90 A. 863 | N.H. | 1914
Lead Opinion
A portion of the charges here complained of were on interstate shipments. As to these the defendant alleges that they were collected according to rates lawfully filed and published according to the provisions of the interstate commerce acts. This is a valid defence. It is settled by a line of uniform decisions of the supreme court of the United States, that once schedules are so filed and published, the sole remedy of the shipper is by a complaint to the interstate commerce commission. This jurisdiction cannot be infringed upon by previous contract of the parties, nor by *227
statutes enacted by the states. It cannot be defeated directly or indirectly. The subject has been so fully considered by the tribunal whose exclusive province it is to finally declare the law pertaining thereto, that any discussion of it here is superfluous. Adams Express Co. v. Croninger,
Substantially all the arguments now advanced to support the plaintiffs' claim were presented in the cases above cited. It is useless to attempt to consider them here. The law upon a federal question has been fully elucidated by the federal court of last resort, and it only remains for the state courts to apply it to the cases in hand.
If the rates here filed contravened the terms of a contract made with the state by the defendant, or were contrary to the provisions of a state statute theretofore existing, the contract or the local law must yield to the power of congress to act upon the subject. The question what effect this may or may not have upon the leases and contracts of union made under the state statute is one which the present controversy does not present. As the validity of the defence is so clearly settled by federal authority, it is not necessary to now determine whether the statutes here under consideration were or were not intended to apply to any part of interstate carriage.
No conclusion has been reached as to the other questions involved in the case. The decision of this point is announced at this time, as it is understood that the state and the defendant desire to take action upon the subject under the statute passed by the last legislature.
All concurred.
At the January session, 1914, reargument was invited upon the questions which had not been decided in the foregoing opinion, filed June 27, 1913. The case was thereupon reargued in February, 1914.
Concurrence Opinion
1. The principal question presented is one of statutory construction. It is the duty of the court to ascertain from competent evidence what the legislature of 1889 meant when it provided that the "rates for fares and freights existing at the time of the passage of this act shall not be increased on the roads leased or united under it." Laws 1889, c. 5, s. 17; P. S., c. 156, s. 42. Was the phrase "the rates for fares and freights" intended to refer to and designate every individual rate then in existence upon roads that might subsequently consolidate, or was it intended to apply to the aggregate sum that might be received from reasonable rates upon an equitable readjustment of the existing rates? Was the statute intended to operate as an absolute prohibition of the increase of a single rate, however unreasonable, unjust, and discriminatory it might be? If not, then the only other suggested construction of the statute is that it prohibited, not the increase of specific rates, but the increase of the aggregate rates.
2. It is elementary that in the construction of a statute the court must take into consideration, in connection with, and as explanatory of, the language of the legislature, the circumstances existing at the time of its passage relating to the subject-matter involved, which will often show the object or purpose the statute was designed to accomplish and the sense in which its language was used. A citation of authorities upon this point is quite unnecessary.
3. It is conceded that up to 1889, when the policy of the consolidation of the railroads became effective, the protection of the people of the state against the imposition of extortionate rates by the numerous railroad corporations then existing was understood *240
to be largely secured by competition between the railroads, and that the result was that there was little uniformity of transportation charges throughout the state. Where competition was the sharpest, the rates were the lowest; and where there was little or no competition, they were the highest. No rational basis of rate-making, growing out of the cost of the service rendered in a given locality, was adequately recognized. As a rule, the rates were either too high or too low according to the degree of competition. At length it became evident that this competitive policy was a ruinous one both to the public and to the railroads. "For the lessons of experience, as well as the deductions of reason, amply demonstrate that the public interest is not subserved by competition which reduces the rate of transportation below the standard of fair compensation." Manchester etc. R. R. v. Railroad,
4. To promote the interests of the people and those of the railroads, the statute in question was passed. It was believed that better service at a reduced expense would be secured by discarding the competitive method of railroad regulation and authorizing a general consolidation of the existing railroad lines. But in order to make it absolutely certain that the expense to the people of the state would not exceed the expense they then had to pay for the same volume of business done by the consolidating roads, it was provided that "the rates for fares and freights" should not be increased. The fundamental idea was that the state, meaning the people as a whole, should receive better transportation facilities than they had before enjoyed, without any increase of expense for fares and freights. They were not providing for special favors to some shippers and unreasonable burdens to others, but for the protection of the people as a political unit in the expenses of railroad transportation. That such was the legislative conception of the purpose of the statute, under the conditions existing at the time of its passage, would seem to be a reasonable deduction.
5. If the members of the legislature in 1883, when this provision of the statute was first enacted, understood the inequality and injustice of the then existing fares and freights brought about by railroad competition, if this was in fact one of the evils of that method of conducting the transportation business of the state which it was proposed to obviate, it would be strange if they used language in the statute which the court must hold simply continued and sanctioned the old schedules of fares and freights. We must at least *241 give them credit for understanding the general lack of uniformity of fares and freights in the different parts of the state; and upon this reasonable assumption, it would be difficult to find, in the absence of unequivocal language to that effect, that they were dealing with the specific rates then existing, which they desired should remain indefinitely unless reduced under legislative authority. It is unreasonable to infer that their idea was that uniformity of rates should in all cases be secured by reducing all rates for a given service to the lowest rate produced in any part of the state by the disfavored policy of competition, which naturally would be out of all proportion to the service rendered. It is apparent, and it must have been understood by the legislature, that an approximate equality of rates upon any reasonable basis could only result from a general readjustment thereof, increasing some and decreasing others. Unless, therefore, it was the purpose of the legislature to sanction the inequality of rates then existing, it cannot be found that the statute in question related exclusively to specific rates.
