7 F. Cas. 776 | E.D. Mo. | 1869
It appears that, pending negotiations for an extension of the •defendants’ paper, they returned to the vendors a piano, which had been bought to fill -a special order, and was somewhat damaged •during its transportation. The party for whom the same was designed refused to pur•chase it when it arrived. The action of the defendants in returning the same was no act •of bankruptcy, as charged, but an entirely proper course of proceeding. It was return•ed with no view of giving a preference or of defrauding creditors, but as a prudent and .proper business transaction.
The other ground alleged in the creditor’s petition, is the defendants’ suspension of their commercial paper, and the nonresumption thereof within fourteen days. Courts ■differ in th“ construction of the act on that point; some holding a fraudulent suspension necessary, and others not. This court has followed the latter construction, but not in the literal or arbitrary sense urged in behalf ■of the petitioning creditor. When a trader fails generally to meet his commercial paper .according to the usual course of business— that is, suffers not some, but all, as it matures, to go to protest, or in other words, comes to a general supension, as unable to proceed further with his business—then his creditors may. through the bankrupt act, compel an adjudication and distribution of his assets. The mere fact of insolvency is not decisive. He may procure renewals or extensions, and thus, with the assent of his creditors, continue for their and his benefit. If all of his •creditors assent to extensions or renewals, none of them can proceed against him; if a part consent thereto, the residue are benefited, for their demands can be enforced by ordinary legal proceedings. Thus, if in this case, all the creditors except the petitioners had unqualifiedly, each for himself, agreed to an extension for one year or more, then the defendants would have had no outstanding obligation enforceable against them at the present time, except the petitioner's, and, consequently, he could have recovered his dues by ordinary process. Many of the creditors agreed to the desired extension un-qualifiedly; one or more with the qualification that all should join. The petitioner, though at first willing to join, concluded not to do so for reasons developed at the hearing. Negotiations were had between the several parties in interest, the creditors and partners, and inter sese between the partners. An honest difference of opinion existed, and reasonably, as to the ultimate success and existing solvency of the co-partnership. If any of these negotiations had been successfully terminated, this suit would probably not have been instituted. This case, therefore, is one where partners, with reasonable cause to believe that by a little indulgence they can make their comparatively new undertaking a decided success, consult freely with each other and their creditors, and being induced to suppose full assent would be had to the desired extension, suffer the payment of some —and it may be the larger part—of their commercial paper to be suspended for more than fourteen days; a suspension fully justifiable under the circumstances, for the payment of one would have been a preference given to that one. It may be the petitioner was justified in his opinion, that the business never could succeed; but that does not make the defendants guilty of an act of bankruptcy. Other creditors, and at least one of the defendants, thought otherwise. True, the peculiar relationship of the petitioner to the co-partnership might make him more anxious and sensitive, but he is before the court simply as a creditor of the co-partnership.
The provision in the bankrupt act [of 1867 (14 Stat 536)] concerning the suspension of commercial paper has no just application to the case presented—is designed to work no such harsh or oppressive result as to enable one creditor, against the wishes of a majority or of all others, to compel a struggling trader who has fair prospects of success or believes ne has, to surrender his effects, to the manifest injury of all concerned. If the trader meets his paper generally by renewals or extensions, and some one creditor does not grant the desired renewal or extension, but proceeds to enforce his demand at once, the latter is really benefited by the indulgence shown by the others, for he may thus make his money by ordinary suit at law. He cannot, however, under any provision of the existing bankrupt act, proceed to collect his personal claim through its agency. If as a creditor he makes his demand by a common law action, the advantage thus acquired by his diligence he will be permitted to retain. It must not be supposed that the bankrupt act is for the collection of ordinary debts; or that a creditor can force a debtor into bankruptcy for any other than the causes named in the act. Mere insolvency is not, of itself, ground for involuntary bankruptcy;
In this case the court holds that there was no violation of the act in the return of the piano mentioned, and no such suspension of the commercial paper of defendants as constitutes an act of bankruptcy under the law. The petition is against two co-partners, one of whom is in default, and the other of whom contests; and as the co-partnership or both partners must be guilty under the act before judgment can be entered, the petition must be dismissed with costs. Voluntary and involuntary proceedings depend on distinct principles.
