in this age, to say that we do not propose to assert our belief in a dogma that is either preposterous or unintelligible.
What DeGrey meant is to be ascertained, not by a literal and ridiculous interpretation of some dark passage in the fragmentary report, but from some rational sense of his whole opinion. Taking the third sentence in connection with the reason he was giving for holding “ a secret partner” liable (with which it is visibly coupled by “ And”), and with the rest of the opinion, and making due allowance for the inaccuracy of a hasty memorandum made by one man of an extemporaneous effusion of another, the general drift of the whole is plain enough, and is plainly opposed to a sliaring-profit test in any other sense than sharing profit in the capacity of a principal. The terms “ profit ” and “ profits ” .lie apparently used without any discrimination between gross and net profit. The general and uncertain idea of profit, indefinite as it is in the report, is no more indistinct than ideas are apt to be under similar circumstances, but more so than it would have been had its influence been foreseen. To give clearness and precision of thought and expression to what he is reported to have said about profit would now be an unauthorized alteration, likely to impose a meaning and produce results not contemplated by the author.
Some notion of a creditor relying on profit seems, to be presented three times in his opinion, — the last time in a'formal summing up and explicit statement that leaves no doubt what his test of the defendant’s liability was, however “cloudy the reported theory of creditors relying on profits. “ I think the true criterion is to inquire whether Smith agreed to share the profits of the trade with Robinson, or whether he
“ If,” says DeGrey, “ any one advances or lends money to a trader, it ismnly lent on his general personal security. It is no specific lien upon the profits of the trade.” If the defendant, as a partner, left his money in the business, he had the “ specific lien ” of a partner “ upon the profits; ” that is, the profits, being owned in common by him and Robinson, could not be diverted to the payment of Robinson’s private debts, to the damage of the defendant. If, as a creditor, he lent liis
Blackstone, J., made no distinction between “ partners inter sese ” and “ partners as to third persons,” but held that, as between the defendant and Robinson, their chances of’loss and profit ought to be equal and reciprocal. In the absence of an express stipulation on that point, it would naturally be presumed that they understood their chances of loss and profit were to be equal and reciprocal. “ Every man who has a share of the profits of a trade, ought also to bear his share of the loss,” said DeGrey, repeating the civil law. “Illud expeditum est, si in und causd pars fuer it expressa (veluti in solo lucro, vel in solo damno J in altera verb omissa: in eo quoque quod praetermissum est, eandem partem servari. Sec. 3, inst. de societ.” 1 Domat (2d Eng. ed.) 142. Many inferences of fact are laid down in the authorities of the civil law, because, under that system, questions of law and fact being decided by the court without a jury, there is little occasion to preserve the distinction between law and fact, which is indispensable under the common-law system of a court to decide the law and a jury to decide the facts. BlacksIone, recognizing the question, Creditor, or partner ? as the ultimate inquiry; seeking for nothing but the understanding of the defendant and Robinson on that question ; not constructing “ a partnership as to third persons’’out of a creditorship inter sese, — inferred, from the defendant’s “profit or premium” being a limited and certain sum, that they
In Hoare v. Dawes & a., 1 Doug. 371 (1780), the ground of action was, that the defendants, who, with others, had employed a broker to buy tea, were liable as partners. The verdict was for the defendants. Lord Mansfield, before whom the case was tried, reported the evidence for the consideration of the whole court, on a motion for a new trial. And the court, weighing all the evidence, and coming to the conclusion that, as a matter of fact, the defendants were not partners with the others, were satisfied with the verdict.
In Coope & a. v. Eyre & a., 1 H. Bl. 37 (1788), is an authority against a literal and unqualified sharing-profit test; and also goes far to show that Grace v. Smith is opposed to such a test. It appeared at the trial that “the defendants, Eyre for himself and partners (who were Atkinson and Walton, general merchants), Eattersley' for himself and Stephens, who were oil merchants, and Pugh for himself and son, who were also oil merchants, agreed to purchase jointly as much oil as they could procure, on a prospect that the price of that commodity would rise. That Eyre should be the ostensible buyer, and the others share in his purchase .at the same price which lie might give. Hattersley & Co. were to have one fourth, Pugh one fourth, and Eyre & Co. the remaining moiety ; that they bought large quantities of oil belonging to other ships and other traders besides the plaintiffs, in the name of Eyre & Co.; that Eattersley and Pugh occasionally came forward and gave directions as to the delivery of the oils, and otherwise interfered in the transaction, and also made many declarations £ that they were all jointly interested in the different purchases, and that there was a general concern between them'.’ * * Lord Loughborough, after declaring his opinion (that, as the defendants did not appear to have been jointly concerned further than the purchase of the oil, they had not such a joint interest in the profit and loss as the law made nec.essary to a partnership), directed a verdict to be found for them, which was accordingly done.” Gould, J., in his opinion, speaks of££ the jury having found for the defendants.” Whether the verdict was ordered, or the jury adopted Loughborough’s opinion distinctly announced to them, is not important. English judges sometimes, without absolutely ordering a verdict, express their opinion of' the evidence alone, or the evidence and law together, in a positive manner that is practically equivalent to ordering a verdict; and sometimes, in such and in other cases, on motions for new trials, the distinction between conclusions of law and conclusions of fact is not clearly recognized.
In the argument of a motion for a new trial, in Coope & a. v. Eyre & a., it was asserted by the defendants that, “in Hoare v. Dawes and Grace v. Smith, it is established as essential to a partnership, either that there should be a contract to share profit and loss, or that the parties should offer their joint credit to the vendor.” The plaintiffs
Loughborough, C. J., said he still continued to think the defendants were not liable as partners; “the vendor can have no remedy against any person with whom he has not contracted, unless there be a partnership. * * In order to constitute a partnership, a'communion of profits and loss is essential. The shares must be joint, though it is not
“ Communion of profit and loss ” is civil law language, and means a certain condition of partnership, that is presumed, in the absence of a stipulation to the contrary (1 Domat 1, 8,1, art. 8, 9; Stoiy on Part., sec. 62), as between the partners, without regard to third persons. Sicuti lucrum, ita damnum quoque commune esse oportet. Societas cbm contrahitur, tarn lucri, quám damni communio initur. Loughborough had not forgotten the civil law which he had studied and practised in Scotland. (Joope a. v. Eyre a. shows that, in 1788, the court of common pleas (their attention being particularly called to Grace v. Smith, decided iu that court thirteen years before, and one of the judges who decided it still remaining on the bench) did not understand that a literal and unqualified sharing-profit test had ,been established in that or in any other case.
“A partnership is a joint understanding to share in the profit and loss.” If there is no estoppel, the question is whether the defendants “ considered themselves as partners.” Saville v. Robertson, 4 D & E. 720, 727, "28. When Ashhurst, J., in that case, speaking of the liability of “ dormant partners,” says, — “There the party furnishing the goods may resort to all those who are entitled to share in the profits; for though in such case the dormant partners may not be known at the time of the contract, yet,” when discovered, they are liable, — he does not lay down a sharing-profit test in conflict with his definition of a partnership, “ a joint undertaking to share in the profit and loss.” “ To share in the profits ” was an elliptical repetition of his previous expression “ to share iu the profit and loss.” Sharing profit and loss is a different thing from sharing profit, when the sum of the losses exceeds the sum of the profits.