6. But if, as is claimed, the legislature of 1889 took no pains to investigate the rate question and knew nothing of the unequal accommodations and charges connected with transportation by rail in this state, it would be a reproach on a coordinate branch of the government for the court to hold that the legislature determined arbitrarily that the various schedules of rates then in force were in every instance sufficiently high, which in the interest of the public and in fairness to the railroads should not be increased in a single instance. It would be a severe reflection on the wisdom of the legislature to say that they came to that conclusion without understanding the facts upon which it was based. If it is conceded that they had little conception of what is called modern classification and scientific rate-making, now resorted to in the business of railway management, it cannot be assumed by the court in construing this legislative language that the legislators were ignorant of the material facts bearing upon the subject in hand, which were patent and not concealed by scientific mystery. It is unreasonable to find from their assumed ignorance of the facts of existing rates and charges that they intended to prohibit an increase of rates in all cases; while if they understood the inequality and the disproportionate charges for fares and freights, as it must be assumed they did, it is absurd to suppose their purpose was to continue them.
7. If there is evidence contained in unauthenticated reports of *242
hearings before legislative committees that indicate that some men thought, or assumed to think, that the statute of 1883 prevented the increase of specific rates, it is of very little weight or importance upon the question of legislative intention. The question is, not what some men thought, or what individual members of the legislature conceived the language to mean, or what individual members of the court might think was most expedient under the circumstances (Pollard v. Gregg, ante, 190, 194), but what was the intention of the legislature as a composite body, expressed in, or fairly inferable from, the language embodied in the statute. The evidence referred to is of doubtful admissibility, and if considered, it is of little consequence; certainly it is far from conclusive. It has been held that the court, in construing an act, will not consider the motives, or reasons, or opinions expressed by individual members of congress in debate, but will look, if necessary, to the public history of the times in which it was passed. Keyport etc. Co. v. Company,
8. When the belief is expressed in argument that the statute would not have been passed if it had been understood that it merely prevented an increase of charges in the aggregate, it might be equally germane to express the belief, in reply, that a distinct understanding that the statute would perpetuate and sanction the former unjust, inequitable, and discriminatory rates would have resulted in its defeat. The expression of a belief either way upon this point is neither helpful nor important.
9. The fact that the legislature of 1883 created a board of railroad commissioners, giving it power "to fix tables of maximum charges for the transportation of passengers and freights upon the several railroads operating within this state" and to "change the same from time to time as in the judgment of said board the public good may require" (Laws 1883, c. 101, s. 4), must be considered in connection with the statute forbidding the increase of rates; and when so considered, the conclusion is greatly strengthened that rates in the aggregate on the uniting roads, and not the individual rates, constituted the subject-matter of the legislation under discussion. Subject only to the prohibition against increasing the aggregate receipts from rates of transportation, the commissioners were fully authorized to readjust the specific rates in accordance *243 with a rational theory of justice to the railroads and equity and fairness to the people. But if the statute referred to specific rates only, it is not easy to see how the commissioners could fully perform the duty imposed upon them. Their duty was "to fix maximum charges" and to "change the same from time to time." Is it probable that the legislature, having prescribed the maximum rates, in the next chapter conferred in words the power to perform the same service upon the commissioners, intending, however, that their language in this respect should be held to mean nothing with reference to the uniting roads? It is very significant that such an intention was not expressed, as it easily might have been in a proviso, condition, or limitation defining the powers intended to be conferred upon the commissioners. The inference follows that the purpose was to empower the commissioners to readjust the transportation charges upon all railroad lines, raising some and lowering others, "as in the judgment of said board the public good may require." Of course, the legislative determination that the public good did not require such an adjustment of rates as would result in an increase of the receipts from the same amount of traffic was a limitation, and apparently the only definite limitation, upon the power of the commissioners with reference to the fixing of rates upon the consolidated roads. In this way unfair and discriminatory rates could be in a great measure avoided; and to accomplish such a result was the exident purpose of the legislature by the legislation of 1883 and 1889.
10. The statute of 1889, like the statute of 1883, also provided, as the concluding part of the section we have been considering, as follows: "And the decrease in the operating expenses consequent upon the leasing or uniting of any roads shall be met from time to time by a reasonable and just reduction of fares and freights." Is there such a difference in meaning between the expression "rates of fares and freights" in the first part of the section and the expression "fares and freights" in the last part, that it can be reasonably said that the prohibited increase applies to specific charges, while the reductions to be made on account of operating expenses refers to the fares and freights generally? No one seriously contends that the decrease in expenses was to be applied pro rata to all the individual fares and freights, but to a "reasonable and just reduction of fares and freights," considered as a whole or in the aggregate. No reason is suggested why these two similar expressions used in a single section of the statute should have two distinct and *244 dissimilar meanings. The presumption is they were used in the same sense and did not relate to special rates.
