1 N.Y. 9 | NY | 1857
Lead Opinion
It will be convenient to approach the questions in this case, having first an accurate notion of the
The receivership in question was constituted under sections thirty-nine, forty and forty-one of the Revised Statutes, concerning “ Proceedings against corporations in equity.” (2 R. S., 463,464.) Under those statutes, any creditor or stockholder of a banking corporation may commence a suit in equity for the causes therein enumerated, and the court may issue an injunction, and “ appoint one or more receivers to take charge of the property and effects of the corporation,” with authority to recover the debts due to it, and “ the property that may belong” to it. The next section declares that “ such receiver shall possess all the powers and authority” conferred by article third of the same title'upon receivers appointed in case of the voluntary dissolution of a corporation. According to art. 3, secs. 67, 68, receivers appointed om voluntary dissolution “ are vested with all the estate,
The appellant, as receiver, has no interest in or power-over the property affected by the trusts in question, except such as he derives under the statutes which have been mentioned. It has been said in this, as in other cases, that he represents the creditors and the stockholders, but for all the purposes of inquiry into his title, he really represents the corporation. He is by law vested with the estate of the corporate body, and takes his title under and through it. It is true, indeed, that he is declared to be a trustee for creditors and stockholders; but this only proves that they are the beneficiaries of the fund in his hands, without indicating the sources of his title or the extent of his powers. If, then, in a controversy between the receiver and third parties, in respect to the corporate estate, it is possible to form a conception of rights, legal or equitable, belonging to the shareholders as individuals, which the corporation itself could not assert in its own name, the receiver does not represent those rights. So far as shareholders are concerned, he can litigate respecting the fund upon precisely the grounds which would be available to the corporation, if it were still in existence, solvent, and no receivership had been constituted. In regard to creditors, I should certainly incline to take the same view of his rights and powers
In general, then, a receiver of this description takes merely the rights of the corporation, such as could be asserted in its own name, and on that basis only can he litigate for the benefit of either stockholders or creditors, except when acts have been done in fraud of the rights of the latter, but valid as to the corporation itself. In this particular case, it will readily be seen that the controversy is still further reduced, in respect of parties interested, to a mere question between the Palmers and others, holding the bonds secured by the two trusts, and the general creditors, claiming to annul those trusts and to share in the property embraced therein. On the part of the receiver, it has been strenuously argued that the corporation was insolvent when the trusts were created. If not, then its insolvency afterwards and at the present time has not been denied. If by repudiating the debts, or the greater portion thereof, something might be left for the shareholders, the decision which we pronounce in another branch of the case renders that result impossible. Following the principles laid down in the case of the State of Indiana ( Tracy v. Talmage, 4 Kern., 162), and applying them to this controversy, we determine that the debts of the corporation cannot be repudiated upon any of the grounds which have been urged. It becomes absolutely certain, therefore, that the claims of creditors, including the bondholders, greatly exceed the entire value of the corporate effects. For this reason, if no other, the shareholders or individuals may be regarded as strangers to the controversy. The rights of creditors only are really in question.
I. And first, then, it is claimed that both of the trusts are void, under section eight of the statute “to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations” (1 R. S., 588), because they were not authorized by any previous resolution of the board of directors. That statute declares that no conveyance, &c., not authorized by such a resolution, “ shall be made by any such corporation, of any of its real estate or of any of its effects exceeding the value of one thousand dollars.” The next clause in the section makes certain exceptions not material to the question; and the concluding one declares that the conveyances, &c., shall not be rendered “ void in the hands of a purchaser, for a valuable consideration and without notice.” Conceding that no previous resolution of the directors was in fact adopted, sufficient in its terms to authorize either of the trusts, some of my brethren are of opinion that they can be sustained on the ground that the holders of the trust bonds are bona fide purchasers, and so within the protection afforded by the last clause of this statute. While I do not dissent from
In accordance with what seems to have been the opinion of one of the judges in this court, in Gillett v. Moody (3 Comst., 486), opposed to his well considered decision in another tribunal (Gillett v. Campbell, 1 Denio, 520); in accordance, also, with a resolution concurred in by a majority of the judges, in Tulmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328), after that case had been disposed of on other grounds ; and with a decision somewhat more directly involving the question, in a case quite recent ( Gillett v. Phillips, 3 Kern., 114), where the point was neither argued by counsel nor considered by the court, I shall assume that banking associations, organized under the general act of 1838, are brought within the statute under consideration and within other provisions of the same title. I must observe, however, in passing, that this is an assumption opposed to the clearest convictions of my own mind; and that, if it were necessary in the determination of a controversy so important as the present, I should feel bound to inquire whether a doctrine which appears to me so plainly erroneous is irreversibly settled.
The objection we are now considering does not deny that the corporation had power to create the trusts. It only insists they were created in the corporate name and under the corporate seal by certain subordinate agents, who acted without due authority from their principal, and hence that they are void. If we may apply to the question the most familiar of all the doctrines of agency, such an objection cannot prevail, provided the principal at the time approved or afterwards ratified the act of its agent. The ratification need not be declared in express terms. Mere silence and acquiescence will in many cases be sufficient So it may be inferred from the acts and proceedings of the principal in pais When he receives and. appropriates the
To these principles, so simple and so just, the receiver’ counsel oppose the peculiar language of the statute. The requires, as they argue, a previous resolution of the directors and they insist that the assent of the corporation to tho trust conveyances could not be given at any other time or manifested in any other manner; and the conclusion from this argument is, that the trusts must be annulled, however formally assented to at the time or afterwards, and even although the corporation actually received the proceeds thereof, amounting to over a million of dollars, and applied the moneys to its use in the payment of its debts and otherwise. If these views are justified by the statute, then, as to all the moneyed corporations of this state, principles of hitherto universal application, and founded in the plainest justice, are no longer in force. I cannot bring my mind to the conclusion that such was the intention of the legislature.
The precise object of the statute was to prevent fraudulent and improper transfers of the corporate effects by officers of the corporation acting without the sanction of the board of directors. It was simply in restraint of their authority and of their acts that the statute was enacted. It was not intended in any wise to abridge or restrain the power of the corporations themselves, as represented by their directors, over their effects, or to confine them to any special mode or particular time of manifesting their will in
Very different, I am pursuaded, were the intentions ,of the legislature. At the time this statute was passed, it was
Upon these views I prefer to rest my conclusion on this branch of the case. The North American Trust and Banking Company never questioned the validity of these trusts; on the contrary, we have the very highest evidence that it approved them. The deeds were executed in the name and under the seal of the corporation. Regarded as the acts simply of the officer who signed them, they were void (so I assume) under the statute; but, almost contemporaneously with the execution of the deeds, the company itself sold and pledged the bonds which the conveyances were made to secure, received the proceeds and used the
The trusts being valid as against the corporation, so far as the objection considered is concerned, the receiver cannot repudiate them for the benefit of creditors. In the absence of fraud, a creditor holds under and through his debtor, and is concluded by all the valid acts and assurances of the latter. (Candee v. Lord,, 2 Comst., 275.) This principle is just as applicable to a corporate as any other debtor. Whether the trusts were fraudulent as to creditors is a distinct question, having no connection with the one which has been examined.
II. I come next to the objection that banking associations formed under the general law of 1838, have no power to borrow money, and hence that this corporation could not issue its bonds, create the trusts, or give any valid assurance for a loan. This is a very grave proposition, opposed to the known practice of probably every banking institution in
Banking is not in its nature a corporate franchise. In the absence of legislative restraints, it may be carried on by individuals and partnerships in all its departments of issuing, lending, receiving deposits, discounting, dealing in exchange, bullion, &c.; and in examining the powers of banking corporations, the nature and incidents of banking as a business, when not under special legal restraints, are in the highest degree important. It is true the question will always be one of corporate power rather than of the rules and principles of banking; but those rules and principles may have a decisive influence in the construction of charters which profess to confer powers of this description. And this leads me to observe that banking, regarded as á business and not as a franchise, includes the borrowing of money as one of its features or incidents. As no one-denies-this proposition, I will not dwell upon it further than to
If, then, a number of persons should associate themselves together as bankers, in the recognized modes of carrying on that business, it will be, and, as I understand, it is admitted that the managing partner or partners, or any general and unrestricted agent, could bind the firm by engagements contracted for moneys loaned, without a specification of the
Let us then suppose all statutes prior to 1838, in restraint of banking, to be done away, and a mere partnership formed under articles, reciting an intention to pursue “ the business of banking,” and declaring that the associates would, under a certain name, carry on that business in or by the issuing of circulating notes, receiving deposits, discounting bills, dealing in exchange, bullion and coin, and loaning money on real or personal security. I know of no broader terms in the English language to define “ the business of banking;” and would any one, who admits that the borrowing of money is included in that business, deny that the power would be embraced as the incident of some or all of the operations
If, so far, I have differed from those who deny the power in question, I think the difference is in the mode of statement rather than in principle. The objection to the power is, after all, really made to turn on the terms of the banking
We come then to the question of construction, which to my own mind presents no difficulty. The argument on the other side urges that “ the business of banking” is authorized by the 18th section, only according to the specifications therein contained, among which the power to borrow is not found. To this the answer is, that these specifications, with the issuing power granted in the previous sections, cover the whole ground of banking. If the statute had omitted the general terms “business of banking,” and had merely enumerated the power of issuing, and all the others named in the 18th section, that would have been a general grant of banking powers, including, as their incident, the right to borrow money when a necessity may arise in the exercise of those powers.
To deny this conclusion is necessarily to assume (and it seems to be assumed, perhaps unconsciously) that borrowing is an independent operation in the business of banking; in other words, that it is banking in one of its branches, and hence that the power cannot exist without a particular specification. This is, I think, plainly an error; and yet it appears to lie at the foundation of the opposing view of the present question. Now, in a very simple and elementary view of the subject, borrowing is not banking, nor is it in a just and proper sense any other kind of business. It is the incident and auxiliary of various kinds. Let us test this. If a person should open and keep an office for receiving deposits payable on demand, he would carry on a well known branch of banking business, although he might use the deposits in speculation or other modes totally unconnected with banking. He would be a banker. So if he were to keep an office for issuing his own circulating notes, or for dealing in exchange, or for discounting bills, and should
The course of bank legislation in this state leads to the same conclusion. In the charters prior to 1825 there was no enumeration of the banking powers, but in that year the Commercial Bank of Albany was chartered, “ with all incidental and necessary powers to carry on the business of banking, by discounting bills, &c.,” proceeding with the same specifications as in the act of 1838, now under consideration. This was the model of a vast number of charters down to and including the year 1836, when special legislation of this kind ceased. Now, it is a fact not at all remarkable, but very pertinent to the present question, that in no special bank charter ever granted in this state was it thought of to specify the borrowing of money as one of the substantive and express banking powers. Yet I am not aware that it was ever before suggested that the right to borrow was excluded by the enumeration of those powers.
