23 Wis. 590 | Wis. | 1869
Lead Opinion
The following opinion was filed at the February term, 1868.
This action was brought to enjoin the sale of the plaintiff’s lands for an assessment imposed upon them for paving the streets in front of them with what is known as the “Nicholson pavement.” It is claimed that the proceedings failed in several respects to comply with the provisions of the charter, in matters so essential as to render the tax void. But another objection is taken, which goes to the foundation of the whole proceeding; and the conclusion to which a majority of
Tbe other mode of avoiding tbe objection was, by proving tbat tbe owners of tbe patent were anxious and willing to sell tbe royalty, and bad offered it for sixteen cents per square yard. And upon this proof it is insisted tbat tbe principle of
I will state, as briefly as may be, wby I think neither of these theories overcomes the objection. The first assumes the correctness of the position that the charter cannot be applied to a contract for work the right to do which is a' patented monopoly. And it then infers, that because the charter is inapplicable, the city had the general power to make the contract without regard to its restrictions, and that such was the legislative intent. The error lies in this inference. This position was attempted to be supported mainly by the case of The Harlem Gas Co. v. The Mayor, etc., 33 N. Y. 309. The counsel on both sides rely upon that case, and it will therefore be proper to examine it carefully, to see what position it sustains.
The action was on a contract for lighting certain streets in New York city with gas. The company had by law the exclusive right to furnish gas for that part of the city. The charter required all contracts for work and supplies, beyond a certain limitation in value which this contract far exceeded, to be let by contract to the lowest bidder.. The contract for this gas was not so let, and therefore it was claimed to be void. The court held that inasmuch as the company had the exclusive right to furnish the gas, the provision of the charter requiring the contract to be let to the lowest bidder was inapplicable, and that it would be absurd to attempt to apply the provision in such a case. Poetee, J., says: “ In the present case, an adoption of the construction claimed by the municipal authorities would lead to the absurd conclusion, that the legislature designed to force a provision into the city charter compelling the corporation to pay whatever price the sole bidder might choose to exact in his sealed proposals for the use of property in which he has an absolute monopoly, and in relation to which there can be no competition within the range of legal possibility.”
The case, therefore, fully sustains the position of the appellant’s counsel, which seems obvious enough in itself, that a provision requiring wort to be let to the lowest bidder is not applicable to a contract for work as to which there can be no competition. And if not applicable to it, of course it can furnish no authority for such a contract. And if such a contract is made, it must be sustained, if at all, by authority derived from some other source than such a provision of the charter.
But the court in that case -did hold the contract valid, and the city liable. And this branch of the decision the respondents’ counsel rely on, to sustain their position, that, if the charter was inapplicable, these proceedings should be sustained, whether conducted in accordance with it or not. But the cases are so different in respect to the grounds of that part of the decision, that it becomes inapplicable here. The power to contract for the lighting of the streets of the city was assumed, in that case, to be one of the general powers of a municipal corporation. Hence, so soon as the court came to the conclusion that the mode of contracting pointed out in the charter was inapplicable in such a case as they had under consideration, they had no difficulty in sustaining the contract under the general corporate power of the city. But here the question is quite different. It is not necessary to inquire whether the city of Madison, by virtue of its existence as a municipal corporation, would have had the- power to contract for paving its streets with the Nicholson pavement, at the expense of the city, after discovering that the provisions of the charter enabling it to cause its streets to be paved at the expense of the lots
I think, therefore, that while tbe case in New York does show that tbe contract in tbis case was outside of tbe scope of the provisions of tbe charter, it fails to show any general authority in tbe city by which, it could be sustained, independent of those provisions. In truth, it would seem toó late for us now to say that these requirements of tbe charter are not applicable to contracts for paving streets, for tbe contrary bas uniformly been held by tbis and other courts. Myrick v. La Crosse, 17 Wis. 442; Mitchell v. Milwaukee, 18 id. 92; Kneeland v. Furlong, 20 id. 431; Brady v. New Fork, 20 N. Y. 312.
Neither can I see that tbe other mode of answering tbe objection is successful. . On proof that tbe owners of tbe patent were willing to sell tbe “royalty,”, as it is called, for sixteen cents per yard, it is said that other parties might-bave bid, and tbe principle of competition was preserved. If an arrangement had previously been made, by which tbe owners of tbe patent became bound to transfer tbe right at sixteen cents per yard, and tbe contracts bad then been let in pursuance of tbe charter, for tbe materials and labor, subject to the condition of obtaining tbe patent, tbe principle of competition, so far as tbe
But no such method was resorted to. On the contrary, the proposals were for furnishing the materials and doing the wort, without any thing in regard to the price of the royalty, and without any previous agreement with the owners of it. There could be no competition in this method. The fact that the owners were willing to sell it at sixteen cents per yard, does not show that there could have been. For, assuming that any contractor might have safely relied on the willingness of the owners to sell it at that price, and assuming that the latter, in case they desired to bid for the work themselves, would not use their power over the patent to aid in obtaining the contract, as far as possible, by preventing others from getting it — assumptions which it would scarcely be safe for contractors to act upon — still there could have been no safety in bidding. For suppose A, B, and C, all bid, none of them making any'previous arrangement for the purchase of the royalty ? Before the bids are opened, one of them, thinking to get the contract, desiring in good faith to do the work, goes to the owner of the patent and buys the royalty for that part of the city where the work is ordered to be done. The bids are opened, and some one else has the lowest bid, and gets the contract. What position would the successful bidder be in, bound under somewhat severe penalties to enter into and complete his contract,
It has been compared to the case of work ordered to be done with a particular kind of stone, the quarry of which is owned by one who is willing to sell to all alike at a fixed price. Undoubtedly in that case there might be free competition. If the owner of the quarry, before the contract was let, should sell to one bidder enough stone for that work, he might the next day sell as much to another bidder. And if neither of these should get it, he might afterward sell whatever was needed to such person as did get the contract. Such being the case, any bidder could safely wait until he obtained the contract before making arrangements for his stone. But there is a marked difference in the case of the patent. There the owner, having disposed of the right for any particular district to one person, cannot afterward furnish the same right to any other. This difference destroys the whole force of the illustration, and shows that the safety of bidders would be very different in the two cases.