“ Though, in point of fact, parties are not partners in trade ; yet, if one so represents himself, and by that means gets credit for goods for the other,” both are liable. De Berkom v. Smith, 1 Esp. 29 (1798)
The chief justice begins by saying, that, if there were an annuity granted out of a banking house, to the widow, for instance, of a deceased partner, it would not make her liable to the debts of the house. This can mean no more than that an annuitant is not necessarily a partner. A partner might stipulate for an annuity instead of any other form of benefit. But an annuity is not a common, kind of partnership interest; and the widow of a partner does not usually take his place in a hanking house. In the supposed case, the annuity, the nature of the business of the house, and the sex of the annuitant, would he circumstances tending to show that she was a creditor and not a partner.
The second part of Eyre’s opinion relates to estoppel. “ The definition of a partnership cited from Puffenborf is good as between the
The third part of the report of Eyre’s opinion has caused this case to be considered a leading one. In its general tone, this third part is a continuation of his previous statement of estoppel. If his remarks were accurately reported, he said, — “ It is plain, upon the construction of the agreement, if it be construed only between the Carvers and Giesler, that they were not nor ever meant to be partners. They meant each house to carry on trade without risk of each other, and to be at their own loss. * • * That was the agreement between themselves. But the question is, whether they have not by parts of their agreement constituted themselves partners in respect to other persons. The case, therefore, is reduced to the single point, whether the Carvers did not intitle themselves, and did not mean to take a moiety of the profits of Giesler’s house generally and indefinitely, as they should arise, at certain times agreed upon for the settlement of their accounts. That they have done so, is clear upon the face of the agreement: 'and, upon the authority of Grace v. Smith, ho who takes a moiety of all the profits indefinitely, shall, by operation of law, be made liable to losses, if losses arise, upon the principle that, by taking a part of the profits, he takes from the creditors a part of that fund which is the proper security to them for the payment of their debts. That was the foundation of the decision in Grace v. Sviith, and I think it stands upon the fair ground of reason. * * If, therefore, the principle be true, that he who takes the general profits of a partnership must of necessity be made liable to the losses, in order that he may stand in a just situation with regard to the creditors of the house, then this is a case clear of all difficulty. For though, with respect to each other, these persons were not to be considered as partners, yet they have made themselves such with regard to their transactions with the rest of the world. I am therefore of opinion that there ought to be judgment for the plaintiff.”
The apparent meaning of the report is, that, as “ between the Carvers and Giesler,” “ they were not nor ever meant tobe partners;” that, “ upon the authority of Grace v. Smith, he who takes a moiety of all the profits indefinitely, shall, by operation of law, be made liable to losses, if .losses arise, upon the principle that, by taking a part of the profits, he takes from the creditors a part of that fund which is the proper security to them for the payment of their debts: that was the foundation of the decision in Grace v. Smith, and I think it stands upon the fair ground of reason; ” and that, “ though with respect to each other, these persons were not to be considered as partners, yet they have made themselves such with regard to their transactions with the rest of the world.” According to the report, Eyre professed to follow “ the authority of Grace v.Smith,” and “the principle” which “was the foundation of the decision in Grace v. Smith.” He intended to invent no new law. He meant to be governed absolutely by a particular precedent, and “ the principle ” of that precedent. He distinctly stated that precedent, and “ the principle ” of it. He is not to be charged with the introduction of new law, when he avowed his passive obedience and implicit submission to authority. The doctrine which he reverently accepted was “ the principle that, by taking a part of the profits, he takes from the creditors a part of that fund which is the proper security to them for the payment of their debts.” He said that was the doctrine of Grace v. Smith, and he thought it stood “ upon the fair ground of reason.” It will be quite time enough for us to accept or reject this doctrine, when we are informed what it is, — what DeGrey meant by it, and what Eyre supposed DeGrey meant. When there is but one creditor, the question does not arise: the question arises when a defendant, as well as a plaintiff, claims to be a creditor. If there are several creditors, every one of them (except the one last paid) who takes a part of the fund, capital or gross profits, on which he relies for payment, takes a part of the fund on which other creditors (one or
“ The foundation of the decision in Grace y. Smith ” was, that the question, Creditor, or partner ? was the test of the defendant’s liability to the plaintiff, and that that question did not appear to have been erroneously decided by the jury in favor of the defendant. The dark reported saying of DeGrey about taking a part of the fund on which creditors rely, whatever archaeological interest it may possess, would be uninteresting if it were now put forth for the first time. As a literary curiosity, it may receive some attention: as a legal proposition, its meaning and value have never been satisfactorily made out. It is no matter of wonder if, occasionally, a loose, unconsidered, extemporaneous remark of a fallible judge, as understood, abridged, and hurriedly thrown upon paper by an unofficial, volunteer reporter, who perhaps did not “ write short-hand nor very quickly ” (1 Doug, x, preface), is, upon critical examination, found unintelligible.
Decided in the same court, and reported in the same volume with Waugh v. Carver, is the case Benjamin v. Porteus, 2 H. Bl. 590. The question is whether one Bennett, a broker, who was to have a share of profit, is a competent witness, or whether lie is rendered incompetent by being a partner. It is argued on one side, that “ he was to have a profit on the sale, not as a broker, but as a partner; ” and on the other side, that he “ was nothing like a partner, as there was no communion of profit and loss.” The court, deciding the question by the weight of the evidence, is divided in opinion. Eyre, C. J., thinks “here the agent takes a profit in fact as a principal: ” Heath and Rooke, J. J., think he takes it “ as a broker, and not as a principal.” This case is important, not as an authority on the test of partnership liability, but as showing that Eyre (as well as DeGrey) recognized the distinction between taking profits “ as a principal,” and taking them as a creditor. And when, in Waugh v. Carver, he repeated DeGrey’s remark about taking profits, — and when it is apparent he did not mean taking profits as a creditor, — what could he mean but taking them as a principal ? If that is his meaning, there is no difficulty in the authorities. The objection to this explanation is, he is reported to have said that, as between the defendants, “ they were not nor ever meant to be partners:” but this was said with reference to, and as synonymous with, the next sentence, — “ They meant each house to carry on trade without risk of each other, and to be at their own loss.” He might have meant that, inter sese, they were not partners in the sense of being, inter sese, chargeable with the losses of both houses, although they were principals who jointly carried on the business of both houses. He might have meant that persons are not fully and strictly partners (according to the
This explanation has the support of high authority. In Cox v. Hickman, 9 C. B. (N. S.) 47, 92, 95 (1860), Lord Cranworth said, — “A right to participate in profits affords cogent, often conclusive, evidence that the trade in which the profits have been made was carried on in part for and on behalf of the person setting up such a claim. But the real ground of the liability is, that the trade lias been carried on by persons acting on his behalf. When that is the case, he is liable to the trade obligations, and entitled to its profits, or to a share of them. It is not strictly correct to say, that his right to share in the profits makes him liable to the debts of the trade. The correct mode of stating the proposition is, to say that the same thing that entitles him to the one makes him liable to the other, namely, the fact that the trade has been carried on on his behalf, i. e., that he stood in the relation of principal towards the persons acting ostensibly as the traders, by whom the liabilities have been incurred, and under whose management the profits have been made. * * I can find no case, in which a person has been made liable as a dormant or sleeping partner, in which the trade might not fairly be said to have been carried on for him, together with those ostensibly conducting it, and when therefore he would stand in the position of principal towards the ostensible members of the firm as his agents. This was certainly the case in Waugh v. Carver, 2 H. Bl. 235. There, Messrs. Carver, who were ship agents at Portsmouth, agreed with Giesler, a ship agent at Plymouth, that, if he would establish himself as a ship agent at Cowes, they would share between them the profits of their respective agencies in certain stipulated proportions. "When, therefore, Giesler, in pursuance of the agreement, did establish himself at Cowes and there carry on the business of a ship agent, he in fact carried it on for the benefit of Messrs. Carver as well as of himself ; and the court held that, in these circumstances, the stipulation which they had entered into, that neither party to the agreement should be answerable for the acts of the other, was .a stipulation which they* could not make, so as thereby to affect third persons. Each firm was carrying on business on account not only of itself, but also of the other firm : this, therefore, made each firm the agent of the other.”