Again, suppose a corporation were chartered under a special or general law for manufacturing purposes, with a particular authority to borrow money whenever deemed necessary in the business: would that be considered a grant of one of the banking powers ? Plainly not; and quite as plainly it would be, if the authority were to receive deposits or discount bills, or issue circulating notes.
Under these views, it is not very important to answer the question, Why did the legislature of 1838 specify the express powers which it was intended to confer, instead of leaving them to be derived from the general grant to carry on “ the business of banking?” That legislature surely might copy the language of its predecessors since the year 1825, without affording any occasion for imputing to it the special intention of excluding a well known incident of that business. Still the question is not difficult to answer. In the restraining law of 1830 (1 R. S., 712, §6), it was declared to be unlawful, without express legislative authority, to keep offices of deposit, discount, &c. The act of 1837 (Suit., p. 14) removed this restraint only in favor of persons and associations not incorporated. In order, therefore, to confer upon associations; under the act of 1838, the
We arrive then at the conclusion that the North American Trust and Banking Company had capacity to borrow money as incidental to the banking business and the powers expressly granted. But the objection takes another form. It has been urged that these associations cannot borrow money as a substitute for capital. If by this proposition it is only meant that these institutions, having no capital subscribed at all, cannot lawfully procure it upon loan and so make a total substitution of credit for capital, the doctrine has no precise application to the present case; for this company had an actual capital of some $3,000,000 subscribed and paid, and it is not denied that the subscriptions were paid in a manner which the law permitted. It is remarkable, however, that there is no provision in the law requiring a single dollar to be paid by the shareholders. The association must, in some way, whether upon credit or with capital, procure mortgages and stocks, and deposit them with the comptroller of the state, in order to secure the ultimate payment of its circulating notes, if it issues any. But it is not compelled to exercise the issuing power at all; and if it chooses not to do so, then it has no occasion to procure or deposit the securities, and it will have no circulation to
< and not to the actual policy of this state.
If we admit, then, that these associations can borrow, and I trust this has been shown, I do not see in what quarter we are to find restraints upon the power, so long as it is exercised in the course of that business. The right exists as the incident of banking, and beyond that it cannot be exercised without transcending the limit of corporate power. The act of borrowing for objects not within the general scope of that business would be ultra vires. But if the power exists, we cannot say that the lending contract is void, because the occasion for the loan arises out of a course of merely imprudent and hazardous dealing. This particular company, no doubt, carried its credit to extraordinary lengths, and it may even be true that its embarrassments arose out of speculations in stocks or other
The conclusions at which we arrive, affirming the right of banking institutions to borrow money, and sustaining its exercise in the case before us, do not necessarily result in the doctrine laid down by a very able judge, assistant Vice-Chancellor Sandford, in the case of Barry v. The Merchants' Exchange Company (1 Sand. Ch. R., 280, 289). That case, however, should not be overlooked in this discussion, because it asserts a principle which more than covers the ground now in controversy, and because the same question afterwards arose in this court. The Merchants’ Exchange Company was chartered with a capital of SI ,000,000, for the purpose of building an exchange in the city of Hew-York. After the first erection was destroyed by fire, the corporation purchased more land and rebuilt on a larger
But can these decisions be shown to be wrong upon principle or authority ? I confess my own inability to refute the doctrine so perspicuously laid down by Assistant Vice-Chancellor Sandford. I am not aware that it comes in conflict with any known distinction between private person i and corporations. It is true that the latter take all then powers, direct and incidental, under their charters; but when the direct power is granted in terms, they take it, as natural person enjoys it, with all its incidents and acces series. A simple association of merchants to build an exchange, could, if they so agreed with each other, very appropriately borrow money in furtherance of the object; and why can they not, if they take the principal power under a charter from the government, which enables them to act as a single person and with a collective will ?
It is truly said that corporations can only exercise such incidental powers as are necessary to carry into effect the express objects of their charters. But necessity is a word of flexible meaning. There may be an absolute necessity, a great necessity, and a small necessity; and between these degrees there may be many others depending on the ever varying exigencies of human affairs. It is plain that corporations, in executing their express powers, are not confined to means of such indispensable necessity that without them there could be no execution at all. The contrary doctrine would lead at once to a very great absurdity; for if there are several modes of accomplishing the end, neither one is indispensable, and each would exclude all the others. And thus, by inevitable logic, an express grant of power
It is almost as difficult to say that the incidental power depends for its existence on the degree of necessity which connects it with the power in chief. Such a doctrine would impose upon courts a never ending difficulty, for the inquiry would always be whether the chosen instrumentality is the very best that could be selected; and if not the very best, however minute the difference may be, then the inevitable decision must follow that the choice was fatally bad, although strictly adapted to the end in view and made in the utmost good faith.
These demonstrations, for such they appear to me, would seem to leave but one other conclusion, which is, that corporations, along with their specific powers, take all the reasonable means of execution, all that are convenient and adapted to the end in view, although not the very best by many degrees of comparison. And this'is a doctrine which must necessarily result in the liberty of choice amongst those means. The choice may be wise or unwise. If made in the exercise of an intelligent good faith, the wisdom of the selection may be called in question, but the power to make it cannot be.
T can therefore see no room for the distinction which admits the power of a corporation to contract a debt for labor and materials to be used in building an exchange, or a bridge, or a turnpike road, or in manufacturing, those being in each case the specified object of the charter, but denies the right to borrow money to be used in the purchase of the same labor and materials. If there be any reason for a distinction, resting on a comparison of benefit to the corporation, the advantages of borrowing would in most cases be undeniable. So, in point of public policy, the reason for that preference would appear to be still stronger, for while the industrial classes would require no protection, the money lenders could safely be left to guard their own interests. I
If these views in regard to trading corporations in general are sound, then our conclusion, which affirms the power of incorporated banks to borrow money, when not specially restrained, rests not only upon the peculiar nature and necessities of banking business, but upon a principle somewhat more comprehensive.
III. The trusts are also objected to on the ground that the power to borrow money could not be exercised in the particular mode of issuing the so-called million and half million trust bonds as assurances for the moneys advanced, and this point is next to be examined. This objection raises the following questions: 1. Is it within the power of corporations generally to issue instruments of this kind, when no prohibitory or restraining statute is violated, and the purpose or occasion of making them is lawful ? 2., Is there any express or implied prohibition, contained in the act of 1838 or in any antecedent statute, by which this company was bound ? There are no other aspects in which this objection can be presented, provided the bonds were issued prior to June 3, 1840, when another statute took effect. The time of their issue will be hereafter noticed.
The first of these inquiries can be briefly answered. The right of corporations in general to give a note, bond or other engagement to pay a debt is so nearly identical or so inseparably connected with the right to contract the debt that no doubt upon the question ought to be admitted. When a corporatioti can lawfully purchase property or procure money on loan in the course of its business, the seller or the lender may exact, and the purchaser or borrower must have the power to give, any known assurance which does not fall within the prohibition, express or implied, of some statute. The particular restriction must be sought for in the charter of the corporation, or in some other statute binding upon it; but if not found in that
In the second place, if there are any special legislative restraints, which in their terms or policy condemn the trust bonds, they are to be found in the safety fund act of 1829, or in the statutes against unauthorized banking, called the restraining laws, or in the organic act of 1838, from which this corporation derived its powers. There is no other particular legislation supposed to have any bearing on the question.
The argument of the receiver’s counsel, so far as it is derived from the safety fund act (Laws of 1829, ch. 94, p. 167; 1 R. S., 737, 3d ed.), turns wholly upon the thirty-fifth section of that statute, and may also be answered in few words. This was an act, applicable only to future banks and those whose charters should be renewed in future, requiring them to contribute annually, for six years, one-half of one per cent upon their capital to a fund specially pledged for the redemption of the circulating notes of insolvent institutions. The thirty-fifth section contains a prohibition against the “ issuing of notes and bills,” unless payable on demand and without interest. The evil intended to be suppressed by this prohibition was undoubtedly the practice of issuing post notes, designed and calculated to circulate as money. The provision is, however, broad enough in its terms to include all bills and notes payable at
In further discussing the objection to these bonds we are to consider the restraining laws and the general act of 1838, and these matters are so connected that they must in some degree be examined together.
The statute of 1829 against unauthorized banking (1 R. S., 712), known as the restraining act, declares (§6) that “no person, association or body corporate, except such bodies corporate as are expressly authorized by law, shall keep any office for the purpose of receiving deposits or discounting notes or bills, or issuing any evidences of debt, to be loaned or put in circulation as money, nor shall they issue any bills or promissory notes or other evidence of debt as private bankers, for the purpose of loaning them or putting them in, circulation as money, unless thereto specially authorized by law.” Some of the other sections in the same act are intended to promote the same policy, but they need not be referred to. It cannot fail to be noticed that this statute does not forbid either natural or artificial persons from entering into written engagements of any description, provided they
The most delicate and dangerous by far of all these powers was that of creating a paper currency, to be loaned and put in circulation as money, for the use of the community. While, therefore, all other restraints were removed, by the act of 1837, already cited for another purpose, so far as unincorporated persons are concerned, this particular one was kept in full force precisely as it stood in the act of 1829, binding both upon persons and corporations of every description. It may be useful to add, that the restraining act of 1829 contained nothing new which is material to the present purpose. The policy began in the year 1804, was continued in the acts of 1813, 1818, 1829, down to the year 1837, and even in the statute of that year it was maintained, as we have just seen, so far as the power of creating currency is concerned. It was thus that banking in general became with us a franchise at an early day; but it has never been held, and I think never suggested, that there was anything in the restraining statutes, or in the policy they indicated, to deprive corporations of any kind of the incidental power to contract debts and make their written engagements therefor in any form not coming within the particular condemnation of these statutes. Banking only was restrained, one of the distinct operations of that business being the issuing upon loan of a paper currency; but the incidental
We come then to the general act of 1838, which I am sure can now be intelligibly examined with reference to this question. The restraints upon issuing notes, bills, &c., upon loan or for circulation as money, as we have seen, were still in force; and it is now very pertinent to observe, that this act did not repeal them. They are in full forcu at this day. The statute, however, did authorize the creation of an indefinite number of associated banks, which we call banking corporations, and gave them the issuing power upon the precise conditions therein contained; and it gave the same power to private individuals also, under the same exact conditions. Those conditions required thai the notes intended to be loaned and issued as currency should be payable on demand, should be countersigned and registered in one of the departments of the state government, and should be secured by a pledge of bonds and mortgages and stocks. This, I repeat, was not a repeal of the restraining acts, but it was the “ special authority of law” required by the very language of those acts, in order to exercise the business of banking in the particular department of creating and issuing a paper currency. It is, therefore, beyond all question, true that this power cannot be exercised under the act of 1838, except upon the precise conditions named; and if the trust bonds of the North American Trust and Banking Company were an exercise of that independent banking power, the conclusion would certainly follow that they were unauthorized. They would be ultra vires, because no “ express authority” to issue them can be found in that statute, and expressly prohibited by the restraining act.
