Davis v. Mason

3 Or. 154 | Multnomah Cty. Cir. Ct., O.R. | 1869

Upton, J.

instructed as follows :

The plaintiff sues to recover $80, which he alleges he loaned to the defendant, and also for the reasonable value of his services.

Where the parties agree upon and contract for a stipulated value or rate of wages, the plaintiff can recover no mo3'C than the amount agreed upon. But where the parties have not determined the rate by their own agreement, the party performing labor at the request of the other is entitled to recover the reasonable value of his services.

To constitute an express contract fixing the rate of wages, thes'e must be the assent of two minds to one and the same proposition, and the contract must he such as can be enforced.

If these parties assented that the wages should be a certain amount of gold coin, and if its payment in gold was a material condition or term of the agreement, it was a contract that could not be fully entered into so as to make all its terms binding upon the parties without a writing. The parties cannot be considered as having made such a contract, unloss some writing was made.

If no writing was made, the parties did not make a valid contract that the payment should be made in gold coin. If *156payment in gold coin was one condition, and the rate of wages another condition, or term, that both parties intended should be part of the contract, it evidently was not agreed that such rate of wages was satisfactory if paid in something of less value than gold coin.

In that case, there was not a binding contract for the payment of gold coin; because for the want of a writing such contract cannot be enforced, and it was not a binding contract for that rate of wages, payable in something of less value, because the minds of the two contracting parties never assented to that proposition. Unless there has been an assent of both parties, to a definite mode and measure of compensation, which can be enforced both as to the amount and the value they had in contemplation, they have not by their own act fixed upon the rate of wages, and the law determines it for them. In such ease the law declares the compensation to be what the services are reasonably worth. If the plaintiff recovers a judgment for wages in this case, the defendant will be authorized to pay it, if he chooses to do so, in legal tender notes, and it is proper that the jury should estimate the wages in view of that fact, when estimates are made in different kinds of currency by different witnesses.

As to the alleged loan of money, there is no rule of law that will authorize the jury to render a verdict for a greater amount than was loaned, merely because the judgment can be paid in a currency of less value. This may appear to be a hardship in some cases, and'it is impossible to institute a system of laws that will never work hardships. When one so far trusts to others as to contract for gold coin, and take no written agreement for its payment, he must suffer the consequence of his neglect, if results do not come up to his expectations.

Jurors are not at liberty to disregard the law in such cases, upon an idea that they can thus do justice between the parties. If courts or juries are at liberty to disregard the law in some cases, what is' to prevent them from doing so in all cases, when they do not approve of the law. It is evident that such practice would undermine the foundation *157of remedial justice, and would be substituting the arbitrary-will of those who are called apon to administer justice, for the settled rules of law upon which every citizen lias a right to rely for the protection, not only of his property, but his liberty and his life. It is better that we should sometimes suffer great hardship^ whether caused by our own neglect or otherwise, than that we should exchange known rules of law for the arbitrary will of those who undertake to administer the law.

The plaintiff had a verdict, and judgment was entered without specifying the bind of currency.