By “ taking a part of the profits,” DeGrey and Eyre may have meant (if their meaning reached a mature and definite shape) “ taking a part of the profits as a principal; ” and their idea of creditors relying on profits for the payment of their debts may have been a generality too crude, superficial, and vague to be practically applied to the details of evidence, or to any specific point of a case. Whatever they meant, it is certain they did not mean that a creditor relies on or takes a part of the net profit left after he is paid, or that a creditor, taking part of the gross profit, as a creditor, in payment of his debt, thereby becomes
Wilkinson v. Frasier, 4 Esp. 182 (1802), was assumpsit, brought against the captain of a whale ship, by a sailor, to recover his share of the produce of a whaling voyage. By the articles, the proceeds of the voyage were to be divided in certain proportions between the owners of the ship, the officers, and crew. The proportion of a common sailor was a one hundred and ninetieth part. At the trial, the defendant objected that the action could not be maintained because the plaintiff and defendant were to be paid out of the profits of the voyage, and were therefore partners. But “ Lord Alvanley said, He would not nonsuit the plaintiff on such an objection : That the plaintiff, and the other sailors, were hired by the defendant and the owners, to serve on board the ship for wages to be paid to him; and the share was in the nature of wages, unliquidated at the time, but capable of being reduced to a certainty on the sale of the oil, which had taken place: and that he should not therefore consider them as partners, but as entitled to wages to the extent of their proportion in the produce of the voyage.” There was a verdict for the defendant. This case only shows there was no partnership inter sese: but all the authorities agree that, in such a case, the sailors are not partners as to third persons, and are not liable for the implements they use or the food they consume. Mair v. Glennie, 4 M. & S. 240, 244; Rice v. Austin, 17 Mass. 197, 206 ; Parsons on Part. 81, n.- They do substantially the whole work of the voyage; they, and the officers and owners of the ship, are to have shares (“ casual, indefinite, and depending on the accidents of” the business) of the profits of their labor and capital invested in what is, in a certain sense, a common enterprise and joint concern : yet the sailors are. not partners inter sese or quoad alios, because they neither share in the profits, nor have anything, nor do anything in the business of the voyage, as principals. They are to have shares of the profits as creditors, not as partners.
Hesketh v. Blanchard, 4 East 144 (1803), was assumpsit for money paid. The plaintiff had bought-goods, on the credit of himself and the defendant’s testator (Robertson), to be disposed of by Robertson, the profit to be equally divided between them. The plaintiff brought this action to recover what ho had paid for the goods. A verdict was taken for the plaintiff by consent, subject to the opinion of the court. The objection, that the action could not be maintained because the plaintiff
Dry v. Boswell, 1 Camp. 329 (1808), throws a light upon the meaning of Ellenborough in Hesheth v. Blanchard. It was “Assumpsit for work and labour, and materials in and about the repairs of a lighter. Plea, the general issue. There was no doubt as to the repairs being done; and the only question was, whether the defendant was liable for them. The witnesses first stated that the lighter was the sole property of a person of the name of Russell; that she was let out by him to the defendant, who worked her; and that the two shared her profits equally between them. Lord Ellenborough said, in that case the defendant was to be considered a partner, and was jointly liable for the rep.airs done to the lighter : there was here a participation of profit and loss, which constituted a partnership. But the agreement with Russell subsequently appeared to be this, that the defendant, in consideration of working the lighter, should receive half her gross earnings, and that Russell, as owner, should receive the other half. Lord Ellenborough observed that this was only a mode of paying the defendant wages for his labour, and was different from a participation of profit and loss; so that under these circumstances no partnership could be considered as existing between him and the owner of the lighter.” When it appeared that the defendant was entitled to a share of net profits, — a fund which a creditor, as such, cannot be entitled to a share of, and cannot rely upon, — Ellenborough held him to be a partner: when it appeared that he was entitled to a
Wish v. Small, 1 Camp. 831 (1808), exhibits the distinction between a partner’s and a creditor’s share of profits: but the understanding of the parties on that point appears to have been inferred froimthe evidence by the judge, and not left to the jury as it should have been.
Ex-parte Garland, 10 Ves. 110 (1804), a bankruptcy case, was a petition by the assignees of Margaret Bellman, a widow, whose husband had by will directed her, as executor and trustee, to continue to carry on his business, the profits to be applied for her own use and the maintenance and education of his children. The widow, continuing the business, became a bankrupt; and this petition was for an order declaring the whole of the personal estate liable to the debts contracted by her in carrying on the trades of a miller and farmer under the directions of the will. Lord Eldon refused to make the order.