But it is just as plain .that this “ special authority of law,’ which conditionally relieved, and which was necessary
These views of the act of 1838, and of antecedent legislation, if they are correct, meet with directness and force the argument so much urged by the receiver’s counsel, that out of the express provisions contained in that act, allowing circulating notes of a particular kind to be issued, payable on demand, there arises an implied prohibition against all other written engagements, and especially against all time paper. We are enabled to see distinctly that, without the express authority of law contained in those provisions, neither associations nor individuals could lawfully issue notes for circulation or upon loan, payable on demand. That banking power was sealed up as a franchise by the previous legislation and policy of the state. It was opened only on the performance of the conditions precedent which have been named. To all persons and associations not performing those conditions it remains sealed as before. But it would be absurd to hold that, in thus opening the fran
The objection to the bonds as time paper, when urged under the act of 1838, not only overlooks the restraining laws, as indispensable to a correct-view of that act, but also the distinction between the express and the implied powers of banking and other corporations. The argument assumes that when one of these associations gives a written obligation for money borrowed or stocks purchased, payable at a future day, it exercises a distinct and express banking power not granted in the statute. This is not true: the right thus exercised is incidental and accessory to those banking powers which are expressly given. This distinction has already been considered at large in discussing the power to contract a debt, inseparably connected with which must be the ability to promise, in any form not expressly forbidden, to pay such debt. Indeed, the necessity of creating time paper, for money borrowed to redeem circulating notes payable on demand, often arises out of the particular franchise of issuing such notes, and that necessity results in the right to enter into such engagements. In this view, the grant of the franchise in express terms, instead of excluding the power now in question, may become the very source from which it springs.
There is, then, in the language of the general banking law, no implied force to invalidate the trust bonds. It is next to be observed that the ac b contains no express prohibition. Its provisions will be examined in vain for a single clause to which such an interpretation can be given. On the contrary, we shall find language which plainly recognizes
We are brought, then, to an inquiry which belongs essentially to the facts of the case: What was the character of these instruments? Were they in the nature of currency ? Were they issued to be loaned, or for circulation as money ? If they were, then their issue and sale amounted to the usurpation of a banking franchise not granted in the general charter and prohibited by the restraining laws. Here, I apprehend, is the turning point on which the validity or invalidity of the bonds must depend, and on this subject, it seems to me, there is no room for reasonable doubt. They were not issued “ to be loaned.” The banking association was not creditor in these transactions, nor did the dealer become a debtor. The relation was exactly reversed. The association was the borrower and the debtor in respect to each bond, and the dealer became the lender and creditor. They were not issued for “ circulation as money.” Without examining the question whether, in strict law, they were perfect as sealed instruments, they had impressed upon them the corporate seal, were intended to be and in all their appearances were sealed. They were eminently special, also, in the language which expressed the obligation. Still, in their legal effect, they might be promissory notes if the seal be entirely rejected ; but it is certain they could not be accepted and received as such in any community. They were moreover payable in large sums, at distant periods of time and in the coin of a foreign country to which they were transmitted, and where they were sold or pledged. They were, in short, wholly unadapted to circulation as
We find, then, in all the legislation of this state, antecedent to the issuing of these bonds, nothing", either in the direct or implied force of language, which pronounces against their validity. On the other hand it cannot be pretended that there was any express authority. The question therefore turns upon the incidental power of corporations, and particularly of banking corporations, when not specially restrained, to contract a debt for money borrowed upon a lawful occasion, and to execute an appropriate assurance for the payment of such debt at a future day. That question has already been examined, and the power asserted upon grounds which are to me satisfactory. Something however remains to be observed, which I think will place the subject in a still clearer light.
In the argument upon this branch of the case, much was said concerning the general intention of the legislature and the supposed policy of the state. These matters I will now briefly examine, endeavoring to show why, in the free banking system of 1838, the legislature omitted to impose restraints upon the business of banking, except in the particular department of issuing bills to circulate as money. That system has been undoubtedly in some degree misunderstood.
In the year 1791 an act was passed “to incorporate the stockholders of the Bank of New-York,” which became the model of some forty other institutions specially chartered prior" to the year 1825. These banks were authorized to carry on the “business” of banking, in general terms, without specification of the power to issue bills or any other banking power. They were unrestricted in the exercise of any of their powers except' that of contracting debt, which, over
In the year 1825 two bank charters were granted, and no others until 1829. In these, the business of banking was defined, as we have already seen, but the definition included all known powers belonging to that business, and therefore, in this respect, those charters instituted no new policy or restraint. In other respects, some new provisions were introduced, one of which required that fifty per cent of the capital stock should be actually paid in. But the system remained unchanged. The debt-creating power remained
In the year 1827 a general act was passed, which took effect in January, 1828, and became incorporated in the Revised Statutes (1 R. S., 601), applicable only to existing banks. In this statute are some new regulations concerning the management of banking corporations, directed to special abuses, but no change in the system. It was thought no important change could be made in respect to preexisting charters. The power of creating debt remained as before, and was limited, as before, to three times the amount of capital paid in, whether created by “bond, bill, note or other contract ” (§ 3); and thus the legislature, so far from restricting the right, again justifies the inference that time engagements might be issued. The issues for currency were still blended with other modes of creating debt and still the community was unprotected.
The evils and abuses of such a system gave rise also to another code of regulations, elaborately prepared, which took effect at the same time (1828), applicable to future charters and charters which should be renewed in future. This was the act to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations, (lit S., 589.) This code, as well as the one applicable to existing banks, recognized in very unambiguous language a distinction between bills and notes for circulation, payable on demand without interest, and demands of a different character and bearing interest. (§ 20, subs. 5, 8 ; id. 2, sub. 2.) It. omitted the provision limiting the amount of debt, but required the whole capital to be paid. Reports were required to be made to the comptroller
The safety fund act of 1829 took a feeble step in the right direction by establishing a specific fund for the redemption of the circulating notes of insolvent institutions. This, it is true, was a fund of very minute proportions, but, so far as it went, it provided a special security for the billholder, and tended, no doubt, in some degree, to impart stability and soundness to the currency. This act limited the issues for circulation to twice the amount of capital paid in, and, for the first time in the legislation of this state, it prohibited the issue of bills and notes unless payable on demand. The act was only applicable to future charters, or previous ones to be renewed. Between the years 1829 and 1836, inclusive, many bank charters were granted, subject to the code of regulations and the safety fund law. But fundamental principles underwent no change, and the system was soon after exploded by its own inherent vices.
Thus far, since 1804, banking in this state had been a monopoly by force of the restraining laws. In the year 1837 these monopolies had become intensely odious, and no more special charter's were then or ever afterwards granted. The legislature, moreover, as we have before seen, by a change in those laws in the year 1837, reduced banking to a private business, except in the department of creating a circulating medium, and, as a private business, left it absolutely without restraint or control. Any person or association could deal in bullion, could habitually lend money, could receive deposits, discount notes and bills, and with these banking powers could run in debt, borrow money and execute every species of obligation, except circulating notes, just as a private person in any other business could do.
At that period (1838) the principles of banking had undergone a thorough discussion both in this country and England. The ablest theorists and writers had asserted the duty of government to exact absolute security for the redemption of the circulating medium, and the policy of leaving banking, in all its other operations, like merchandize a private business. These views prevailed with the legislature of Mew-York. The preexisting system, so often amended without any change in its fundamental principles, had fallen in the crisis of 1837. All the forms of special charter, and all the codes and regulations which made up that system, were before the legislature and received a most careful consideration. They were all discarded, and a policy entirely new was adopted. The cardinal point was to render the circulation absolutely secure. This was accomplished by providing for a deposit of mortgages and stocks, dollar for dollar, and by leaving the restraining laws in force as to all issues for currency not thus secured. Connected with this fundamental measure was the policy, adopted by the legislature of 1837, as to other modes of banking, of permitting individuals and associations to issue their notes on giving the required security. This was also done. The next grand idea was to leave banking, in all its other operations, with the fewest possible restraints, and to permit it to be carried on like other branches of business. This too was accomplished. These were the great features of the organic act of 1838, and they were wide departures from all legislation prior to
Thus, in the simple contrivance of exacting security to be deposited with the government for all circulating notes, and causing them to be issued with the government stamp, we have a paper currency which has been favorably tested now for nearly twenty years. How, it may well be asked, is this contrivance, so simple and efficacious, improved by judicially attaching to it either the provisions or policy of the exploded system? A code of regulations, like the ac" which took effect in 1828, “ to prevent the insolvency of moneyed incorporations,” ineffectual as it proved to be, was nevertheless appropriate in a banking system which gave to the circulation no other protection than the solvency of the chartered banks. Such a system could not be too watchfully guarded, for the currency and the bank must go down together. But such regulations are inappropriate to the free banking system, because principles entirely new lie at its foundation. Persons who are not bankers at all may-have circulating notes if they will go and deposit the required security for their redemption. So may associations which will do the same, and file a certificate as the evidence of their organization. Private individuals and associations O may also, if they choose, carry on the general business of banking in the departments of discount, deposit, &c. They may discount with their circulation, or with other capital at their command. If they circulate, they must secure one hundred cents on the dollar; but the idea of preventing the banker’s insolvency, which’ had proved so fallacious, was wholly abandoned. The private banker or the association might be solvent or insolvent—might deal with actual or borrowed capital; but the currency, which is the life-blood of commercial and industrial communities, was rendered
Upon this subject views to which I cannot assent have made some progress. The courts began, at an early day, by declaring associations, which had filed a certificate, to be corporations. This was a simple common law necessity, resulting from the peculiarities of a common seal, perpetual succession, &c. But this doctrine surely did not, by any legal or logical sequence, draw after it, and incorporate into the banking law of 1838, all or any of the complex machinery of an exploded system. Yet it is true, starting at that point, that, by a mere logic of words, we can, if we will, take in both the act of 1828, to prevent insolvency, and the safety fund law of 1829, and annex them as adjuncts to the system of 1838. I say the safety fund law, for it begins by declaring that “ every moneyed corporation, having banking powers, hereafter to be created in this state, shall be subject to the provisions of this act.” Associations under the general law, we admit, are corporations, and clearly they have banking powers. We find here a perfect adaptation of words to a result, and that result is, that every free bank in the state must contribute its. one-half per cent annually, for six years, to the safety fund; and, by the same reasoning, we car.
