28 F. 553 | U.S. Circuit Court for the District of Northern New York | 1886
The motion by the defendant for a new trial raises the questions whether the contract in suit was void as one in restraint of trade, and whether the correct rule of damages was given by the judge in his instructions to the jury. The facts, so far as they are necessary to the consideration of these questions, may be briefly stated. The parties were competitors in the business of manufacturing and selling washing-machines throughout the United States, the plaintiff’s place’of business being at Cincinnati and the defendant’s at Troy. They were the principal, but not the only, manufacturers in this country. In January, 1882, in order to obviate the consequences of competition with each other, and secure better prices and better profits, they entered into an agreement to divide the profits on all sales made by each, upon the basis of a fixed manufacturers’ price and selling price upon machines, during the term of five years. Among other things, by the terms of the contract, (1) the plaintiff promised to deliver to the defendant such “Dolph Standard” machines as the latter should order, from time to time, at the price of $110 each, and the defendant promised to take at least 50 of such machines in each year; and (2) the plaintiff was to have the option of manufacturing all machines sold by both parties, at the price of $110 each for the “Dolph Standard” machine, and at such prices for other machines as might be bid for them in open competition by any other responsible manufacturer for equal quality of goods. After the parties had proceeded under the contract for one year, the defendant terminated it by notice to the plaintiff. During the remaining four years of the contract both parties sold many of the “Dolph Standard” machines at prices ranging from $110 to $175 each. During these years the plaintiff was ready and willing to comply with the provisions of the contract. The- evidence was that during these four years the plaintiff could have manufactured the machines at a cost, to himself of from
The judge denied an instruction, requested for the defendant, that the contract was void, as being one in restraint of trade. Upon the question of damages, ho instructed the jury that the plaintiff was entitled to recover what he.would have realized had the contract been performed, taking into consideration what ho would have made in the future if ho had been permitted to carry it out, as well gains prevented as losses sustained, provided they were certain, and such as naturally followed from the breach of the contract. Referring to the 50 Dolp'h Standard -washers which the defendant had agreed to take for each of the four remaining years of the contract, he instructed the jury that the plaintiff was at all times ready and willing to furnish these machines, and could have done so at a cost to himself varying from $45 to (592.50 each, and by doing so would have made a pro'it consisting of the difference between the cost and $110, the contract price. Respecting the other machines, he instructed the jury that the plaintiff was entitled to recover the difference between the price the defendant paid other manufacturers for such machines, or tho cost of the machines to the defendant when manufactured by itself, and the sum for which the plaintiff could have manufactured them. He refused to instruct the jury, as requested by the defendant, that the rule of damages was the difference between the contract price and the market value of the machines at the times at which they were to have been delivered. Exceptions were taken by the defendant to the instructions given, and to tho refusal to instruct as requested.
Assuming that, in entering into the contract, the parties contemplated that the defendant should cease manufacturing machines, and buy all its machines from the plaintiff, and that the only purpose in viewr was to promote the interests of the parties, and enable them to obtain from customers higher prices for the machines, it is not obvious how such a contract contravenes any principle of public policy. Washing-machines, although articles of convenience, are not articles of necessity. The scheme of tho-parties did not contemplate suppressing the manufacture or sale of machines by others. Those who might be unwilling to pay the prices asked by the parties could find plenty of mechanics to make such machines, and the law of demand and supply would effectually counteract any serious mischief likely to arise from the attempt of the parties to get exorbitant prices for their machines. It is quite legitimate for any trader to obtain the highest price he can for any commodity in which he deals. It is equally legitimate for two rival manufacturers or traders to agree upon a scale of selling prices for their goods, and a division of their profits. It is not obnoxious to good morals, or to the rights of the public, that two rival traders agree to consolidate their concerns, and that one shall discontinue business, and become a partner with the
“Public policy requires on the one hand that a man shall not, by contract, deprive himself or the .state of his .labor, skill, or talent; and on the other hand-that he shall be able to preclude himself from competing with particular persons, so far as necessary to obtain the best price for his business or knowledge when he chooses to sell it.”