Barton v. Hanson, Tibbs & a., 2 Taunt. 49 (1809), was an action brought to recover the price of some hay and corn. The defendants “ were generally concerned as proprietors of a stage-coach running from Hastings to'London. They divided the road between themselves into different quarters; and the separate proprietors were severally the owners of the horses which drew the coach through their respective districts, and of the harness ; and severally provided their stabling, food, and horse-keepers in those districts. The defendants, Hanson' and Tibbs, were the proprietors of the horses which drew the coach in the Lamberhurst quarter. * * None of the other partners had any property in these horses, or contributed to furnish them with corn or hay. The goods in question were delivered for the use of these horses” at a stable owned by the plaintiff and occupied by Hanson. “ The profits arising from the coach were divided among the defendants in proportion to the number of miles which they respectively drew it. Best, Serjt., for the defendants, contended, on the authorities of Savile v. Robertson, 4 T. R. 720, and Coope v. Eyre, 1 H. Bl. 37, that the
This case, as reported, is a strong authority against a sharing-profit test. The remark of the chief baron, at the trial, that, as all the defendants shared the general profits, “ all might be liable to pay for the goods furnished for the purpose of producing that profit,” in view of the authorities already examined, seems to present the idea that all the defendants were liable if they shared the profits of the entire stage line, from Hastings to Lendon, as joint principals; otherwise,-not. The case seems distinctly to show that, in 1809, Waugh v. Carver was not understood by the eminent counsel, nor by the judges, who might be supposed to understand the reported decisions of their own court, to establish a sharing-profit test. At the trial of Waland v. Elkins (1 Stark. 272), before Gibbs, C. J., in 1816, “Best, Sérjt., referred to the case of Barton v. Sanson, 2 Taunt. 49, in which it had been held that for corn supplied for the use of the horses of a stage-coach belonging to several proprietors, but horsed severally for specific stages, that proprietor alone was liable who supplied the horses by which the corn had been used.” But Gibbs, C. J., said, — “ I recollect the case very well, but the decision there turned upon the inferior contract (if I may so term it) between the parties. In that case there was a particular contract between the parties, and it was known in what situation they stood with respect to each other. Such contracts are binding upon the pai'ties, but they make no difference in their relation to the public.” From what is said in another report of Waland v. Elkins (Holt, N. P. 227), it seems that Gibbs held the defendant to be a partner with one Dyson inter sese ; and perhaps he understood the defendants in Barton v. Sanson were partners inter sese, and therefore partners quoad alios, except so far as others were .aware of their agreement that each should
In other cases, Barton v. Hanson has been understood to be an authority against a sharing-profit test. In Wilson v. Whitehead, 10 M. & W. 503 (1842), Parke, B., spoke of “the ordinary case of coach proprietors, where each horses the coach for one or more stages, and each agrees to bring into the concern the work and labour of his horses, and none of the others has any interest in them, though all share in the profits.” Upon counsel suggesting that “ Those cases proceed on the ground that it is notorious to all that each does so work with his own horses,” Parice replied, “Not at all; but on the ground that such is the authority given,” — ^tliat is, on the ground that the proprietors do not authorize each other as agents to buy for all as joint principals or partners. In Kilshaw v. Jukes, 3 B. & S. 847, 871, 872 (1803), Wightman, J., in a written opinion, questioning the decision in Wilson v. Whitehead, spoke of the case “ of stage-coach proprietors, where each horses the coach with his own horses for one or more stages, in which case the proprietors of the coach are not jointly liabl e for provender supplied to the horses of each, as decided in Barton v. Hanson, 2 Taunt. 49,” without expressing any doubt of the soundness of the decision or the accuracy of the report of the latter case.
In Gouthwaite v. Duckworth & a., 12 East. 421 (1810), Duckworth was held to be a partner with the other two defendants, and liable to the plaintiff for goods sold, on the ground that he was to share the profit and loss of a joint adventure, and the goods were bought of the plaintiff for all the defendants as joint principals in the adventure.
Eldon’s description of the person who is not a partner is a plain description of a creditor. “As a reward of his labor ” is an illustration thrown in to apply the description to one class of creditors as an example. His description of the person who, he says, “is a partner,” is a description of a partner. His “ specific interest in the profits ” is the same as DeGrey’s “specific lien upon the profits.” “ Profits themselves, as profits,” of course are meant to be contrasted with profits, not as profits, but as something else. What else can they be (when somebody is entitled to them not as profits) but profits as a reward of labor, as compensation for anything as the payment of a debt, as the
It was natural for a chancellor to refer to a bill in equity for an account of profits as one of the rights of a partner. But as such a bill may be maintained by persons not partners, and not liable as partners, it is not a test of partnership liability. “ In cases where there is a remedy at law, there is no small confusion and difficulty in the authorities ” as to equity jurisdiction of account. There are English authorities which assert that it exists where discovery is material, necessary, and effectual. But “ there are other authorities in the English courts which conflict with this doctrine; and which, without attempting to lay down any rule for a practical discrimination as to cases within and cases without the jurisdiction, seem to deliver over the subject to interminable doubts. The doctrine now generally (perhaps not universally) held in America is, that in all cases where a court of equity has jurisdiction for discovery, and the discovery is effectual, that becomes a sufficient foundation upon which the court may proceed to grant full relief.” 1 Story Eq., secs. 455, 456. Where a salary is payable to a. servant in proportion to the profits of his employer, the question whether the servant has a right to go into equity for an account and payment, in lieu of suing at law, depends upon whether
In Wightman v. Townroe, 1 M. & S. 412 (1813), executors improperly continued to carry on the partnership business of the testator for the benefit of his infant daughter. The legal title was in them. They bore profit and loss for tire infant, not for themselves. The infant could not be a principal. They were the principals personally liable for the debts. In Meyer v. Sharpe, 5 Taunt. 74 (1813), the court, from certain circumstances, drew the inference of fact that the intention of. certain persons interested in an adventure, and sharing the profits of it, was, that they were not partners.
Waland v. Elkins (1 Stark. 272—S. C., Holt, N. P.227,1816) was an action on the case against the defendant, the proprietor of a wagon, for the negligence of his servant, the driver, who had driven the wagon against a cart which stood in a public street, and had forced the cart against the plaintiff’s shop window, which was thereby broken. The defendant and one Dyson were carriers from London to_ Gosport. The defendant provided the wagon. Dyson found horses and drivers from London to Farnham: the defendant found horses and drivers from Farnham to Gosport. When the plaintiff’s window was broken, the wagon was drawn by Dyson’s horses-driven by Dyson’s servant, who was hired and paid by Dyson, and with whose employment the defendant had no concern whatever. At the trial, Gibbs, C. J., is reported to have said, — “ The action is maintainable on this principle: the wagon belongs to Elkins ; he has the profit of the carriage. On what terms he engages with other persons to horse the wagon, we cannot tell. It is sufficient that he is found to be a partner in a common concern, and jointly interested with Dyson in the profits. It is of no importance how Elkins and Dyson apportion the carrying business between them. The servant is engaged to drive the wagon for Elkins, as well as for his immediate employer Dyson. Though by the subordinate contract between the partners he is the servant of one, yet, in the contemplation of the law, and for all purposes of legal responsibility, he is in the employ of both.” The report does not show that the question of partnership was passed upon in this nisi prius ruling. The judge seems to have taken it for granted that the defendant evidently
Cheap v. Cramond, 4 B. & Ald. 663 (1821), was decided upon the authority of Waugh v. Carver. Abbott, C. J., delivering the opinion of the court, said the principle of the decision in Waugh v. Carver was, “ that where two houses agree that each shall share with the other the money received in a certain part of the business, they are, as to such part, partners with regard to those who deal with them therein, though they may' not be partners inter se. By the effect of such an agreement, each house receives from the other a part of that fund on which the creditors of the other rely for payment of their demands, according to the language of Lord Chief Justice Db Grey in the case of Grace v. Smith, 2 Sir W. Black. 998. And such an agreement is perfectly distinct from the cases put in the argument before us, of remuneration made to a traveller, or other clerk or agent, by a portion of the sums received by or for his master or principal, in lieu of a fixed salary, which is only a mode of payment adopted to increase or secure exertion.” And he mentioned other instances where, as a matter of fact, the relation of creditor and debtor, and not the relation of partners, would be inferred. The decision practically amounts to this: Waugh v. Carver is conclusive authority: it establishes the principle that persons sharing profits are partners, except in those cases in which they are creditors : whether they are creditors or partners, the court, invading the province of the jury, decide as a question of fact upon the evidence in each particular case.” The publication of such decisions tends to confusion, because, while they lay down no legal rule, they are not ^announced and reported as decisions of questions of fact.