11. Other reasons of evidentiary importance upon this question of statutory construction of the same general purport as the foregoing could be suggested; but it would seem from what has already been referred to, that the restriction imposed by the statute was intended to limit the rates in the aggregate and not in specific instances. As the phrase in question is ambiguous in view of the subject-matter, I cannot reach the conclusion upon a reasonable construction of the language that the legislature intended to sanction the palpable inequalities and unjust discriminations in railroad rates, which resulted from the operation of an unreasonable competition, and to provide for their indefinite continuance, as a condition for railroad consolidation which it was believed would promote the public welfare.
I therefore concur in the opinion of the chief justice.
Addendum
"The proprietors of every railroad shall furnish to all persons reasonable and equal terms, facilities, and accommodations for the transportation of persons and property over their railroad. . . .
"If the proprietors of any railroad shall not comply with the provisions of the preceding section, they . . . . shall be liable to the party injured for his damages in an action on the case.
"The proprietors of every railroad shall cause to be posted in their depots a table of prices for the conveyance of persons and property. . . . The rates shall be the same for all persons and for like descriptions of freight between the same points." P. S., c. 160, ss. 1, 2, 3.
In answer to the plaintiffs' claim to recover certain sums alleged to have been illegally collected of them for the transportation of lumber, the defendants offer to show that the sums collected were neither discriminatory nor unreasonable in fact, but were the prices fixed for such service by the defendants' regularly established tariff, and which were charged by them to all persons for like service, and that the amounts charged did not exceed a fair and reasonable return for the service rendered. The plaintiffs' motion to reject the brief statement setting forth these facts is an admission for the purposes of the case in this court of the truth of the facts stated therein. Hence the discussion must proceed upon the ground that the sums paid were fair and reasonable and the same as charged others for like service. The question is: Had the plaintiffs a legal right to have their lumber transported for less than others paid, or for less than a reasonable rate? They do not claim a special personal privilege for a lower rate than others, but contend that railroads leased or united under certain statutes are forbidden to charge for the transportation of lumber a higher rate than was charged upon certain dates named in those statutes.
Section 17, chapter 100, Laws of 1883, authorized the lease or union of certain railroads: "Provided, that the rates for fares and freights existing August 1, 1883, shall not be increased on any part of the roads so leased or united, and the decrease in the operating expenses consequent upon the leasing or uniting of any roads shall *229
be met from time to time by a reasonable and just reduction of fares and freights." Chapter 100, Laws of 1883, appears to have been expressly repealed in 1891. State v. Railroad,
The plaintiffs claim "that the restriction is specific and particular, and that it forbids the increase of the charge for the transportation of any particular article of freight above what was charged for the transportation of the same article" (State v. Railroad,
The facts before the court are that the particular charge is a reasonable one, and that the total charge for freight transportation collected and received by the defendants was $500,000 less in each year than the rates of 1883 would have yielded, and the collections for freights and fares $1,000,000 less. In the aggregate, the rates have not been increased, but have been decreased to the extent stated. Upon these facts, in a proceeding by the state to enforce *230
the state's contract in behalf of all the people of the state, it would be difficult to find a violation of the statute which would authorize equitable interference to secure to the plaintiffs an unreasonably low-rate at the probable expense of the rest of the public. State v. Railroad,
The method of statutory interpretation here followed has been so fully explained in recent times that it would be idle to repeat at length the authorities, many of which are set forth in the defendants' brief. The question is what the words used meant to those using them. To ascertain that, the circumstances under which the language was used, the probable purpose, the general policy on the subject, prior legislation upon the subject, the entire legislation at the time, and the reasonableness or otherwise of one construction or the other, are matters competent for consideration. Glover v. Baker,
The legislation of 1883 was a change of policy, authorizing railroad incorporation by general law, substituting consolidation, with regulation by a commission, for enforced competition. State v. Railroad,
In 1850, the legislature provided: "Every railroad corporation in this state shall, in the month of August in each year, agree upon and fix their rates or tariffs of toll for the transportation of freight and passengers over their road. . . . Such corporation shall, on the first day of September in each year, post up at all the stations and depots on their road a copy of such rates or tariff of tolls. . . . Such corporation shall not, for one year after the rates of toll are posted as aforesaid, . . . charge or receive any higher rates of toll, fare, or freight than shall be filed upon and posted as aforesaid." Laws 1850, c. 953, s. 4. In 1852 it was enacted: "Any railroad corporation in this state shall establish from time to time . . . the rates or tariffs of tolls, . . . and the rates thus established . . . shall be the same for all persons and for the like descriptions of freight, . . . and no rates of fare or freight shall be at any time advanced except on thirty days' notice established and posted as aforesaid." Laws 1852; c. 1277, s. 1. The language of either of these sections would have expressed what the plaintiffs claim was meant. These provisions are to be found the General Laws, where, after requiring the posting of a table of prices for the conveyance of persons and property, the statute enacts that "such prices shall not be raised." G. L., c. 163, ss. 1, 2. But the clause in question contains no reference to an existing table of prices or schedule of rates.