The following views expressed by the court in Jones v. Howland, 8 Metc. [Mass.] 385, meet the full approval of this court: “The doctrine, we think, is correctly and clearly laid down by Gibbs, C. J., in the case of Fidgeon v. Sharpe, 5 Taunt. 539. He observes that ‘the general effect of the statutes on the subject of bankrupts is, that all payments made before bankruptcy are legal and valid; but a certain class of cases has arisen in which certain payments have been supposed to be made in fraud of the bankrupt laws, and are therefore fraudulent and void. But I find in all the cases, from Pordyee’s to the present, the fact found that the act was done in fraud of the bankrupt laws. It must be an act. then, not only that in effect contravenes the bankrupt laws, but it must be done with intent to contravene them and in contemplation of bankruptcy. The innocence or guilt of the act depends, then, on the mind of him who did it; and it cannot be in fraud of the bankrupt laws unless the actor meantitshouldbeso.’ See. also, Hartshorn v. Slodden, 2 Bos. & P. 582; Morgan v. Brundrett, 5 Barn. & Adol. 289; Gibbins v. Phillipps, 7 Barn. & C. 529; Atkinson v. Brindall, 2 Bing. N. C. 225, and 2 Scott, 369; Belcher v. Prittie, 10 Bing. 408. The result of these eases is the drawing of a distinction between an actual insolvency and a contemplated bankruptcy; between the payment of a just debt in the course of business, though insolvency exists and is known to the insolvent, and the design to give a preference in view of stopping payment. And in view of all the authorities we hold the law to be this: That though insolvency in fact exists, yet if the debtor honestly believes he shall be able to go on In his business, and, with such belief, pays a just debt without a design to give a preference, such payment is not fraudulent, though bankruptcy should afterwards ensue. And on the other hand, if the debtor, being insolvent, and knowing his situation, and expecting to stop payment, shall then make a payment or give security to a credit- or for a just debt, with a view to give him a preference over the general creditors, such payment or giving security is fraudulent as against the creditors, and property that is transferred in making such payment, or giving the security, may be recovered by the as-signee; and the debtor will not be entitled to a discharge under the statute. It rests upon the intent with which the act was done; and the intent is to be proved, as a fact, either by direct evidence, or the necessary and certain consequence of other facts clearly proved. In respect to the charge of the judge in the case at bar, it will be found, when carefully examined, to express the opinion that the fact of insolvency being proved, and a knowledge of it on the part of Stowell, the debtor, the jury were bound to infer the intention of Stowell to make a fraudulent preference, because he must be held to have intended the natural result of his own actr and consequently, that his act was in fraud of the bankrupt law. This direction, though in accordance with opinions of the court in Poland v. Glyn [Case No. 11,243], and Pulling v. Tucker [Id. 11,464], is, we think, broader than is warranted by the cases of Fidgeon v. Sharpe, Morgan v. Brundrett, and Atkinson v. Brindall [supra], which, as before observed, we think, lay down the law correctly. The charge assumes, as a fact, the very thing which is to be proved, namely, the intent which actuated the debtor at the time of making payment; whereas, insolvency maybe known to exist, and yet the debtor, though compelled to make sacrifices, be determined to go on in his business, and not yield to the pressure, and thus make payment without any intention of giving a preference in contemplation of bankruptcy. Such instances are not of very rare occurrence; and such intent should have been more freely submitted to the jury. It is said that a man must bo-supposed to intend the natural result of his act. But this remark, though often treated as an axiom, is by no means an infallible proposition. The result is not always evidence of the supposed intent. When we look back upon events that have happened, we stand in a different position; we behold with a clear vision, as we embrace witbin one-glance the beginning and the end, the act and the consequence. But the man who is doing the act may contemplate a very different result. His judgment may be biased by his wishes, and sanguine feelings may be the cause of overlooking difficulties which to a more quiet temperament might appear insurmountable. Disappointments may also take place which were not anticipated. The expe