In Fromont v. Coupland, 2 Bing. 170 (1824), there was no controversy about the plaintiff’s claim. The only question was, whether the defendant could set off against it his own claim against the plaintiff. The plaintiff and defendant had “ been engaged in running a coach from Bath to London, the plaintiff finding horses for one part of the road, and the defendant for another, and the profits of each party were calculated according to the number of miles covered by his own horses. The plaintiff received the fares, and rendered an account
In Smith v. Watson, 2 B. & C. 401 (1824), one question was, whether Gill, who was to have a share of profits, was a partner with Sampson, inter sese, in regard to certain property. Among the remarks of Mr. Justice Bayley are the following: “ It is said that the jury ought, up
In Dickinson v. Valpy, 10 B. & C. 128 (1829), there was a partnership called the Cornwall and Devonshire Mining Company, organized with directors, treasurer, and secretary, and with shares of stock, like a corporation. The action was brought to hold the defendant as a partner by the plaintiff, as endorsee of a bill of exchange drawn by the company on itself. The defendant had applied to the secretary for thirty shares, and ton were appropriated to him. Upon these shares he paid an instalment of 51. per share, and received script receipts. He afterwards paid a second instalment of 10Z. per share, signed a deed, and attended a meeting of the shareholders. At the trial before Burrough, J., the defendant objected, first, that there was no evidence to show that the defendant ever actually became a partner in interest,
This idea of authority as the test of partnership liability (when there is no estoppel, and the person sought to be charged on a contract, did not make it in person), is the idea of the liability of A, on a contract made by B, -authorized by A to make it for and in behalf of A, i. e., the
When, in 1860, in Gox v. Hichman, 8 II. L. Cas. 268 (S. C., 9 C. B. (N. S.) 47, 88-102),it was held by Campbell, Brougham, Oranworth, Wensleydale, and Chelmsford, that “ The liability of one partner for the acts of his copartner is, in truth, the liability of a principal for the' acts of his agent; ” that “ The law as to partnership is undoubtedly a branch of the law of principal and agent; ” that upon the question of agency — the question of the authority of one- person as agent to make a contract binding another as principal — “ we must look at the real
Fox v. Clifton, 6 Bing. 776 (1830), was assumpsit against seven defendants to recover a debt due the plaintiff from the “ Imperial Distillery 'Company,” the plaintiff claiming to hold the defendants as partners. It was tried before Tindal, C. J., who submitted to the jury three questions: “ 1st, Whether, when the contract was entered into with the plaintiff, all the defendants were, as partners, entitled to a share of the profits of the concern: 2dly, Whether, if this were an inchoate partnership, the defendants had legally withdrawn themselves from the concern before the partnership was complete: 3dlv, Whether, in such case, they had held themselves out as partners.” The first question recognizes a distinction between being entitled to a share of the profits “ as partners,” and being entitled to a share not as partners. The jury found a verdict for the plaintiff, which the court set aside on the ground that, under the circumstances proved, the directors had no authority to bind the defendants. Tindal, C. J., delivering the opinion of the court (after holding there was no evidence of an estoppel) upon the main question whether the defendants were actually partners, said, — “ The question, therefore, becomes this, Whether, at the time of this contract made by the directors, the relation between the defendants and them was such that the directors were constituted the agents of the defendants to bind them by their contracts.” This is the doctrine of Cox v. Hickman, stated with a precision that leaves no room for a doubt of the meaning. In the course of the opinion, the chief justice says, upon the question “ whether a partnership was actually formed, we think, if the right to participate in the profits of a joint concern is to be taken, as undoubtedly it ought to be, as a test of a partnership, these defendants were not entitled at any time to demand a share of profits, if qirofits had been made, inasmuch as they had never fulfilled the conditions upon which they subscribed. We think the matter proceeded no further than that the defendants had offered to become partners in a projected concern, and that the concern proved abortive before the period at which the partnership was to commence: and, therefore, with respect to the agency of the directors, which is the legal consequence of a partnership completely formed, we think the directors proceeded to act before they had authority from these defendants.” While he says the question of liability when there is no estoppel is the question of agency and authority, he also recognizes a sharing-profits test in the form of “the right to participate in the profits of a joint concern,” meaning, by “the profits of a joint concern,” the net profits of a concern of joint principals.
Upon a second trial of Fox v. Clifton, 9 Bing. 115 (1832), the jury
In ex parte Chuck, & Bing. 469 (1832), there was an undisclosed partner entitled not to “ any definite aliquot proportion of the profits,” but to a certain sum annually “ out of the clear profits,” — “ clear profits” being used in the sense of the profits left after paying all creditors.
In Green v. Beesley, 2 Bing. N. C. 108 (1835), the declaration was held bad on demurrer, because it alleged a communion of profit and loss between the plaintiff and the defendant that made them partners. Tindal, C. J., said, — “ I have always understood the definition of partnership to be a mutual participation in profit and loss.” If by “ a communion of profit and loss” is meant a joint ownership of the gross profits left after making up all losses and paying all debts, it is a sufficient proof of the relation of joint principals: but the phrase is often used in a very indefinite sense.
In Owen v. Body, 5 A. & E. 28 (1836), it was held that a certain assignment for the benefit of creditors, with a stipulation for the assignees continuing the debtor’s business, and appropriating the profits to the payment of such creditors as should sign the assignment, was invalid, because it might be construed to create a partnership among the creditors signing it. Creditors were not bound to accept the assignment with the possibility of the court holding the true construction of it to be that the creditors accepting it would be interested as principals in carrying on the business. - Janes v. Whitbread, 11 C. B. 406, 417, 418, 419; Coates v. Williams, 7 Exch. 205, 206; Cox v. Hickman, 18 C. B. 617, 632, 634-638 — S. C., 3 C. B. (N. S.) 523, 528, 538, 541, 558, 559 — S. C., 9 C. B. (N. S.) 47, 86, 101.