Prior to 1883, the legislature had in no instance, it is believed, attempted to regulate rates in detail. If advanced knowledge on the scientific construction of rates renders such a policy wise, there is no evidence such policy was then known to the legislators. The details of rate-making were by the several railroad charters placed in the hands of the directors, with certain provisions by which "the authorized net profits were made the standard of reasonable tolls." State v. Railroad,
"The general statute was not a change of policy, but of method. Its purpose was not to obtain revenue, but to enforce the established policy of the state. The profits of the proprietors of railroads were limited to ten per cent for the sole purpose of securing to the public reasonable rates of toll. . . . Ten per cent annual profits remained, as before, the standard of reasonable tolls." State v. Railroad,
In 1883, the act before referred to, requiring uniformity of rates and equal facilities to all persons, was in force. G. L., c. 163, s. 2. It was not repealed in 1883, but the penalty of five hundred dollars for its violation was that year increased to one thousand dollars, by an act approved the same day as the consolidation statute. Laws 1883, c. 105. In 1879, the legislature prohibited railroads from making a higher charge for transportation by the carload to a station than was charged for like transportation for a greater distance. Laws 1879, c. 55. This provision, omitting the limitation to carload lots, was reenacted in 1883. Laws 1883, c. 100, s. 27. By section 26 of the same chapter, the directors of railroad corporations were required from time to time to "establish reasonable rates for the transportation of passengers and freight over their railroads." By section 4, chapter 101, of the same session (the companion act creating the board of railroad commissioners), it was made the duty of the board "to fix tables of maximum charges for the transportation of passengers and freights upon the several railroads operating within this state, and shall change the same from time to time as in the judgment of said board the public good may require." *233
One other consideration remains: the knowledge available in 1883 of the character of the then existing rates. It is unnecessary to take into consideration the conclusion of the public service commission, reached in 1912 after most laborious and exhaustive investigation, in which the rates existing in 1883 and 1889 are characterized as "inconsistent, discriminatory, and unscientific," as "antiquated classifications and haphazard tariffs." Pub. Serv. Com. Rep., Nov. 30, 1912, pp. 357, 366. If it could be said that the legislation was enacted with the light of this information, it would not require argument or consideration to conclude that, if another meaning could be extracted from the language, the legislature did not intend one which would impose such a condition upon the state. But though such information was not at hand in 1883, it was known at that time that there were a large number of independent railroads in the state. A few of them were operated under joint traffic agreements, but most of them were operated as independent roads, each competing with others for business and making rates at competitive points calculated to get business that naturally belonged to their competitors, making up what they lost on such business by charging those living at non-competitive points enough more than a fair price to make up for their loss on competitive business. Each road was a law unto itself as far as its charges for fares and freights was concerned. It could not have been understood that a uniform system of rates existed over all the roads of the state, or over any one road. The increase in the penalty for inequality of treatment and the reenactment with increased application of the long and short haul statute indicate conclusively that there was dissatisfaction with the existing arrangement of rates. There was more than a suspicion of discriminations for the benefit of favored shippers. The journal of the house (1883, p. 568) shows the introduction of a resolution for an investigation as to any unjust discrimination in fares and freights upon the Boston, Concord Montreal and Northern Railroads.
Upon all this evidence, the conclusion seems irresistible that, in 1883, it was not intended to establish the existing rates as a maximum schedule of prices in detail. If such was the intention, there is no reason why some such term, or the expression "table of prices" found in the statute which was then under amendment, was not used, or why the particular language of the statutes of 1850 or 1852, before referred to, was not employed. It is not without significance that when by the same legislature, and as a part of the same legislation, *234
the duty of establishing maximum rates was imposed upon the railroad commissioners, the duty was defined to be "to fix tables of maximum charges." Laws 1883, c. 101, s. 4. If the legislature had intended to make the existing tables or schedules of charges a fixed maximum in detail, it can reasonably be assumed that they would have used the language they employed in placing the duty as to detail upon the commissioners. The policy of the state as to legislative regulation of freight tariffs had always been, and is now (State v. Railroad,
Although the commissioners were authorized to fix the maximum rates, the legislative definition of reasonableness was not altered. In the judgment of the legislature, reasonable tolls were tolls which did not produce a net income exceeding ten per cent. For the roads leased or united, a new basis was provided — the gross amount of the rates then existing. Upon such interpretation, the, directors could make from time to time reasonable tolls as required by the statute; the commission could establish maximum tolls in detail, changing them from time to time as the public good required; and the provisions for equality to individuals and rates proportionate to service, insisted upon as part of the same legislation, could all be carried into effect. It is obvious that if the roads and the commission were bound to cast-iron schedules in detail, the main legislative purpose of justice and equality could not be carried out unless the basic schedule was originally fair and just, and certain always to remain so. It is also certain that no exhaustive investigation was made in 1883 to ascertain what the rates then were; and it is a reasonable conclusion that the legislature could not have intended to establish the details of those rates as fixed marks for all time, without having first made some attempt to establish their reasonableness and justice. As the law stood undisturbed at this session, railroads were entitled to charge such tolls as would yield a net income not in excess of ten per cent. Few, if any, of the roads earned that income; but united, there would be no legislative barrier in the way of such an increase as would produce such an income, rendering probable a large increase in rates as the legitimate result of consolidation. Some limitation was necessary, and that was found in the amount then being paid for such service. *235