It is by following, in the same way, mere verbal sequences, that efforts have been made with some success to bring into the free banking system the elaborate act of 1828, to prevent insolvency. But we shall find the difficulties still greater. Some of the provisions of that act are absolutely incongruous and cannot by any ingenuity be made to harmonize with the law of 1838. We have been told by a resolution that we may take them so far as “ not inconsistent.” ( Talmage v. Pell, supra.) What is to be the degree of consistency or inconsistency, and how much ingenuity must be exercised upon each question as it arises, we have not been informed. If we are to take them when not absolutely repugnant, then we must adopt the entire safety fund act also. If this is not the rule, then must we adopt them when they are only slightly repugnant ? Even in that case, we must take in also the safety fund statute. I repeat, the difficulties are still greater; for aside from the admitted impossibility of receiving into the system of 1838 many of the provisions of the act to prevent insolvency, &c., we shall find that some of them, deemed useful in the working of the free banking associations, were adopted verbatim, and one or two others with modifications. This I hold to be unanswerable proof that the legislature care
IV. If the trust bonds had not been issued before the 3d of June, 1840, when the act of May 14th took effect, which made it unlawful to “issue or put in circulation any bill or note, unless payable on demand and without interest,” some questions would arise which have not been discussed. But the evidence shows, beyond any reasonable doubt, that they were issued before that day. [The learned judge here stated the facts in regard to the negotiation of the trust bonds; the pledge of such bonds to the Palmers; the alterations in the form of the deeds, and the substitution of sets of bonds, substantially as stated on pp. 27, and 33-38, ante, and then proceeded. ]
Upon these facts, the counsel for the receiver have insisted that all the so-called bonds, which they claim were unsealed instruments, and, therefore, in legal effect, promissory notes, except the one hundred and eighty-seven sold before June 3d, 1840, fall under the condemnation of the statute which took effect on that day. It has also been urged that no more than the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds were ever negotiated or sold in pursuance of the trusts, and therefore that the trusts, if not illegal or void in their creation, never became operative as to all the residue of the bonds. It will be seen that both of these propositions are refuted, if the pledge to the Palmers was effectual, according to the intention of the parties, so as to give them a right to hold the bonds until they could be sold; and if they could not be sold at all, then still to hold them and take the benefit of the trusts.
Y. But the receiver insists that the four hundred, and ninety-nine bonds, part of those in the million trust, were negotiated in England, at a usurious rate of interest, and on this ground it is claimed that the trust is void, so far at least as the bonds thus usuriously sold are concerned. This part of the case will now be examined. These bonds, like all the others, bore interest at the rate of six per cent; were negotiated at ninety per cent on their par value; and I assume that, when paid, the lenders will receive a higher rate of •interest than is allowed by the usury laws of this state or of England, and therefore that the bonds are void, unless by recent legislation, both here and in that country, the case is withdrawn from the operation of those laws. The statute of this state, passed April 6, 1850 (Session Laws, 334), declares that “ no corporation shall hereafter interpose the defence of usuryand the term corporation is defined in the same act so as to include banking associations. If these bonds are to be regarded as New-York contracts, I am inclined to chink that this statute would be decisive against the right of the receiver to allege usury in any stage of these causes, either as a defence to the original bill or as a foundation for his cross bill.. My impression is that the act must be construed as a repeal of the statutes of usury as to all contracts of corporations stipulating to pay interest, thus leaving the contracts in full force according to their terms, and that such an act is liable to no constitutional objection.
But however this maybe—and the subject is not free from doubt in some of its aspects—it is clear that the Legis
We are of the opinion that they are English contracts. The circumstances which are decisive upon this point may be briefly stated as follows: The bonds were not intended to be negotiated in this country. This is conclusively shown by the million trust deed, which recites that they were intended to be sold in England. Having been transmitted for that purpose, they were actually sold and the money advanced upon them there. They were made payable in the currency of England and not of New-York. Before they were sold, the parties who actually took them entered into a written agreement with the agent of the company to take, each,- a certain number, amounting in all to four hundred and ninety-nine. This agreement was made, in London. The interest, semi-annually, during the period they had to run, was, by the terms of the bonds, payable at the house of the Palmers, in London. The place where
These are the essential facts on which the question must turn, and they lead to the plain conclusion that the several contracts of loan, into which the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds enter as a part, are English contracts, and I think this would be so even if the facts tending to that result were less decisive. We may take the single circumstance that the interest is payable in London. The question here is one of interest, solely, and if the rate had not been specified at all, that allowed by the laws of England, in cases where there is no specification, would, most clearly, be deemed, the one in reference to which the parties contracted. If, therefore, the actual rate agreed upon will amount in the result to eight or ten per cent, and that is not unlawful there upon contracts of this particular character, but would be, as it plainly was, by the statutes of New-York in force at the time of these transactions, then it is still more plain that the English laws must govern. The lawfulness or unlawfulness of the contract, as determined by the statutes and policy of the country to which we assign the dealing, very commonly
Were the loans, then, upon the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds, usurious by the laws of England ? They certainly were, until the statute of 2d and 3d Victoria, ch. 37, enacted in 1839. This act provided that “ from and after the passing thereof, no bill of exchange or promissory note, made payable at or within twelve months from the date, or not having more than twelve months to run, nor any contract for the loan or forbearance of money above the sum of ten pounds sterling,” should be void by reason of any rate of interest taken or agreed to be taken. Loans of money upon the “ security of any lands, tenements or hereditaments, or any interest therein,” are expressly excepted from the operation of the act; and there is another provision limiting the rate of interest to five per cent, as it stood before, in all cases where the parties did not otherwise agree. The statute was to continue in force only until January 1, 1842, a period which included the transactions now in question. The argument on the part of the receiver is, that the four hundred and ninety-nine so-called bonds, in consequence of the imperfect sealing, were, in legal effect, promissory notes having more than twelve months to run, and therefore that they do not come within this statute. If they are not held to be promissory notes, then it is further insisted that the loans were secured upon lands, and so were excepted from the operation of the act.
We here reach the inquiry whether the bonds were sealed instruments, and as we hold them to be English contracts, that question also must be determined by the law of England. The validity of the seal goes. directly to the obligation of the contracts, and, like any other question
VI. The claim of the Philadelphia banks, or their assignees, to the benefits of the half million trust as pledgees of the two hundred and seventy bonds, part of the four hundred and fifty issued under that trust, presents not only the question of usury, but some others of considerable importance.
[The learned judge here stated the facts substantial, as stated at pp. 28-32, ante, and then proceeded. ]
Upon these facts the receiver insists, in the first place, that the rate of interest on the loan of $250,000, although in terms six per cent, will amount, when the certificates of deposit are paid, to more than seven per cent on the sum actually received in cash, and therefore that the contract was usurious and void by the laws of New-York. Without examining the question in that light, we hold that the contract must be governed by the laws of Pennsylvania. In all the negotiations, a Pennsylvania loan was evidently, in the contemplation of the parties, to be made in the currency of the Philadelphia banks, and at the rate of interest which prevails in that state. But a more controlling circumstance is, that the contract was to be performed by the' company in Pennsylvania, by the payment there of the money loaned. The authorities do not leave this question in doubt. (Story’s Con. of Laws, §§ 242, 242 a, 285—7, &c.; Dewolf v. Johnson,
But the receiver also insists that the twelve certificates of deposit were promissory notes, and being issued by the banking association after the act of May 14, 1840, took effect, are illegal and void, because expressly prohibited by that act. If this position is sound, and I do not stop to question it, the consequences upon the contract of loan, in part evidenced by those certificates, and upon the half million trust, are to be carefully considered.
It is well to observe, in the first place, that, prior to the Philadelphia loan, this trust had an independent, valid existence. This has already been shown. The four hundred and fifty trust bonds were placed in the hands of the Palmers, as pledgees, in May, 1840, and the trust itself had therefore fully taken effect as the security for those bonds. Now, it is plain that the dealing with the Philadelphia banks, in whatever light we may regard it, did not and could not invalidate the trust. The Palmers, although they parted with two hundred and seventy of the bonds, still retained, and they now hold, the remaining one hundred and eighty. If the pledge of the two hundred and seventy is void for any cause, and the receiver is in a position to assert the voidness, the result is, not that the trust is gone,
The simple inquiry then is, can the Philadelphia banks or their assignees, now in possession of the two hundred and seventy bonds, hold them as security for the moneys loaned to this company, according to the pledge under which they were delivered ? If they can, then they are ccstuis que trust in respect to the half million trust. If they cannot, then the Palmers are the only ccstuis que trust, either as holders of the other one hundred and eighty or of the whole four hundred and fifty. The solution of this question must depend, in the first place, on the general validity of the contract of loan, notwithstanding the alleged illegality and voidness of the twelve certificates of deposit or written promises to repay the money. It was lawful for the banks to lend the money, and for this company to borrow it, and engage, either verbally or in writing, to repay it at the times agreed on. The only thing unlawful, then, about the transaction was the particular form in which the engagement was given. Can the corporation, on this ground, repudiate the whole contract, keep the money, and recover back the pledge? Or, if it cannot do all this, then can it annul the pledge on the faith of which the loan was made and recover the thing, pledged ? These are very grave inquiries.