In Bond &a. v. Pittard, 3 M. & W. 357 (1838), the question being whether the plaintiffs were partners, Patteson, J., told the jury that, to constitute a partnership, there ought to be a community of loss as
Wilson v. Whitehead & a., 10 M. & W. 503 (184-2), was assumpsit for paper sold and delivered; and was an attempt to hold liable, as partners, the defendants who were to share the profits of publishing a review. The chief baron, in directing a' nonsuit, and the court of exchequer (Abinger, Parke, Gurnet, and Rolfe), in refusing to set it aside, may have taken the place of the jury in drawing an inference of fact. Park-é, B., said the question- was one of authority, — “ Did- the other defendants authorize Whitehead to purchase the paper on their account?” This is the doctrine of agency — the doctrine of Cox v.JIicJcman, in the decision of which casé, eighteen years afterwards, Parke and Rolfe (as Lords WensleydaLe and Oranworth) took part.
Pott v. Eyton, 3 C. B. 32 (1846), was assumpsit by the assignees of bankrupt bankers, brought to hold the defendants, Eyton and Jones, as partners. Jones was defaulted. An agreement liad been made between the defendants for opening a shop, principally with a view of supplying goods to the workmen of Eyton’s colliery. Eyton built the shop, and his name was placed over the door. Jones sold the goods. Eyton received a certain per cent. of the amount of sales to his workmen ; and Jones had the rest of the profits. Tindal, C. J., left it to the jury to say, first, whether there had been a sharing of profit and loss between Eyton and Jones, so as to constitute ah actual partnership ; secondly, whether Eyton had been, by his own permission, held out as a partner, and his credit pledged to the bank. The jury, answering both questions in the negative, returned a verdict for the defendants; and the court being of opinion that the verdict was right, the plaintiffs’ motion for a new trial, on the ground of the verdict being against the evidence, was denied. Tiñdal, C. J., delivering the opinion of the court, says, — “ There was no evidence to show that credit was in fact given to Eyton, or that the bankers knew that his name. was over the door of the shop at Mostyn Quay, or that they supposed him to be a partner. * * We must assume, therefore, that credit was given to Jones alone; and if Eyton is to be made liable, that must be on the ground of an actual partnership between himself and Jones. It was contended that an actual partnership was proved, for that Eyton, by taking 51. per cent, on the sales to his workmen, received a share of the profits, and was therefore, in point of law, a partner as to third persons. But we are of opinion that the taking of that money was not sufficient to make him a partner. Traders become partners between themselves by a mutual participation of profit and loss; but, as to third persons, they are partners if they share the profits of a concern ; for, he who receives a share Of the profits, receives a part of that fund upon which the creditors of the concern have a right to rely for payment, and is therefore to bo made liable to losses, although he may have expressly stipulated for exemption from them. Grace v. Smith, 2 W. Bl.
The remark of Parke, B., in McAlpine v. Mangnall, 3 C. B. 496, 516 (1846), that creditors, for whose benefit a debtor’s assignment is made and his business continued, are not responsible as partners to persons furnishing goods for carrying on the business, may be questionable. It does not recognize a sharing-profits test of liability: but whether creditors, who become parties in„sucli an arrangement, are joint principals in the business carried on, with their assent, for their benefit, — whether it is their business, conducted by their agents authorized to make necessary contracts binding them as principals, — is a question that is not disposed of by rejecting a sharing-profits test.
Barry & a. v. Nesham and Lowthin, 3 C. B. 641 (1846), was assumpsit to recover for goods alleged to have been sold to the defendants as partners in the publication of a newspaper. Lowthin was defaulted. A verdict was taken for the plaintiffs, subject to the opinion of the court upon the evidence : if the court should be of opinion that the plaintiffs were entitled to maintain the action, the verdict was to stand ; otherwise, to be entered for the defendant Ncsliam. (In cases brought up for decision in this manner, in the English practice, the court frequently pass upon the weight of the evidence, much as if the case were tried by the court without a jury, and the distinction between law and fact is not observed ; and if the court infer partnership from sharing profits, the question remains whether the inference is one of law or fact.) The plaintiffs argued that the real question was, whether Nesliam was entitled to a part of the fund on which creditors relied for the payment of their debts (citing, to that point, Grace v. Smith and Waugh v. Carver), and claimed that “ This court, in the recent case ot
In Heyhoe v. Burge, 9 C. B. 431 (1850), the question was, whether the defendant was liable as a partner with others, with whom, or from whom, lie was to receive a share of the clear profits arising from a contract to construct a piece of railway. At the first trial, Pollock, C. B., told the jury that, if they believed the written agreements to be the agreements which they purported to be, “ they ought to find that the defendant was interested in the profits, and consequently a partner.” “ The jury accordingly returned a verdict for the plaintiff,” which the court (Coltman, Maulé, Cresswell, and Williams) set aside. The decision (delivered by Coltman, J.) was this: “ It appears to the court that there was in this case a question of fact which ought to have been submitted to the jury, viz., whether the defendant had assented to the agreement of the 5th of August, 1846. We think that the omission to present that to the jury, and dealing with the whole as a question of law, was a miscarriage, and, consequently, that the rule should be made absolute for a new trial.” At the second trial, Mr. Baron Parke presided. A part of his charge to the jury occupies seven and a half pages of the report. The jury found a verdict for the plaintiff, which the court refused to set aside. Parke “ left the question to the jury on the whole of the evidence, — not leaving it that that instrument (the principal written agreement relied on) constituted a partnership: on the contrary, he said it would not.” The reporters say that, in presenting the case to the jury, he told them that the first question for them to consider was, whether there was a partnership between the defendant and Fly and Frost, — whether he entered into a contract with them to share in the profit and loss of the particular adventure; that, if the defendant did actually agree, by a binding contract, to take a share of the profits of the adventure, in point of law he was a partner, and authorized everything that was necessary for the purpose of carrying the contract into effect, and constituted Fly and Frost 1ns agents for the purpose of entering into any sub-contracts which might be necessary for that purpose. The report goes on to give Parke’s own words. Among the observations appearing to be in his own language are the following : “ This agreement purports to give the defendant a fourth part of the clear profits, not the gross profits of the contract. A person who shares gross profits is not a partner; but a person who shares net profits is prima facie to be considered as a partner. * * Upon the whole of the facts, taken together, the question will be, whether you are satisfied that this was a binding agreement, * * that the defendant should have a share of the net profits of carrying into effect this particular contract. If you are not satisfied of that, there is an end of the plaintiff’s case, because the whole rests upon the inference to be drawn, of the defendant’s being a partner in the profit and loss of the contract. If he is" not a partner in the profit and loss, then the defendant is entitled to your verdict. But, if you are satisfied that he was a partner in the contract, then the defendant is, I
Such are the most important English cases, before Cox v. Hickman (1860), relating to the subject of a sharing-profits test. Whatever loose general notions may have been entertained as to the effect of these cases, they do not establish such a test in an unqualified form. They cannot be arrayed as a mass of authorities overruled by Cox v. Hickman and the subsequent cases, which have settled the law, for England, that sliaring-pi’ofits, in a general unlimited sense, is not a test.