The legislation went further. It being claimed that the proposed consolidation would result in economies in management, it was further provided: "And the decrease in the operating expenses consequent upon the leasing or uniting of any roads shall be met from time to time by a reasonable and just reduction of fares and freights." Laws 1883, c. 100, s. 17. The profit of consolidation was reserved to the people of the state. The privilege of consolidation was granted upon the condition that the cost of transportation should not be increased, and the profit of the change in management be reserved for the people and not for favored individuals or localities. The section itself recognizes justice and reasonableness as the true basis of rates; and it is not probable that the legislature adopted as such basis, as between different individuals and places, tables or schedules of rates which the legislators did not know to be reasonable and just. It cannot be assumed they did not know that changes in conditions in the future might make the existing ratios and classifications unreasonable and unjust. The necessity for change "from time to time" was recognized in the power of fixing rates given the commissioners by section 4 of chapter 101, and to the directors of railroad corporations by a subsequent section of the chapter under consideration (s. 26). It is not probable that the contingency was not foreseen in which justice and reason would require increasing the rate on some subjects of transportation to render feasible lower rates on others.
In argument in favor of the plaintiffs' contention, it is said that there were expressions used by counsel and witnesses at hearings before committees of the legislature and in other places, tending to show that it was understood the prohibition would apply to specific rates. There is little evidence of that character. If there is any and it is competent, the opinions of individual counsel and witnesses as to what a written document will mean when executed, or what they think it means after execution, can be of very little weight. In most instances, the language used is the language of the act and helps neither side. It is to be remembered that the provision originated in 1883. In 1881, the attempt to get a general railroad law failed. In 1883, the controversy was between the Hobbs bill for an unlimited general railroad law, with right of the new railroad to lease generally, and the Colby bill, with its more limited provisions for new railroads and authority for lease and union of existing lines. After the practical failure of the Colby bill, the controversy in 1887, to which most of the documentary evidence *236
relates, was between the Concord and the Boston Maine Railroads over the possession of the Northern and the Boston, Concord Montreal Railroads. This was not a contest between consolidation and competition, but a right to obtain the fruits of the policy of consolidation upon which the state had already entered. Whatever was said in 1887, no legislation was founded thereon. The contest was undecided. In 1889, the territory was, divided by agreement, and the legislation necessary to render the Colby act effective was adopted without a struggle. State v. Railroad,
Upon all the evidence competent for consideration, it seems more probable that the legislature did not intend to make the existing schedules in detail the maximum, but laid down as the measure of reasonableness the gross sum then received for the amount of traffic carried — the average charge per ton per mile. If the defendants can show that from each of the roads over which the plaintiffs' lumber has been transported they have not increased the average charge per ton per mile, they are not guilty of a violation of the statute. The evidence offered is competent. Further offer of proof is made as to decrease in fares. Such evidence is also competent. The expression "fares and freights" is naturally collective. It might not require much evidence to sustain the conclusion that "and" meant "or"; but the sole basis of reasonable rates recognized in the statutes is the tolls from fares and freights together — the net receipts from transportation. There is nothing in the act upon which to differentiate the two sources of revenue. Section 11, chapter 128, Laws of 1844, is based on "net receipts," and section 13 provides for the regulation of "the rates of toll for freight of passengers and merchandise."
It might be urged that this construction gives little protection *237 to the individual shipper. No one feeling that an unlawful toll had been collected of him would be prepared to litigate with a railroad the question of its entire receipts in 1883 and at the time complained of. But the legislature did not give in terms the right of recovery for a violation of the statute by the railroad. If the shipper has such a remedy, it stands upon other grounds than a statute creating it. That no such remedy was specifically given tends to show it was not understood a situation had been created in which such a remedy would be useful. The railroad commission were required to fix "tables of maximum charges," and to "change the same from time to time." By section 2, chapter 5, Laws of 1893, they were required to do so "upon the petition of any party interested." If the plaintiffs felt that they were charged an unjust, unreasonable, or illegal rate, they had a prompt and inexpensive remedy by application to the commission.
It is contended that the question was settled in State v. Railroad,
The question whether the restriction of the act of 1889 and of chapter 156 of the Public Statutes is specific, applying to rates then in force for particular subjects and routes, or general, applying to transportation as a whole, is in this case first presented for decision. Why the defendants did not earlier take this position, as perhaps they might have done, is not material. It may be that, conscious of raises made in certain rates in 1903, they were unaware, until the thorough examination before the public service commission, that they were insufficient to bring the general charge for freight service up to the level of 1889. But for whatever reason the claim was not *239 earlier made, there is nothing which now estops them from making it. As the case is presented, the decision is merely that the evidence offered is competent and that the motion to reject the brief statement should, as to this contention, be denied.