There are in the books many cases which assert the right of the more innocent party to disaffirm an illegal contract, and so recover back, on an implied assumpsit, the money or value advanced. These were relied on in the Indiana case for the particular purpose of showing that the claimant was not within the influence of the maxim “ in pari delicto,” &c. His right to relief was contested upon the force of that maxim; but principle and authority, as we said, agreed in denying its application to such a case. Now, those cases are liable to mislead us here unless we discriminate with some care. The distinction will.be seen at a single glance. They are all cases where the plaintiff had no title to-the money if the contracts were allowed to stand, and where the defendant had a right to hold it by the very terms of the contract. Hence, there was no possibility of relief except through an unqualified disaffirmance. For example, in the earliest of those cases (Smith v. Bromley, Doug., 696), the plaintiff had paid to the defendant £40, to induce him to sign a bankrupt’s certificate, and the action was brought to recover the money back. Clearly the plaintiff could have no title to the money except through the absolute invalidity and a disaffirmance of the whole contract, because, by the very terms of that contract, the defendant was entitled to retain it. So in Jaques v. Golightly (2 W. Bl, 1073), the action was brought to recover money paid for illegally insuring lottery tickets; and there, too, relief was, in the very nature of the case, impossible until the contract was wholly disaffirmed. This precise principle runs through all the cases where illegal transactions have been disaffirmed. It will be found that in all of them the contracts themselves if lawful and valid, stood directly in the way of the action. But here the broad difference is, that the Philadelphia banks can recover, and seek to recover, the money lent without a disaffirmance, and upon the very terms of the
What, then, is the precise question now before us? It is. I apprehend, whether the contract of loan made between this company and the Philadelphia banks is void, for the particular reason that in one of its incidents the company r exceeded its powers or violated the statute, the lending parties being innocent both in fact and in judgment of law What was the contract ? On the part of the banks it was to loan $250,000, and on the part of the borrower to repay the money at certain periods, and to secure the debt by a pledge of certain securities. This is' exactly what was agreed on, but, as the evidence of the promise to pay at the times specified, post notes were issued in a form prohibited by law. There was no other illegality in the transaction, and, as far as the lenders are concerned, even the notes were not illegal. As to them, they were merely worthless and void. I assume such to be the logical result of the prohibition upon the borrower against issuing them, but there is no other result. It is a mere voidness, and not a contamination which spreads itself over the whole contract.
How, a doctrine which is expressed in the words “ void I in part, void in toto,” has often found its way into books ) and judicial opinions as descriptive of the effect which a statute may have upon deeds and other instruments which have in them some forbidden vice. ’ There is, however, no such general principle of law as the maxim would seem to ’ indicate. On the contrary, the general rule is, that if the
The principle which upholds this contract is powerfully supported by a series of decisions in this state, known as the Utica insurance cases. (Utica Insurance Co. v. Scott, 19 John., 1; Same v. Kipp, 8 Cow., 20; Same v. Cadwell, 3 Wend., 296; Same v. Kipp, id., 369; Same v. Bloodgood, 4 Wend., 652.) In all these cases the Utica Insurance Company had taken notes in a course of unauthorized banking. The restraining act then in force (2 R. L., 234) declared that all notes and securities for the payment of money, made to any association, institution or company not authorized as aforesaid, should be null and void. It was held that the corporation, having violated the statute-and transcended its powers, could not recover on the notes it had discounted, but could recover on the contract of loan, being authorized by its charter to lend its surplus funds. The court, in each of the cases, affirmed the distinction between the lending contract and the security which the statute had declared void. In one of them (8 Cow., 20), the supreme court said : “It was unnecessary for the act (the restraining law) to go further than to avoid the security taken, thereby depriving the association of the means of effectual operation. True, it was competent for the legislature to have avoided the contract also. But they have not done so.” And again it was observed : “ This
There is another class of cases, arising under the British stamp acts, which seems to me entirely in point. In Cundy v. Marriott (I B. & Adol., 696), the action was on a bill of exchange, and for goods sold. The defendant bought goods of the plaintiff, and gave in payment an unstamped bill. The instrument was not only void, but by the stamp act it was a penal offence to issue it. But the plaintiff recovered on the contract of sale. (Wilson v. Vysar, 4 Taunt., 288; Chitty on Bills, 12th Am. ed., 144, 145, and notes.) Many other views of this question might be urged, but in further illustration I will only refer to the familiar doctrine that the lending banks might bring their action for money lent without noticing the securities, even if they were of unquestioned validity. The contract could be proved without the notes. If it appeared that they had been given, it would only be necessary to produce and cancel them at the trial. A fortiori, could this be done if the notes are simply void, and they are at most only void as to the innocent lenders ? In that view, it would not even be necessary to produce them at all.
VII. I come, then, to the conclusion that the loan of the . Philadelphia banks to this company, was, in all respects, a valid contract, to be performed according to its terms. The question now to be considered is, whether the pledge of the two hundred and seventy half million bonds is also valid as a special security for such loan. On this point I do not entertain a doubt. If we uphold the contract we must uphold the pledge also. The only argument tending to a different conclusion is derived from the written agreement, executed contemporaneously with the loan, which.declares, as we have seen, that the two hundred and seventy bonds are to be held as collateral to the twelve certificates of deposit. The certificates being illegal and void, it has been urged that, the pledge must fall with them. The answer is
To what, it may be asked, does the law'annex this pledge? Is it to the debt for the money lent, or to the particular form of the instrument which is the evidence of such debt ? Most clearly to the former. Such is the just construction of the agreement, and such is the judgment of the law upon the nature of the transaction. This may be tested by rules and analogies which are quite familiar. No one will doubt that á release of the debt would extinguish the post notes and the pledge also, although not mentioned in the instrument. It is just as clear that the post notes may be lost, destroyed or surrendered without affecting the debt or the security therefor. So, if the two banks should make a written assignment, reciting the loan and transferring their demands, it is plain that the certificates and all the securities held would pass without specification. A mortgage may be given, conditioned in its terms, to pay a note or a bond. The note or bond may be canceled without impairing the lien. So the lien would hold if the note or bond recited were in fact not executed, the intention being to secure an actual debt. In this very, case, if, by accident or mistake, the post notes had not been delivered, is it possible to doubt that the pledge would, nevertheless, be good? and if it would be, can the result be different if the notes are simply void? I have before shown that it is their voidness onlv
There is no occasion here to reform the -written instrument which expresses the terms and object of the pledge. It only is necessary to consider the nature of the transaction and fairly interpret the language of the contract. If we do this, it is impossible not to see that the end which all the parties had in view was to secure the debt for the money lent. The amount of the debt and the times of payment were expressed in the post notes. It was convenient language, therefore, to say that the two hundred and seventy bonds should be held as collateral to those notes. But in the same instrument the existence and cause of the debt were disclosed. The notes were merely the representatives of the debt, and no pledge could be possibly given to secure the one without securing the other also. If it were true that the terms of the pledge confined it to the notes, the law, nevertheless, instantly annexed it to the debt. I think these principles are elementary.
This question, although it would seem a very plain one, is nevertheless supposed to be embarrassed by the decision of this court in Leavitt v. Palmer (3 Comst., 19). That decision, very probably, proceded in part upon views of illegality, and its consequences as affecting the entire transaction, somewhat stronger than we might now feel inclined to sanction. But the cases differ widely. If they did not differ, we might be led to believe that principles quite familiar had somehow been overlooked. Let us note some of the points of distinction. In that case, this same company had issued to the Palmers, after the prohibitory act of May 14, 1840, forty-eight promissory notes, and created a trust to secure their payment. In the present case, on the contrary, although the notes may be void, the trust is not collateral to them and does not fall with them. The two hundred and seventy bonds were valid (that has already been shown),
. VIII. In respect to the claims of the Holfords & Co., as holders of twenty-four of the million trust bonds, it has already been observed that in May, 1840, they took them by transfer from the Palmers, who held them in pledge. They therefore have the Palmers’ rights. It appears to be well settled that a pledgee may transfer his interest in the things pledged, even without the consent of the pledgor, and for his own debt. (Story on Bailments, 214, 218.) I suppose the title of the transferee or second pledgee cannot be any weaker if the transfer is made with the consent of the original pledgor, and the consideration is a debt due from him. If this is not a satisfactory view on the subject, the alternative is that the Palmers virtually surrendered their own claim upon the bonds,' and that the company repledged them to the Holfords. In this alternative, I think the result is the same in regard to the rights of the receiver. Although the bonds were made for sale, and although the trust deed declared that to be the object in view, I see no reason why they could not be temporarily deposited with a creditor as security until a sale could be made. The pledge implies a power to sell and receive the money in satisfaction of the debt. In so pledging them there is certainly nothing which contradicts the terms of the trust or defeats its object. A sale was the ultimate purpose of the whole scheme. A pledge until that should
It has been suggested, however, that, inasmuch as these twenty-four bonds were pledged to the Holfords to secure a preexisting debt, they are not purchasers for a valuable consideration, and so not within the saving clause of the 8th section of the statute to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations. If the trust deeds could be sustained only on the ground that the holders of the bonds purchased them for a valuable consideration and without notice, within that clause of the statute, then there might be a question on the rights of these men. But it has already been shown that the validity of the trust deeds rests firmly upon another ground : I mean the express sanction and authority of the corporation.
The point was made upon the argument, that the Holfords suffered the cross bill to be taken as confessed, and hence that they are entitled to no relief. The fact is true as stated. But the allegation of the cross bill, so far as they are separately concerned, is merely that the twenty-four bonds were delivered to them as security for an “ alleged preexisting indebtedness,” and this they confessed by not answering. Their debt, it will be seen, is not controverted; and its preexistence, as we have shown, is no impeachment of their title. The trustees representing all the bondholders have answered, and all the questions which go to the general validity of the trusts and of the bonds are controverted and must be determined between them and the receiver. If the special allegation, directed against the particular claim of. the Holfords, is in law no impeachment of their rights, they have lost nothing by not answering it.
There is one other suggestion which may be due to this comparatively unimportant branch of the case. If the title of the Holfords to the twenty-four bonds fails, the result is, either that the bonds revert to the Palmers from whom they
The payment or cancellation of a portion of the bonds will not subtract from the fund until all the residue are paid. Now, as I understand the evidence produced by the receiver in endeavoring to make out the insolvency of this company, the effects held under the trusts are somewhat less than sufficient to pay the bonds after withdrawing the twenty-four in the hands of the Holfords. In this view, the general creditors can in no event receive anything out of this fund, and the question as to the Holfords’ title, therefore, concerns the other bondholders only.
The point was taken by the receiver’s counsel, although but very little discussed, that the Philadelphia loan was “ illegal as to the Bank of the United States, that institution being expressly forbidden, by its charter, to take more than six per cent.” Without suggesting other answers to this point, it will be sufficient, I think, to observe that no such objection is taken in the receiver’s bill. If it were intended to raise such a question, the charter of the bank, being a statute of another state, should have been set forth as a fact, and then that it had been violated in the transaction. Not having done so, this question cannot now be raised. It appears to be raised now for the very first time. I do not find any such point among the very great number which were presented on the hearing in the court below.
It appears that one hundred and thirty-five of the two hundred and seventy bonds delivered to the Philadelphia banks, are held by the defendants, the Morrisons, by transfer from the Bank of the United States, which, jointly with the Girard Bank, made the loan of $250,000. The Morrisons, therefore, are the claimants under the half million trust in
I have so far considered all the objections which this corporation, if no receiver had been appointed, could urge against the validity of the two trusts or the title of the various parties who hold the trust bonds. In respect to all these grounds of objection, the general creditors are in no better situation than the corporation would be if it had not been dissolved. If the receiver can repudiate the trusts, as the immediate representative of the corporation, of course the creditors will take the fruits of such repudiation; but if it has been shown that he cannot repudiate them in that character, then they have no ground to stand upon until we come to objections of another class.