It seems to me, therefore, a conclusion derivable from the very nature of the case, that competition could not be and was
It may be said that this pavement is of a superior character, and that it is very desirable that cities should have authority to cause it to be iaid. It may be so, but if so, I think the aid of the legislature will have to be invoked, and that there is no authority to contract for it under charters which require the work to be let by contract to the lowest bidder.
It was suggested that even though this assessment should be held illegal, still there was nothing to show it to be inequitable, and therefore a court of equity ought not to interfere. But that principle has never been applied to these special assessments. And certainly it could not be applied where there is no legal authority to contract for the work at all, to pay for which the assessment was imposed.
I think the judgment should be reversed, and the cause remanded, with directions to enter judgment for the plaintiff for a perpetual injunction according to the prayer of the complaint.
By the Court. — Ordered accordingly.
Rehearing
The respondents moved for a rehearing, and the following opinion was filed at the February term, 1869
The arguments presented on the motion for a reheai’ing have not changed the views of the majority of the court, as expressed in the opinion already filed. But as a rehearing is claimed upon one or two grounds not noticed in that opinion, we will briefly state the reasons for denying the motion upon those points.
The first is, that the claim of Collins for grading the street was legal and ought to have been allowed, even though the
But it is further claimed, that even if this pavement was authorized at the time it was contracted for, still the legislature may subsequently confer authority upon the council to adopt it, and to assess and collect a tax for it. And it is then insisted that the legislature has already done this.
The general proposition, that the legislature may confer such authority, has been already sustained by. the decision of this
The position is based upon the provisions of chapter 132 of the general laws of 1868. But that merely provides that where any taxes or assessments have been set aside or declared void by any court, in consequence of any irregularity or neglect to comply with the law in the proceedings, it may be afterward reassessed. It applies, therefore, obviously only to such taxes and assessments as were authorized by law. Where there is an irregularity or defect in assessing these, they may be reassessed. But it would be a strange use or abuse of such a statute, to say that it would extend to the assessment of a tax which was defective, not on account of mere irregularity in the proceedings, but for an entire want of authority. That is the ground of the objection to the tax here in question, and this statute has therefore no application to it.
Dissenting Opinion
dissenting. After this cause was decided, and pending the motion for a rehearing, the case of Hobart v. The City of Detroit, 17 Mich. 246, was decided by the supreme court of Michigan. The questions involved in the cases are the very same, the language of the Michigan statute being word for word like our own. They were new questions in that court, as well as in this; but having first been decided by this court, the opinion of the majority here was there cited and relied upon. The decision there is the reverse of that here made, and the opinion of the court by Chief Justice Cooley is such a clear and able statement and vindication of my own views, that I have thrown aside an opinion partially written before the report came to hand, and am entirely satisfied with a mere reference to that case. I would, however, call attention to a single fact appearing in this case, but not in that, which seems to make very much more strongly against the decision here. It was conclusively shown in evidence here, that any person
But it is said that after the biddings were closed, and the contract awarded, the owners of the patent might refuse to convey to the successful bidder, or might convey the right as to the particular street or streets to some third person, and that this circumstance, or the anticipation of it, would deter bidders, and defeat the principle of competition. I say, not necessarily so at all. In the first place, it is not to be presumed that the owners of the patent would so conduct themselves under any circumstances. Their property in the patent is of that peculiar kind, that its only value to them consists in the sale of it, or what may be realized from the sale. They hold it for sale at an open, fixed market pi’ice, and it is for their interests to introduce the improvement and extend the demand for it as much as possible. It is not to be presumed, therefore, that they would pursue a course so detrimental to their own interests as this would be, by discouraging purchasers, and preventing the public from using the invention. But if this be not the presumption, and the contrary, and, as it seems to me,
I conclude, therefore, that there was no ground whatever in this case for holding that the contract was not open to the fullest and freest competition on the part of all persons wishing to bid, and that it was not on that account illegal or void. I thought, and still think, that the judgment of the circuit court should have been affirmed.
I desire also to call attention to the case of Astor v. The Mayor, etc., of New York, in the supreme court of the -first judicial district of New York, as yet unreported, in which the
By the Court. — The motion for a rehearing is denied.