If as a result of the trial it should appear that the defendants have collected of the plaintiffs any sums in excess of the amounts allowed by the statute as hereinbefore construed, the plaintiffs are not prevented from recovering the same because the sums paid were paid without protest. The reasons for this conclusion are fully stated in the opinion filed by Judge Peaslee, in which, upon this point, all the justices concur.
Case discharged.
YOUNG, J., concurred.
Addendum
1. The statutes of this state provide that on railroads leased or united by virtue thereof the rates for fares and freights shall not be increased. P. S., c. 156, s. 42; Laws 1889, c. 5, s. 17; Laws 1883, c. 100, s. 17. The first defence involves the meaning of this provision. It is claimed that the statute does not prohibit the increase of some rates, provided that in the readjustment other rates are reduced to such an extent that there is no increase in the aggregate. I dissent from the decision that this claim is sound.
The two later statutes on this subject (Laws 1889, c. 5, s. 17; P. S., c. 156, s. 42) are merely reenactments of the earlier one (Laws 1883, c. 100, s. 17). State v. Railroad,
The acts of which the language under consideration forms a part marked a new departure in railroad legislation in this state. The *245 earlier policy of protection to the public by competition was abandoned. This result was not brought about until the subject had been thoroughly discussed. There was widespread opposition to the change, and the argument that with competition eliminated there would be added danger of unfair treatment of the public was constantly urged. It was to provide against this danger that the prohibition was enacted. Much of that discussion has been preserved and is to be found in the state library. The three volumes entitled "Railroad Controversy" give some idea of what the people were at that time considering. An examination of this and other collections shows that the thought of the people was frequently directed to specific rates. Counsel who argued before committees of the legislature furnished printed tables showing in detail rates from one point to another. As one witness testified, these tables were prepared so that the individual could see just what the rates from his own town would be under the new law. In the cross-examination of a witness before a committee of the house in 1887, Counsel for the Concord railroad asked: "There is a rate from Manchester to Laconia today?" Being answered affirmatively, he further inquired: "If the law provides that that rate shall not be increased, you will not be injured, will you?" One will search in vain for any suggestion in all that prolonged discussion that any rate was to be raised as a part of a larger readjustment of rates. In the report of the railroad commissioners to the legislature of 1889 (pp. 13, 14), it was stated in terms that the rates on some of the weaker roads were below what would yield any fair return upon the capital invested if they were operated independently; that the stronger roads were willing to agree to keep them there in return for the advantages of consolidation; and it was urged that such offers ought to be accepted by the state.
In view of these facts, it seems highly probable that the legislature in speaking of rates for fares and freights had in mind the specific rates then in force. These rates were definite boundaries. They provided an easily ascertained limit to the power of the railroads. G. L., c. 163, s. 1; P. S., c. 160, s. 3. Remembering that it was with reluctance that the old safeguards were abandoned, and that, whether justly or not, the people of the state were suspicious of every move toward consolidation, there would be every reason to expect that some such definite limitation upon the power to levy tolls would be insisted upon.
It may be conceded that the schedules then in effect were *246 unscientific and discriminatory. But the only remedy then suggested was lowering the higher charges. The people of the state insisted upon assurances against any increase of rates, and the only prospective changes suggested by the representatives of the railroads were reductions. It can readily be surmised what the fate of these proposed statutes would have been if it had been publicly stated that the term "the rates for fares and freights" meant the aggregate of all rates, and that quite likely a good many rates would be raised.
Nor does the other provision of these acts, that the decreased cost of operation, incident to consolidation, shall be met by a decrease of rates for fares and freights, militate against the conclusion that the limitation of maximum charges applies to specific rates. If by reason of decrease in operating expenses it became equitable to reduce rates, the fact that no rate could be increased would not seem to interfere with the just decrease demanded by the new situation.
It is to be borne in mind that these statutes were not enacted by those expert in the present-day science of rate regulation, but by the New Hampshire legislators of thirty years ago. They thought and expressed themselves in the light of the knowledge of this subject then possessed by men in general. Whatever defects in their acts the larger knowledge of the present day and the experience of the intervening time may show were not apparent to them. The thought evidently uppermost in their minds was that the people were to be protected against any increase of rates. This they sought to express; and their intent to make the prohibition specific does not, to my mind, admit of serious doubt.
It is further argued that the provision of the companion act (Laws 1883, c. 101), giving the railroad commissioners power to fix maximum charges on all railroads, conflicts with the conclusion here reached. But there would seem to be no difficulty in making both acts effective. If occasion arose to alter rates within the permitted limit, the commissioners might so act. And as to railroads not leased or united under these statutes, the commissioners were free to act without such limitation. When the commissioners first acted under this law, they made sure that the rates in force in 1883 had not been increased on any lessor or lessee road, before giving their approval to the rate proposed. R. R. Comm'rs' Rep., 1886, pp. 18, 19.