But suppose these trusts were void for any one of the reasons which have been considered. If we had come to such a conclusion, we should meet another question which appears to me to be one of very great importance. The receiver, it is to be remembered, thus far stands in the shoes of the North American Trust and Banking Company. Can, then, that corporation allege the invalidity of its own acts, and annul these trusts, after receiving a full consideration therefor, without restitution to the bondholders who acted
It only remains now to consider a different class of objections to the two trusts proceeding, on the grounds of fraud upon the rights of creditors, or of illegal preference between them. These are unavailable to the corporation, but it has been conceded that the creditors may, through the receiver, invalidate the trusts, if the objections are well taken. They are three in number: First. That the trusts were created by the corporation, “ when insolvent, or in contemplation of insolvency, and with intent to give a preference to a particular creditor over other creditors,” in violation of section nine of the “ act to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations;” Second. That they were made “in trust for the use of the company,” and so are void as to creditors, under 2 R. S., 135, § 1; Third. That they were made with intent to hinder, delay or defraud creditors. These will now be examined in the order stated.
I. It has already, for other purposes, been assumed that banking associations are subjected to so many of the provisions of the statute referred to, concerning moneyed corporations, as are “not inconsistent” with the general law of 1838. I have pointed out, in another place in this discussion, the utter inconsistency of the two systems of banking, but if they can be united anywhere, it can quite as easily be done upon the ninth section, against preferences, as any other. I shall not, therefore, change the assumption on which we have so far proceeded.
The language of the statute is “No such conveyance, transfer, payment, &c., by any such corporation, when insolvent or in contemplation of insolvency, with the intent to give a preference to any particular creditor over other creditors of the company, shall be valid in law.” It is obvious, and is not denied, that to bring a transaction within
Provisions similar to this one have existed in the English and United States bankrupt laws, and in the insolvent laws of various states, and they have often come under the consideration of the courts. There is, therefore, in the books, no want of adjudged cases bearing with much directness upon this question. I shall not go over these cases. A few citations will be sufficient for the present purpose. In Fidgeon v. Sharpe (5 Taunt., 544), arising under the English bankrupt act, this doctrine was laid down as the test by which the acts of one becoming a bankrupt must be adjudged: “ It must be an act, then, not only that in effect contravenes the bankrupt laws, but it must be done with intent to contravene them, and in contemplation of bankruptcy. The innocence or guilt of the act depends on the mind of him who did it, and it cannot be in fraud of the bankrupt laws, unless the actor meant it should be so.” In Crosby y. Crouch (11 East, 261) Lord Ellenborough observed: “ Two things are necessary to concur, in order to avoid a delivery of the goods, namely, the purpose of a voluntary preference in respect to such delivery, and the contemplation of bank ruptcy at the time the goods were delivered.”
In Exerett v. Stone (3 Story, 453), Mr. Justice Story observed: “In short, contemplation of bankruptcy means a contemplation of becoming a broken up and ruined trader
Now, it has been strenuously urged that when these trusts were created the banking company was insolvent, within some definition of that term, or, at all events, that insolvency was feared and contemplated. But the true question is one of intention and motive. Was it the design of the trusts to make a partial distribution of assets amongst the creditors, or was the expedient of creating them resorted to for the purpose of raising money to pay debts, and with the bona fide expectation of removing difficulties and averting insolvency? I have looked with some attention into the evidence in the case, and can come to only one conclusion. This company was certainly under very great and alarming embarrassments for want of cash means to meet its rapidly maturing engagements, but its officers did not believe, and I think then had no reason to believe, that its resources were not amply sufficient for the ultimate payment of all creditors. They also believed, so I feel compelled to say upon the evidence, that the moneys to be raised by the successful negotiation of the trust bonds would relieve their institution and enable them to meet all demands upon it. If these are correct conclusions of fact, then the trust conveyances do not fall within the condemnation of the statute. It is an important fact that the company did go on paying its debts, as they matured, for many months after these trusts were created.
It has been urged that the debtor corporation must be deemed to have intended the result of its own acts. This is very often a useful rule of evidence in arriving at a conclusion upon a question of motive and intention, but it is not a rule of law. If a given result must, by plain and absolute necessity, follow from a particular action, or if it be so likely to follow that no two minds of equal intelligence could differ in conclusion, viewing the subject from the same point of observation as the actor himself, then there would be no injustice in holding that he intended such result. Still the
Full justice to this question, perhaps, requires that i should be presented in another light. I think we canno say, upon the language or intention of the statute unde consideration, that it includes, under any circumstances of insolvency, actual or contemplated, a security given for a loan or advance in cash where no other relations exist between the parties. The preferences condemned are those made between the existing creditors of the corporation, where the one preferred, if he loses his security, is in no worse situation than before. Equality among those having equal claims, was the evident policy of the legislature in enacting this law. If it had been the intention to include a cash loan, secured by a mortgage or a trust, then I think that, in accordance with all the analogies of the law, there would have been a saving clause in favor of the dealer having no notice of the insolvency of the corporation. We find such a clause in the previous 8th section, avoiding conveyances, &c., not authorized by a previous resolution of the directors. Its absence in the 9th section tends very much to strengthen the conclusion that such transactions are not within the intention of the statute, as I think they are not within the fair interpretation of the language used. If this is a correct view’, the result follows that the two trusts, regarded as
When, however, these trusts were created, there was a collateral design to pledge the bonds, until a sale could be made, to the Palmers, not only for future advances but for the very large debt which had already accrued in the dealings with that house; and this, as we have seen, was actually done. The question can therefore be made under the statute, whether one of the objects of the two trusts was not, through the pledge, to give to the Palmers an illegal preference of their debt over other creditors; and, according to the construction we have just indicated, no other qestion of illegal preference can possible arise upon the facts of the case.
Were, then, the trusts made in order to pledge the bonds, with intent thereby to prefer the Palmers’ debt, in violation of the statute ? In this point of view there is still less difficulty in overcoming the objection; for, aside from the general facts of the case, indicating, as we have before said, the absence of design to give illegal preferences to any creditor or party, there are some special facts whicH are still more decisive, if the only question is, as we think it is, upon this pledge. In regard to the million trust, the inquiry must be referred to a period as early as some time in February, 1840, because the second trust deed and series of bonds then took effect, embracing in the scheme all the securities after-wards included in the final trust. These bonds, as we have seen, were held under the pledge; but to facilitate their sale
II. The next question is, whether the trusts are void as to creditors, oft the ground that they were made “ in trust for the use of the corporation.” This objection rests upon certain reservations contained in the trust deeds, and upon a doctrine which was laid down by Judge Bronson, in the case of Goodrich v. Downs (6 Hill, 438), determined in the supreme court of this state. In that case the question was upon the validity of an assignment made by a failing debtor, against whom judgment had been recovered, on which execution was about to issue, of the mass of his property, being personal estate, for the benefit of part of his "creditors, but reserving to the debtor the surplus which should remain after paying the debts specified. The assignment was held fraudulent and void, Justice Bronson delivering the opinion of the court; and I do not see any reason to question the soundness of the decision, if we may understand it to rest distinctly on the ground of fraud. But the learned judge went on to say: “ The cases which have been mentioned also hold that where a deed is void in part, as
They are, in the first -place, unsustained by the authorities to which we have been referred. Before Goodrich v. Downs was decided, not a few cases had arisen in this state which involved the validity of instruments conveying a" debtor’s property in trust, with some use or advantage reserved to himself, and in most of those cases the instruments were set aside. (Murray v. Riggs, 2 John. Ch. R., 572; S. C., 15 John., 589; Hyslop v. Clark, l4 John., 458; Seaving v. Brinkerhoff, 5 John. Ch. R., 329; Austin v. Bell, 20 John., 442, 450; Mackie v. Cairns, Hopk., 373, 404; S. C., 5 Cow., 548; Wintringham v. Lafoy, 7 Cow., 736; Grover v. Wakcman, 4Paige, 23; S. C. on appeal, 11 Wend., 187.) In all these cases the conveyances had been executed while both the statutory provisions (with immaterial differences in phraseology) which have been referred to were in force. Indeed, it should be observed that the statute, against trusts in personal property for the use of the persons creating them, had been enacted in England as early as 1487. In this state it had been reenacted in 1787. It is now, as we have seen, incorporated in the revision of 1830, with some difference of language of no importance to the present question. Now, in most of the adjudged cases which have been cited, the conveyances were held void by reason of provisions contained in them for the use and benefit of the grantor, but on a careful examination we shall find that in no one of them was the decision influenced by this statute. The inquiry uniformly was whether the debtor had attempted to place his property beyond the reach of his creditors, with a fraudulent design, contrary to the other statute which has been referred to, and to the principles of the common law. In the prosecution of that inquiry the cases are not entirely uniform in reasoning
In England, as we have seen, this statute was enacted, now three hundred and seventy years ago, but I am confident we can find there no trace of the peculiar doctrine of Goodrich v. Downs. In Estwick v. Caillaud (5 Term R,., 420), Lord Abingdon had assigned part of his real and personal estate in trust, first to pay expenses, next half of the surplus to himself, and then the residue to certain of his creditors. At the trial, it was left to the jury to say whether the deed was made with an actual intent to defraud other creditors, and they found it was not. On motion made, in the court of king’s bench, to set aside the verdict, it was insisted that the conveyance was fraudulent, under the statute 13 Elizabeth, ch. 5, against alienations, with intent to defraud creditors. But the conveyance was upheld, because no actual fraud had been found by the jury. The judges, Lord Kenton, Bullee, Ashhüest and Geose, delivered their opinions seriatim, and all of them agreed that the question turned on the intention to defraud the creditors not provided for. According to the doctrine. I am endeavoring to refute, the statute against personal uses, for the benefit of the grantor, would have been entirely decisive. That statute had then been in force three hundred years, but neither the counsel.
Two cases in this court, later than Goodrich v. Downs, have been referred to as affording some sanction to the doctrine there laid down. These are Barney v. Griffin (2 Comst. 365); Leitch v. Hollister (4 Comst., 214). The first of these cases arose upon an assignment by an insolvent debtor of all his property, consisting of real estate only. The deed was held fraudulent and void. Judge Bronson, it is true, observed that “the question (of fraud) was considered upon authority in Goodrich v. Downs,” and added, “ we think the case was well decided.” I have already observed, in effect, that the decision may stand without resting it upon the particular doctrine which we are now considering. In Leitch v. Hollister (4 Comst., 214), the assignment was held good In sustaining that assignment, Judge Gardiner made some observations which appear to sanction this doctrine, but the case did not call for them.