Neither is such a tost established by a preponderance of the weight of American cases, decided without reference to Cox v. Hickman. The subject has been much considered in Massachusetts ; and the result is far from being a simple, absolute sharing-profits test. Reynolds v. Toppan, 15 Mass. 370; Rice v. Austin, 17 Mass. 197; Baxter v. Rodman, 3 Pick. 435; Grozier v. Atwood, 4 Pick. 234; Cutler v. Winsor, 6 Pick. 335; Turner v. Bissell, 14 Pick. 192; Benny v. Cabot, 6 Met. 82; Bradley v. White, 10 Met. 303; Holmes v. O. C. R. R., 5 Gray 58; Bitch v. Harrington, 13 Gray 468; Julio v. Ingalls, 1 Allen 41; Gunnison v. Langley, 3 Allen 337 ; Pratt v. Langdon, 12 Allen 544 — S. C., 97 Mass. 97. Sometimes such a test seems to be recognized with the qualification “ as a principal.” Loomis v. Marshall, 12 Conn. 69; Berthold v. Goldsmith, 24 How. 536, 542; Collyer on Part., Book 1, ch. 1, sec. 25; Story on Part., secs. 49, 54, 55. Of course, if one shares profits “as a principal,” i. e., in the capacity of a principal,lie is a principal; and so he is if he does anything else in that capacity.
When sharing-profits is accepted as a test, it is almost universally with this qualification, that if the profits are received as compensation for services, or payment of any debt, sharing them is not a test. The
The sharing-profits test, in this modified form, enveloped in and consolidated with its mass of qualifications and exceptions, — the only form in which it can be claimed to be established by the authorities, — is nothing but the elementary doctrine of the liability of a principal, disclosed or undisclosed, on an authorized contract made by his agent, — which is the doctrine of Cox v. Hickman, and the subsequent English cases. Cox v. Hickman, Beavan 164; 25 L. J. Ch. 142; 18 C. B. 617; 3 C. B. (N. S.) 523; 8 H. L. Cas. 268; 9 C. B. (N. S.) 47; Kilshaw v.
In the supposed case of flour trade, where A is to have one ninth of the profit, if it is net profit that he is to have a share of, he is to have it, not as a creditor, but as an owner; the net profit, in cash, specifically ascertained,- identified and deposited by itself, is the joint property of A and B before it is divided ; it is the residue of the proceeds of the sales ; all those proceeds, as well as that residue, were the joint property of A and B; the flour which produced those proceeds was their property ; it was bought and sold by them as joint principals ; the title passed from C to A and B, and not to B only; B, in buying it, acted as agent of A as well as for himself; by the contract of purchase, made by B as a joint principal and agent of A, A is bound as a principal. If we begin with net profit, as the result and test, and cite, in support of it, the cases usually grouped under Waugh v. Carver, net profit leads us back to the relation of'principal and agent (the doctrine of Cox v. Hickman) as the starting-point. If we begin with the relation of principal and agent, it leads us forward, over the same course, to net profit as the result. Eor legal and practical purposes, it is one route.
In Cox v. Hickman (and in other cases) there was a difference of opinion as to the construction of an assignment of property to trustees for the benefit of creditors, which provided for the continuance of the debtor’s business, and the appropriation of the profits to the payment of creditors. The question, Who were the principals in the continued business? was rendered difficult by the complicated nature of the assignment. Whether the final decision of that question of construction was right or wrong, is not material in the present case. The same question would have arisen under the sharing-profits test. By the true construction of the assignment, were the profits to be received by the creditor as creditors, or as joint principals and partners in the continued business ? The insertion of the word “ profits ” in the question does not cause the difficulty of the question to vanish.
Lord Cranworth said a right to participate in profits, “ no doubt, is in general a sufficiently accurate test; for, a right to participate in profits affords cogent, often conclusive, evidence that the trade in which the profits have been made was carried on in part for, or on behalf of, the person setting up such a claim.” Cox v. Hickman, 9 C. B. (N. S.) 92. By a “ sufficiently accurate test,” he meant satisfactory evidence. His remark suggests how easily a piece of evidence could be transformed into a legal test sub modo, by tribunals accustomed, as English courts are, to declare their judgment on questions of fact. When Lord Cranworth said sharing-profits affords cogent evidence of
“ A partnership, in which the entire profit was to belong to some of them in exclusion of others, would be manifestly unjust; and, as between the parties themselves, it would not be a proper partnership. It would be what the Roman lawyers called societas leonina,m allusion to the fable of the lion, who, having entered into a partnership with the other animals of the forest, in hunting, appropriated to himself all the prey.” 3 Kent Com. 29; Story on Part., sec. 18. This is civil law doctrine: it relates wholly to the force, effect, and validity of partnership inter sese, and has no reference to the rights of third persons. If it were a doctrine of the common law, it would go to show that the contract of a societas leonina is void 'inter sese, and not that the parties are liable to third persons. But it is not to be admitted, without deliberation, that there is any such doctrine in the common law. “ It may be said, says Mr. Baron Bramwell, in Bullen v. Sharp, L. R. 1 C. P. 126, 127, “that, if this reasoning is right, a man might bargain to receive all the profits of a business, and not be liable. The answer is, the thing is impossible. There never was, and never will be, a bona fide agreement by one man to carry on a business, bear all its losses, and pay over all its profits. Should such an agreement appear, it would obviously be colourable.” Suppose a New Hampshire merchant, having gained a sufficient estate in trade, and desiring to continue his business for the industrial and charitable purpose of supporting a missionary in Ceylon, gives him a bond to pay him all the future profits of his business; and suppose the profits are called “ net profits ” in the bond : was there ever a court that would hold the missionary liable as a partner for the goods bought by the merchant in carrying on his business ? It would be evident that they both understood the missionary to be a creditor and not a partner; that, by “ net profits,” they meant the surplus of gross profits left after paying all other creditors of the business; and that, in the literal sense, there would be no net profits of the business. Why should the missionary be liable, especially seeing he was not to defraud the other creditors, but only to receive the balance of profits left after they were all paid ?
The result of this examination of the authorities is, that the instructions given to the jury, in the present case, were erroneous. There is a provision in the reserved case, that, if there is error in the instructions as to the effect of a division of the gross receipts, judgment is to
"The following portions of the examination of Mr. Commissioner ]?ane, before the select committee on the law of partnership, printed by order of the House of Commons, 8 July, 1851, place the fallacy of the reasoning in Grace v. Smith and Waugh v. Carver in very strong light: * * ‘ I see no evil in any part of the law of partnership, except that by which it is established that he who contributes to the funds of an undertaking, on the terms of sharing in the profits, is liable, as a partner, to all the engagements of the partnership to “his last acre and last shilling,” although he does not disclose his name; but in that I consider that there is the greatest evil, because its tendency is to prevent capital coming forward to aid industry, ingenuity, and enterprise. Capital without industry is dead, and so is industry without capital. It is the union of the two out of which all wealth arises. It seems, therefore, most impolitic to discourage that union by saying to each accumulator, You shall not risk any portion of your accumulations for the aid of struggling industry or struggling ingenuity, on the terms of sharing in profits, if profits there be, without risking every farthing you have
It is admitted on all hands that he might have ad vane, the same sum at 52., 102., 202., per cent, interest, and incurred no risk beyond his advance ; ffiy should he not be permitted to advance it for a share of profits, and incur no further risk ? What difference is there between interest and profit, but that interest is certain and profit uncertain ? What is interest but a fixed share of profit'! Why should asking for interest involve no liability whatever, and asking for profit involve liability absolutely boundless ?