Upon the question of damages, the effect of the instructions given, and those refused) was to direct the jury that the measure of damages for the breach of the contract was the difference between the contract price and the price which it would have cost the plaintiff to make and deliver the machines, irrespective of the market value of 'the machines during the period of the contract. The general instruction with which the judge prefaced his directions to the jury, that the plaintiff was entitled to recover as damages what he would have realized had the contract been performed, including as well gains prevented as losses sustained, was undoubtedly a correct statement of the law. One of the most recent eases in which it was reiterated is U. S. v. Behan, 110 U. S. 338; S. C. 4 Sup. Ct. Rep. 81. It was there held that where one party enters upon the performance of a contract, and incurs expense therein, and, being willing to perform, is, without fault of his own, prevented by the other party from performing, his loss will consist of two distinct items of damages: First, his outlay and expenses, less the value of materials on hand; and, secondly, the profits he might have realized by performance. In applying this rule to the facts of the particular case, the courts have sometimes used language which is liable to misconception, if understood to be the rule which ordinarily applies in the case of a contract for the future delivery of articles which have a market value. Thus, in the leading case of Masterton v. The Mayor, 1 Hill, 69, the language.of the syllabus is:
“The measure of damages in respect to so much of the contract as remains wholly unperformed is the difference between what the performance would have cost the plaintiff and the price which the defendant agreed to pay.”
See, also, the language of Curtis, J., in Philadelphia, W. & B. R. Co. v. Howard, 13 How. 344.
The error of the instructions in the present case consists in adopting these expressions literally, and applying them to a ease where the
The well-settled rule of damages for the breach of an agreement to sell and deliver personal property at a future day is the difference between the contract price and the market value of the property at the time of the delivery called for by the contract. It is quite immaterial whether the article to be delivered is or is not in existence at the time of the contract, or whether it is one to be manufactured, from time to time, as required. This is specifically pointed out in Masterton v. The Mayor, where Beabdsley, J., says:
“In reason and justice, there can be no difference between damages which should be recovered for the breach of an ordinary agreement to buy or sell goods and one to procure materials, lit them for use, and deliver them in a finished state, at a stipulated price.”
In Rhodes v. Cleveland Rolling-mill Co., 17 Fed. Rep. 426, the contract was for the delivery of pig-metal, to be manufactured, and, the defendant having refused to proceed with the contract, it was held that the plaintiff’s damages, ordinarily, would he the difference between the market price and the contract price at the time defendant refused to go on with the contract; hut that plaintiff having tendered the iron after notice that the defendant would not accept, and the price having advanced between the time of notice and. the time of the tender, the plaintiff could only recover the difference between the contract price and the price at the time of the tender. See, also, McNaughter v. Cassally, 4 McLean, 531.
The plaintiff certainly was not entitled to a larger recovery than he would have been entitled to if he had built all the machines w'hich might have been required to carry out the contract. He might then have stored or retained them for the defendant, and sued for the con
What has been said has reference to the instructions respecting the damages recoverable by the plaintiff for the breach of that part of the contract relating to the “Dolph Standard” machines. It is apparent that, under the instructions given, the jury may have awarded the plaintiff damages in excess of the difference betwee'n the market price or value of the machines at the time when their acceptance was called for under the contract and the contract price. The evidence that both the plaintiff and defendant were selling the machines in open market during the whole term of the’ contract, and the prices at which the machineswere sold, authorized the jury to fix the market value. As to the damages recoverable for the breach of that provision of the contract by which the plaintiff was to have the privilege of supplying the defendant with other washing-machines at the lowest price bid by other manufacturers for supplying defendant with the same, it is not clear that the plaintiff could establish any loss of profits, unless it could be shown that there is some usual or average percentage of profit customarily realized by manufacturers of> analogous articles, or some established manufacturers’ price. The plaintiff might have been unwilling to act upon the option at prices which other manufacturers would have offered, and the extent of his prospective loss, if any, is largely a matter of speculation. The defendant may have been so situated that it could better afford to employ its own men and facilities, even although by doing so its machines would cost it more than to buy them of others, and in this view the difference between the actual cost of the machines to the defendant, and the sum it would have cost the plaintiff to make and furnish them, might not be the correct rule of damages. ’ In.any view, the jury were unduly restricted by the direction that the plaintiff was entitled to recover as his loss under this provision of the contract the difference between w’hat it cost the defendant to build them and what the plaintiff could have built them for. At most, the cost to the defendant was only evidence to be considered with the other evidence of the ordinary manufacturers’ price for such machines.
For these reasons it must be held that the instructions to the jury on the question of damages were erroneous, and prejudicial to the defendant. A new trial is granted.