In short, the doctrine, it is believed, rests upon no authority except the one which has been commented on. Before that decision, many cases, as we have seen, had arisen upon similar instruments, and an arduous contest was maintained in the courts, as will appear in the cases which have been cited, upon the question whether those instruments were to
Upon what.principle can this doctrine be maintained? If it can be, the question may be asked, how can any mortgage of chattels to secure a creditor stand, however free from all imputation of fraud? It is extremely well settled that p such a mortgage passes the legal title to the mortgagee. (Butler v. Miller, 1 Comst., 500; Mattison v. Baucus, id. 296.) | It is moreover true, that these instruments uniformly contain 1 one or more reservations for the benefit of the grantor. Sometimes the possession of the chattle is reserved until default, always the surplus of its value or proceeds after paying the debt. We have, then, literally “ a trust for the use” of the grantor, yet no one ever thought of impeaching these securities under the statute of personal uses. They have often been held fraudulent in fact, but were never condemned on any other ground. If this statute applies to them, then they may be wanting in all the usual badges of fraud; even the possession may be delivered to the mortgagee, still they are void, because they contain a trust for the grantor after the debt is paid.
Singular, indeed, are the consequences to which this doctrine must lead. A man may be worth $1,000,000, owing one-tenth of that sum to each of two creditors. If he makes a mortgage upon or puts in trust some of his stock or other personal estate to secure one of them, with whatever motive, the transaction is void unless he secures the other also in the same instrument; although the debt unprovided for is ten
I think it may be laid down as a proposition, nearly, if not quite self-evident, that the mere expression of a trust, when the law implies one, if not expressed, cannot, of itself, avoid a conveyance otherwise good. “ Expressio eorum qua tacite insunt nihil operatur," is a maxim of unquestionable soundness. It cannot be unlawful to stipulate for that which the law provides. The doctrine, then, which has been contended for, must go farther or it must fall to the ground. It must include conveyances of personalty, although the resulting trust be not expressed; in short, all conveyances not absolute in their intention, if there be creditors existing or subsequent.
But, contrary to all this, it has been many times held that the actual expression of a trust, which the parties really intended, saved instead of condemned the instrument. Secret trusts, attending conveyances absolute in terms, have always been regarded as a badge of fraud since the celebrated , case of Twyne (3 Coke, 80). Even the continued possession of chattels by a vendor or mortgagor, usually regarded as evidence of a fraudulent trust, has been considered, in many adjudged cases, innocent, if it was provided for in the terms of the conveyance; in other words, if in its very language it expressed a trust for the use of the debtor. See cases on both sides of this question: Sturtevant v. Ballard (9 John., 337); Divver v. McLaughlin (2 Wend., 596); Bissell v. Hopkins (3 Cow., 166); and many others cited in Hare Wallace's note to Twyne's case (43 Law Lib., 41). In the numerous
What then is the true meaning of the statute ? It declares that “ all deeds of gift, all conveyances, all transfers or assign
This statute, then, only avoids conveyances, &c., which are wholly to the use- of the grantor. If we came to a different conclusion, if we held that it applied to transfers made for other objects, but containing a residuary interest or partial use for the debtor, then the question would arise whether the whole is void, or only so much of the grant as is not sustained by the valid pmposes for which it was made. On this point I should come to the conclusion that the statute does not subvert all instruments in which any inoperative trust is expressed along with others that are good, but leaves those which are good and valid to stand. This question belongs purely to the' construction of terms. If a statute in terms declares an entire conveyance void which has in it one such element, then it is all void because the legislature has chosen to make it so, but it is not void upon any other principle of law. If a deed is made with some evil intent, whether such intent is denounced by the common law or by a statute, then it is true the whole is void, because the whole is pervaded by a single vice. But a particular provision may be simply void or inoperative, either by common law or by statute, and all the others good. This is the true rule, where the question arises upon a statute simply declaring voidness, unless the declaration, in the strictest terms, embraces the whole instrument. Now, trusts in personal "estate, for the use of the person who creates them, are not illegal or criminal, unless they are made with fraudulent motives. In themselves they are entirely innocent. They are simply declared
Is it, then, the necessary construction of this statute that all the trusts, which in themselves are valid, must fail because in the same conveyance there is one perfectly innocent in its nature, but void when the superior rights of creditors are concerned ? I think not. A single deed may have a “ conveyance,” a “ transfer ” or an “ assignment ” upon a valid trust, and another upon a void one. The terms used do not, by inevitable construction, apply to the instrument in which the void use is contained. They are satisfied by applying it to the inoperative provision only. For this there is authority directly in point. In Doe v. Pitcher (6 Taunt., 363), the question was elaborately considered upon a statute containing the same terms as this, with others also. That case not only affirms the construction I have indicated, but contains an unanswerable refutation of the maxim “ void in part void in toto,” or rather of the uses to which that maxim has sometimes been very inaccurately applied. Without pursuing this question further, the following additional authorities may be referred to: Collins v. Blantern (2 Wilson, 348); Pigott’s Cases (11 Coke, 27); Darling v. Rogers (22 Wend., 487 ); Patterson v. Jenks (2 Peters, 235); Norton v. Simmes (Hobart, 12 c); Mackie v. Cairns (5 Cow., 564, per Sutherland, J.).
III. The remaining objection to the trusts is, that they were made with intent to hinder, delay or defraud creditors, and are therefore void under the statute against fraudulent alienations, and by the principles of the common law, which that statute merely affirms. It is scarcely claimed that there are any facts, out of the trust deeds, to sustain the allegation of fraud, and it will be found that the general features of the case point with great clearness to an opposite conclusion.
This company was certainly in a situation of extreme embarrassment, and even of great peril. It might possibly
If fraudulent motives cannot be imputed to the mere act of borrowing in order to pay debts, as most clearly it cannot, we are to inquire whether the allegation can be sustained because a trust, rather than some other instrument, was selected as the mode of security. I speak now of the general and essential nature of the trust as a security, and not of its particular provisions. We are to observe that the property embraced in the trusts consisted wholly of choses in action, and therefore it was never liable to legal process. The trusts, therefore, did not withdraw it from execution, and as to the residuary interest in the fund, that could be reached in equity precisely as it could be if the transaction had been put in any other form. A direct pledge or mortgage was
I repeat, that, so far as any question of fraud is concerned, it was indifferent whether the company secured the proposed loans by a pledge, a mortgage or a trust. In Leitch v. Holister (4 Comst., 211), this court sustained an assignment, by a debtor, of a chose in action, to several of his creditors jointly, to secure their separate demands, but reserving the surplus to himself. It was not, like these trusts, a security for raising money to pay all debts, but a preferential assignment to secure a party only, with no provision for the residue. Judge Gardiner, delivering the opinion of the court, seems to have considered the instrument as a mortgage; which may well be doubted. But the distinction was plainly of no value, as will be seen from his remarks. He observed: “The property assigned was a chose in action. The complainant acquired a lien upon the interest of the assignor the moment his bill was filed. He was then at liberty to redeem or require a sale, subject to the rights of the respondents [the assignees], or compel an application of the surplus upon his own debt.” “ He has, therefore, not been hindered or sustained any injury other than that he has been postponed to other creditors equally meritorious with himself.” This reasoning, which appears to be entirely sound, obliterates all possibility of distinction, upon a question of fraud, between a trust and any other instrument, where, either from the nature of the security or of the property, the debtor’s interest can be reached in equity only. It cannot be said that a trust withdraws property from execution at law which was never liable to it; and as to the equitable remedy, that is the
The question of fraud, then, so far, stands thus: The company intended and hoped to pay its debts and go on with its business. To that end it determined to borrow a million and then a half million of dollars. In all this there may have been delusion and folly but clearly no fraud. It also determined to secure the loans by trust deeds conveying to trustees a certain portion, suitable in amount, of the securities for money which it possessed and which could not otherwise be realized in cash; and we have also seen that this was a mode of proceeding in principle quite as unobjectionable as any other. Where, then, it may be asked, is the fraud, so long as the law allows a debtor, in the hope of paying his debts, to borrow money and give a special security for the loan ?
But the argument on this question was understood to rely upon special reservations in the deeds for the benefit of the company. Instruments containing such reservations in favor of debtors have been so often set aside that unless we discriminate we are liable to conclude that they are fraudulent and wrong in their own essential nature. This is entirely a mistake. In and of themselves they are perfectly innocuous.
A man proposing to create a security upon his estate, or to assign it upon any trust, has a plain right in general to reserve to himself just such interests and benefits as he and those with whom he is dealing can agree upon. The law upon this subject is entirely adapted to the dealings of mankind.
If the owner makes a purely nominal conveyance of his personal estate, reserving to himself the entire use, then there f is no reason of convenience or necessity for giving any effect to the transaction. It is simply ineffectual, without regard , to motives. On this idea is founded the statute of personal j trusts where the use is wholly to the grantor. But in the I business of every trader exigencies will arise requiring a | pledge, a mortgage or some other assurance less than an
These principles, which are elementary, may be illustrate) 1 by the trust deeds now in question. We may take the million trust, as the two are alike. It declares that this company has issued its bonds for sale, in England, to the amount of $1,000,000; that the company, actuated by a desire to secure the payment of said bonds to the holders, has transferred certain specific securities, set forth in a schedule, to certain trustees for that purpose; and thereupon the trustees agree that they will hold such securities for such purpose. Then follows a provision that the securities shall be held in trust for the company until default in paying interest or principal upon the bonds, which is plainly limited, however, in the same sentence, to a trust for the mere purpose of allowing the company, until such default, to receive the interest accruing on the securities pledged. Then follow appropriate powers given to the trustees, to be exercised, after default, in converting the estate assigned and applying the proceeds to the payment of the bonds, among which are powers to raise money by a sale or borrow it by a pledge of the securities assigned. Inasmuch as moneys might become due on the securities during the existence of the trust, the
These trusts, then, although unusual in their magnitude, so far as any question of principle is concerned, belong to an innumerable class of dealings which take place in all communities where people engaged in various pursuits of life borrow money upon special security. The obnoxious feature is supposed to be in reserving uses and benefits out of the estate pledged; but it has not been contended that men and corporations cannot borrow money for legitimate uses, upon a pledge of property, without, at the same time, declaring further trusts in favor of their creditors. Yet to that result the argument against these trusts inevitably comes.