In the early part of my professional life, circumstances induced me to study the law of partnership, and I found this strange provision in it. I was so startled and amazed that I set about tracing it to its source, and then I discovered that it had, properly speaking, no foundation at all. I traced it to a case decided in 1793, on the alleged authority of a case decided in 1775, which last not only did not affirm it, but actually negatived the liability of the alleged partner.
The case in 1775 was Grace v. Smith, 2 W. Blackstone’s Hep. 998. There Grace endeavored to make Smith, who had retired from a partnership some years before, responsible for a subsequent debt of the partnership, on the ground that he, on retiring, had stipulated for a share of the profits. The counsel who argued for the plaintiff, to support his argument, took from his pocket what, in the language of our profession, is called pocket-pistol law, that is, a manuscript account of an unreported case, which he said had been decided á few months or weeks before by Lord Mansfield,- — Bloxham v. Pell, — in which Lord Mansfield had decided in a similar case that the retired partner was liable. This argument and case, however, produced no effect, for Chief Justice DkGrey and the three other judges held that the defendant was not liable. Similar attempts to make persons responsible for debts, as dormant partners, were repeated in 1780, in Hoare v. Davies, 1 Doug. Hep. 371; and again in 1788, in Coope v. Eyre, 1 H. Blacks. 37, but they failed; nor was it till 1793 that the doctrine was established. In that year, the ease of Waugh v. Carver, 2 H. Blacks. 235, was heard. Two houses, who acted as agents for ship-owners, had agreed to assist each other in procuring agencies : and it was agreed that they should divide the profit of a portion of their agency business. The two houses were entirely distinct, and had no other connection with each other than the above, which was secret. One carried on business at Cowes, the other at Gosport. The' Cowes house failed, whereupon a creditor of that house sued the Gosport house for goods sold and delivered to the Cowes house ; and, having obtained a verdict subject to the opinion of the court, the case was argued before the full court, and judgment given for the plaintiff. In giving judgment, Lord Chief Justice Byre admitted that the two houses “ wore not, nor ever meant to be, partners ; ” that they had no “idea that either was to be involved in the consequences of the failure of the other;” and that they did not understand “ themselves responsible for any circumstances that might happen to the loss of either.” But, said he, “ that was the agreement between themselves. But the question is, whether they have not, by parts of their agreement, constituted themselves partners in respect to other persons. The case, therefore, is reduced to the single point whether the Carvers did not intitle themselves, and did not mean to take a moiety of the profits of Giesler’s house, generally and indefinitely, as they should arise, at certain times agreed upon for the settlement of their accounts. That they have so done is clear upon the face of the agreement; and, upon the authority of Grace v. Smith, he who takes a moiety of all the profits indefinitely, shall, by operation of law, he made liable to losses, if losses arise, upon the principle, that, by taking a part of the profits, he takes from the creditors a part of that fund which is the proper security to them for the payment of their debts. That was the foundation of
It must surely be admitted that the decision in that case was most unreasonable, because the creditor, when parting with his goods, had never looked to the Gosport house for payment, nor had the Gosport house ever voluntarily undertaken the liability; so that two contracts were invented by tho law, — a contract by thecreditor to sell and deliver to the Gosport house, and a contract by the Gosport house to pay, — neither of which had been dreamed of by the parties concerned. This is not the function of law. The function of law is not to invent contracts, but to find out what contracts men have really made, and enforce their due performance.
The result of this case has been a series of contradictory decisions, the judges sometimes affirming the false political economy of Waugh v. Carver, and sometimes setting it aside, as leading to results perfectly absurd. A late writer, — Gow on Partnership (edition 1830), — after commenting on the decisions, says, p. 20, — “Nominally, there is a discrepancy between the cases, but in what the substantial difference consists, it is not easy to determíne; ” and he adds, — “It would be presumptuous to canvass or question the propriety of distinctions which have obtained the sanction of so many enlightened judges.” The matter, however, is too important in a public point of view to excuse slavish submission to authority without inquiry, and I hope, therefore, I shall stand excused, if I venture to discuss the reasoning in Waugh v. Carver, What was it ? It was, that “ he who takes a share of the profits of a business, takes part of the fund on which creditors rely for payment.” 'Can anything be conceived more false? Creditors neither can nor do roly on profits for payment. Profits do not exist till creditors are paid. Look at any individual transaction: A sells goods to B for 10(M.; B resells them for 1KM. There is 1(M. profit. Does the creditor look to this 1(M. for the payment of his I00¿. ? No ; he looks to the 100Í. That sum would pay him, and is the proper fund to pay him. The I0£. would not. The KM. evidently belongs to B, and is the fund to enable him to pay the outgoings of his trade, and subsist himself and his family. If, therefore, any creditor did. look to the profits of a trade, as his fund for payment, he would be a most unreasonable person, for he would wish that his customer, and his customer’s wife, family, and servants, should all starve, profits being tho only fund they have to live on.
But, if the principle, that he who takes part of the profits of a business ought to be responsible to the creditors of tho business is a right principle, it ought to be carried out fully, and then it would involve other and very serious consequences; for, upon that principle, every annuitant on a business, and every creditor who charged exorbitant interest for the'use of money lent, ought to be responsible to creditors ; for they certainly do take part of the fund to which creditors look. They are entitled to be paid even though no profits are made. And so, again, if the head of a house determine to pay his managing clerk a salary equal to one tenth of the profits, the managing clerk ought to be responsible to creditors, for he also would take a share of the fund on which creditors are supposed to roly for payment; but bore the .law is staggered by its own conclusions, and hence it has been held by a distinction, which Lord Elbon has spoken of as “extremely thin” (exparte Hamper, 17 Vesey 404), that a servant so paid is not a partner.
The truth is, that the decision in Waugh v. Carver was not law, but mistaken politi-j cal economy. The only safe principle to go on is this, that those and those only are responsible to creditors, who either arc partners, or have publicly declared themselves as such, and have thus authorised all who deal with the partnership to consider and rely on them as partners. It may, however, be supposed that the law in question is part of the old law of England, or that it existed in the law of Rome. I do not believe that a trace of it is to be found in either. All the treatises on partnership that I have seen trace the law to Grace v. Smith, and trace it no further.
Then is it reasonable to fasten this extravagant liability, — “ to the last acre and the last shilling,” — on those who are willing to aid industry and enterprise by advances of capital ? Is it a crime to aid enterprise ? What would this country have been without the assistance of the joint stock principle ? Should we have had either canals, or