The suggestion that the rates fixed were established for all time *247 is not entitled to very serious consideration. Relief could be granted by any legislature, as indeed it was granted by the last one. Laws 1913, c. 106. The great point in mind was that the state proposed to retain the fullest control of the situation. It intended to have a control which was of practical value, as distinguished from a merely theoretical one. It intended also to reserve to each individual shipper a real weapon of defence against an increase of rates — of his rates, if one chooses to put it that way. This was the consideration given by the roads for the privilege of consolidation. The rates then discussed were the definite, individual sums for individual pieces of service. This is what the railroad commission talked about in its report of 1889, urging the state to close a bargain whereby the rates on the weaker roads would be fixed. There was no suggestion then that this fixing of rates was to be made inefficient by a process of dilution. There was no hint that these rates were to be averaged with all the rates of all the system (no matter how great the system should become) before there could be any determination of how the facts were as to an increase. Rates were thought of and talked about as units.
And this is the fair, sensible, non-technical meaning of the language used. To the mind of the average New Hampshire legislator, the term "the rates for fares and freights" means the table of prices charged by the road. It is believed that no one thought the statute meant anything else until within a very few years. As late as 1909 it was said, in an opinion in which all the justices concurred: "It appears that it was intended to limit the power to increase rates on roads leased or united under the act to the maximums stated in the schedules referred to in section 17." State v. Railroad,
Much time has been spent, upon both sides, in discussing the mere scholastic question of the fit construction of words. Unquestionably, some logical argument for either conclusion is to be found. But the case ought not to be, and is not, decided upon a nice balancing of fine deductions. What is the central reason urged by the majority in the foregoing opinions? It seems to me to be this: the conclusion reached is held to be the correct one because it gives the best results for the state. In varying forms, the evils to flow from the conclusion that the rates referred to are specific rates are dwelt upon, until they are made to appear so great that the majority deem it impossible to think that the people of the state could have intended such consequences. This was the whole tenor *248 of the last argument for the defendant. It is improbable, they say, that the state could ever have desired or contemplated such a situation. It is somewhat remarkable that such arguments should be made the basis for the decision of this case, in view of the fact that all the while the state appears here as a party and insists that it desires the result which the majority of the court think the state cannot desire.
There is considerable evidence how the state has viewed the question in the past. It is all one way. The first recorded official utterance is the report of the railroad commissioners in 1885. In informing the legislature of what had been done under the act of 1883, they say (pp. 18, 19): "The assurance was given by the Boston Maine, and we have no evidence showing the contrary, that the rates existing on the leased lines and on the roads of the lessee have not been increased. No increase could lawfully take place under the act of 1883." Again, in 1889, the commission advised the legislature in the following significant language (p. 14): "Our state has great advantage of position and circumstance in railroad matters, which it should avail itself of while it can be done. Because the managers of two wealthy corporations desire to extend their power and control by building up railway systems in which our roads must be links, they are willing to take these roads upon terms which make them, for the time being at least, sources of loss instead of profit. Because they want our business and what goes with it, they offer to do it at cost or less, trusting to the indirect benefits that may accrue to them from doing a largely increased traffic upon their own roads to balance the draft upon their treasuries from our northern lines. We should take them at their word." It is certainly fair to presume that the legislature acted upon this advice. It passed the act of 1889 with full information that rates were unequal and that the purpose was to keep them so until the higher ones were reduced. This is what the evidence shows the legislature thought. And as before stated, the position of the state in all the litigation growing out of these acts has been that this is their meaning. If there is any evidence that a different view has ever been expressed by the state, it has not been found.
These considerations seem to me to show that the assumption of the majority has no sufficient foundation. That assumption imputes to the legislatures of 1883 and 1889 a knowledge that a statute applying to specific rates would be fantastic, irrational, and in every way unjust. But the evidence is that all the advice given *249 by the state's railroad experts of those days was to the effect that such a law ought to be adopted. At the same time, counsel for the roads were urging upon the legislators the fairness and equity of the provision they now denounce. There is nothing to show that it was ever suggested to the legislators of 1883 and 1889 that a law applying to specific rates would be unjust. The majority opinions disregard all this evidence and seek to show by abstract reasoning alone the legislators' state of mind.
It is to be assumed, the majority say, that these legislators knew this and that, and, so knowing, must have concluded the law would be impolitic. As before suggested, one sufficient answer to this proposition is that the people of today know the situation well, and yet they are insistent in their demand that the law as to specific rates be retained. This was the sentiment of our recent legislatures. This is the view of our public service commission, whose indictment of the general rate situation is the basis of the last argument here for the defendant. This is the practical answer the theoretical proposition that everybody must understand that the law is undesirable and unjust.
Nor is this the equivalent for a construction of statutes by plebiscite. The question being what certain words mean to certain men, we must know how those men use words. If we would interpret the phrase of the street, we must be wise in the vernacular.
The majority, having become convinced in their own minds that a statute relating to specific rates would be unjust, conclude that other men must be of the same mind. This erroneous conclusion as to the mind of others might not be important in most cases. It is important here because it is the basis upon which the majority conclusion is made to rest. The argument is that since all men must think the law unjust and impolitic, therefore such result could not have been intended. The chain being no stronger than its weakest link, and the error as to the mind of others being one link, the conclusion lacks support.
Herein is the real difference of opinion in this case: The majority believe reasonable men generally must think a law applying to specific rates undesirable. The minority deny that such opinion exists, or has existed in the past, and believe that there is satisfactory evidence of a different public and legislative opinion. Starting with these fundamentally different views, it is almost inevitable that we should arrive at different conclusions in the interpretation of the statutes. *250
2. Another defence here made is that there is no private right of action for a violation of the terms under which leases of railroads are permitted by the state. The statute is in effect an amendment to the railroad charters, which the corporations were at liberty to accept or reject. State v. Railroad,
There was no occasion to insert in the acts of 1883 and 1889 a specific provision for a right to private redress. The existence of the right must have been well understood after the decision in McDuffee v. Railroad, supra. And section 28 of the act of 1883 furnished further evidence that this was then the legislative understanding. That section provides a penalty for a violation of the long and short haul limitations in the preceding section. It introduces the provision in this language: . . . "in addition to liability for all damages sustained by reason of such violation, shall be liable for each offence to a penalty," etc. The defendant argues that this shows a legislative intent to give a private action for a violation of section 27 and to deny it as to others, as to which the act is silent. But this is not the language ordinarily used to create a right. It is rather that employed to express knowledge of a right already in existence. It was used here to prevent the defence being made that the imposition of the penalty evidenced an intention to take away the existing private right. If it had been the intent to here create a private right, the same language would have been used that was employed the same day in the reenactment of another statute upon the same subject. "Every railroad corporation . . . shall be liable to a penalty . . . and to the party aggrieved in an action of damages." Laws 1883, c. 105. The legislature of 1883 understood how to express the creation of a right in positive *251 terms. They understood equally well how to express a mere acknowledgment that a right existed. They recognized that this act was to be more than a mere private compact between the state and the railroads, and that damages to individual rights would be caused by its violation.
It is not reasonable to suppose that legislators, who were manifestly seeking to provide every safeguard against the possibility of unfair treatment of the people of the state, would give the shipper an action for damages if he could prevail upon the debatable issue of whether a rate was reasonable (P. S., c. 160, ss. 1-3) and deny him relief in a case where the rate charged was in violation of the express terms of an act to which the offender had agreed. The legislature was seeking new safeguards. It was with a view to giving added means of protection that larger powers were given to the railroad commissioners. Laws 1883, c. 101, s. 5. It was not the intent to make those remedies exclusive. State v. Railroad,
3. The third defence is that the payments here sought to be recovered were made voluntarily and without protest. In answer to this, the plaintiffs say that under the facts in this case the conclusion as to whether the payments were voluntary is one of law, and that the law is against the defendant. It would be of little assistance, in the subsequent trial of the cause, to merely decide that voluntary payments cannot be recovered, while involuntary ones may be. The real question which will present itself at the trial is what does or does not constitute a voluntary payment.
It is the settled law of the state that money voluntarily paid (that is, without coercion of any kind) cannot be recovered back (Keazar v. Bank,
"Money paid to one who, because of his position, is under an obligation to discharge certain duties to the public, but who refuses to discharge such duty without the payment of a sum of money, to which he is not entitled, can be recovered as money paid under compulsion." Keener Quasi-Cont. 437. This proposition is fully sustained by the English authorities. Dew v. Parsons, 2 B. Ald. 562; Steele v. Williams, 8 Exch. 625; Parker v. Railway, 7 M. G. 253. In this country the weight of authority seems to be the same way. Chase v. Dwinal,
The rule is applicable to common carriers because of the similarity of their position to that of one holding a strictly public office. "A common carrier is a public carrier. He engages in a public employment, takes upon himself a public duty, and exercises a sort of public office." McDuffee v. Railroad,
The principles upon which these cases were decided have been applied in this jurisdiction to a variety of situations. The rule here is that excessive payments made under agreements with public officers may be recovered back, even when made "voluntarily." Edgerly v. Hale,
This principle has a general application to statutes prohibiting certain contracts, when the "contracts are prohibited by statute to *254
protect one set of men against another." If "for that reason, or some other of like character, the parties are not par delictum, the law will lend its aid in favor of the innocent party, as in the case of usury." George v. George,
In some of the cases it appears to have been deemed an important fact that the plaintiff did or did not pay under protest; but this seems largely immaterial in cases of this class. The distinction has not been recognized in the cases in this state; and in each of those where a recovery has been upheld, it appears, either in terms or by necessary inference, that there was no protest. "If, independently of protest, the circumstances in which a payment is made would not justify a recovery thereof, the fact of payment under protest will not render such payment involuntary." Keener Quasi-Cont. 423, note 4.
As stated in the defendant's brief, the sole object of a protest in these cases is that it evidences the plaintiff's state of mind. It gives notice that he intends to claim his right to a repayment. The only cases where such notice would seem to be of importance would be those where the defendant had subsequently changed its position in reliance upon the validity of the payment. There is no suggestion of such a defence in the brief statement filed in this case, and Ford v. Holden,
PLUMMER, J., concurred in the foregoing opinion. *255