If this corporation had contemplated insolvency and a closing up of its concerns, and we were able to say that through the reservations in the trust deeds, it intended to tie up and place beyond the reach of its creditors any portion of its effects for its own use, then we might pronounce them fraudulent. But these conclusions would be directly contrary to the facts of the case. The danger of insolvency may have been very great, but we know it was not in fad contemplated. The corporation was forced into liquidation more than a year afterwards. It could not have intended to reserve a fund for its own use in defiance of creditors, for it is impossible to say that securities were pledged to any greater amount than was imperatively required in order to obtain the loans proposed. And there is a further difficulty in the way of imputing such a design. In what way, it may well be asked, could this corporation fraudulently set aside .a fund and use it, in a state of insolvency, with its creditors kept at bay ? The difficulty is in inventing some mode of corporate existence, sustained only by a reserved fund, with its creditors unpaid. Private debtors often resort to such expedients, and sometimes live in splendor on estates which justly belong to their creditors. Now, I suppose that an artificial being may, in judgment of law, intend to defraud
It can only be necessary to observe, further, that all the cases relied upon in support of this objection, are distinguishable by features which are fatal to the analogy supposed. The leading cases cited are Mackie v. Cairns (5 Cow., 549); Grover v. Wakeman (11 Wend., 187); Goodrich v. Downes (6 Hill, 440); Barney v. Griffin (2 Const., 365). In all these, and in all others of the class, it will be found that the assignor was an insolvent or failing debtor. In none of them was it the design or purpose of the instrument to raise money and pay debts. In all of them the assignment was of itself an act of voluntary bankruptcy, and not, as here, a scheme to raise money in a crisis for the very purpose of averting bankruptcy. In those cases the insolvent or failing debtor-conveyed the whole, or the mass of Iris estate, either for the benefit of only part of his creditors, leaving the other portion unprovided for, either in the trust or in other property not assigned, or, if all were provided for, it was only done on condition of a release or some other benefit to the assignor. In some of them the claims of creditors were made expressly subject to a reservation for the support of the debtor and his family. In others, while a part of the creditors were not embraced in the trust, the surplus of the estate was reserved to the debtor. But it may be safely affirmed that no decision was ever made annulling a conveyance solely and merely on the ground that it contained provisions in favor of the grantor. In themselves we have seen that such provisions are lawful.
The principle, indeed, which runs through this whole branch of our law, is, that when a trader or dealer fails, and proposes to put his estate in trust, he must devote the whole of it, immediately and unconditionally, to the payment of his debts. It is only on those terms that he is allowed to withdraw it from the ordinary process of the law. He must reserve nothing to himself, but must give all to his creditors. The principle is sound, but it is not to be applied to transactions of a totally different nature. It is not a principle which interferes hi the honest arrangements which a person in debt may make to remove present embarrassments and go on in business. He may, like other men, in good faith, mortgage, pledge or put in trust his estate or a portion of it to raise money for such purposes, and when he does so, all the accustomed forms of dealing require that the uses of the conveyance should be declared, including the reversion to himself after the obligation is discharged. Such was the real nature of these trusts, and I can see no more reason for applying the principle stated to them than to the common transaction of pledging shares of stock to obtain at a bank the discount of a promissory note.
Having now examined all the objections, my conclusion is that the million and half million trusts are legal and valid; and that the several holders of the bonds are entitled to be paid out of the property and funds embraced in those trusts.
This is a conclusion which necessarily affirms the validity of the debt of the Palmers & Co., who are, as we have seen, pledgees of a portion of the bonds. The principles involved in that branch of the case were considered by this court in the case of The State of Indiana, and they are also now dis
Johnson and Bowen, Js., concurred in this opinion, in respect to the propositions adopted by the court, which will be found at the close of the opinions, post.
When it was judicially ascertained that the associations formed, pursuant to the act of the 18th April, 1838, to authorize the business of banking, were bodies corporate, it followed, as a consequence, that they were also subject to the provisions of the statute concerning moneyed corporations. (1 R. S., 601.) Such is the judgment of this court in Talmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328), as expressed in the first resolution. The learned judge who delivered the opinion declined to consider whether the certificates of deposit were promissory notes payable on time and void under the first and thirty-fifth sections of the safety fund act, or whether the assignment in question in that action was made when the corporation was insolvent or in contemplation of insolvency. He placed the decision solely upon the want of authority to traffic in stocks, or to purchase them as a means of obtaining money to discharge existing liabilities. The resolution, however, expressly declares that these associations are moneyed corporations, within the meaning of the statutes relating to such .corporations, and are bound and affected by those statutes, except so far as they are inconsistent with the provisions of the act to authorize the business of banking, or the act amending the same. (Gillet v. Phillips, 3 Kern., 114.) In Gillet v. Campbell (1 Denio, 520), an opposite opinion was held. The same judge, however, who delivered it, when he came afterwards to pronounce the judgment in Gillet v. Moody (3 Comst., 479), was not entirely certain that it stood on a firm foundation.
The first subject which I shall consider in the progress of this investigation is, the force and validity of the trust deed, and the assignments of the bonds and mortgages, which are parts of the same transaction. It is, under these deeds, that the trustees and the Palmers, and other creditors through them, claim the bonds and mortgages which are the subjects in controversy in both actions. The counsel for the receiver insist that they are void, because not authorized by a previous resolution of the board of directors of the bank. Section eight, of the act concerning moneyed corporations, declares “ that no conveyance, assignment or transfer, not authorized by a previous resolution of the board of directors, shall be made by any such corporation, of any of its real estate, or of any of its effects, exceeding the value of $1000.” [The learned judge here states the facts substantially, as on p. 22-23, ante,and proceeds.] The resolution of the 6th of January authorized the issue of the bonds to the amount of one million of dollars. It appointed the time from which they were to draw interest. It also authorized the assignment of the bonds and mortgages to trustees to secure tire
The final million trust deed, dated February 1st, 1840, was executed by the parties of the first and second parts in the city of New-York, on the twentieth of April of that year, and forwarded to the Palmers in London for execution at the same time. Before the third of June following, its execution by all the parties was complete. The bonds were also changed so as to refer to Blatchford, Graham and Curtis as trustees, in place of Beers, Graham and Tylee. The alterations to which I have referred, in the several instruments,
The ninth section of the same title, concerning moneyed , corporations, avoids every “ conveyance, assignment, transfer, payment made, judgment suffered, lien created or security given by any such corporation, when insolvent or in conteniplation of insolvency, with intent to give a preference to any particular creditor over other creditors.” The insolvency, or the contemplation of insolvency, with the intent to give the preference, at the time the trust deed was executed and the bonds and mortgages assigned, are facts relied upon by the receiver, to defeat the title of the trustees and those claiming through them. These facts must be established by the proof. The onus rests upon him. The bank must be shown to have been insolvent, or to have contemplated insolvency, on the 20th of April, 1840, that being the time when the transaction must be deemed to have been consummated. There must also have existed, at the time, an intent to give a preference, and this, too, whether the bank was actually insolvent .or merely contemplated insolvency. Generally, the qualifying words relate to the immediate antecedent, unless the sense requires a more extended application. Here, the object of the statute manifestly is to prevent preferences while insolvent or with a view to insolvency, and the qualifying words must apply to each of the predicates. Otherwise, an - act done for an honest and laudable purpose, even a payment made in the ordinary course of business, with no suspicion of the inability of the corporation to meet all its engagements, could be vacated and avoided by the subsequent discovery of insolvency. If the term insolvency, as applied to this and like institutions, signifies the want of cash or available cash resources with which the bank could have paid its debts and liabilities, outstanding at the time, then it was not solvent. It is not pretended, indeed it could not
To avoid the payment or transfer upon the other ground mentioned, in the section, there must have been a design to give a preference and a contemplation of insolvency. Contemplation is an operation of the mind, a purpose, an intention. The object of the law is to insure an equal distribution of the assets of an insolvent corporation amongst the creditors. The intention to give a preference and become insolvent defeats this end. They are voluntary acts. Payments made under the pressure of importunity, or transfers made with a view to raise money in the hope of a successful prosecution of the business, could not be regarded as manifestations of the unlawful intent. Indeed I do not perceive how a sale or mortgage of property to obtain money, while it is actually appropriated to the uses of the company in the prosecution of its legitimate business, could be esteemed evidence of a design to give a preference. If the object of the law is to insure equality amongst the creditors, the preference must be given to a creditor, and the payment or transfer made to satisfy or secure a preexisting debt. [The learned judge here cited from Fidgeon v. Sharpe, Crosby v. Crouch and Everett v. Stone, passages defining the intent to give a preference in contemplation of bankruptcy, quoted for the same purpose by Comstock, J., ante, p. 109. He then discussed, at some length, the evidence in relation to the insolvency of the company, and the knowledge of its officers upon that subject, and then proceeded.] It is not easy to resist the conclusion that the weight of the evidence is in favor of the solvency of the company at the time the trust deed and the transfers were made. In 1841, Strong, Davis and others of the directors, purchased no inconsiderable amount of the company’s stock. Loans of money were made to it by other directors, and some of them guaranteed the payment of loans of money obtained from strangers.
It is not claimed that the proof makes out an actual fraudulent purpose in the execution of the deed, but it is said that it is fraudulent, per se, being made in trust for the use of the grantor. The object of the deed was to obtain money upon the bonds. It took the form of a trust, but was, in fact, a mortgage, and, like any other mortgage, made to secure the payment of money to be borrowed. Until the money was obtained it did not have effect. Until that time the transaction was inchoate and incomplete, and subject to the revocation of the company, and consequently to all the claims of the company’s creditors. The conveyance and transfer, as soon as it took effect, was not wholly for the use of the company. That was not its principal or priman end. The primary trust in the deed was to secure the pay
Among the objections taken by the receiver to the bonds which it is the office of the trust deed to secure, is that of usury. At the sum at which they were taken by the holders, a rate of interest greater than that provided by the laws of this state or of England was reserved. They were actually sold in London, were made payable there in pounds sterling, the currency of Great Britain. The contracts must be deemed
This brings me to consider what I have regarded as the principal question to be determined, and that is, the power and authority of these corporations to borrow money. If they have no such authority, then the transaction of obtaining the money and issuing the bonds is ultra vires, and cannot be upheld. But, on the other hand, if the obtaining money upon loan is an act fairly within the scope of the legitimate power of the association, then the contracts are legal and valid, and such as the law will execute and enforce.
The stock of .the banking company was originally $2,000,000, and it was afterwards increased to $3,285,900. More than three-fourths of this large sum was made up of bonds and mortgages upon real estate, of which those in controversy in these actions, were a part. The bank might acquire this class of securities upon loans under the eighteenth section. It might also acquire them for the purpose of deposit with the comptroller, under the seventh section. The bonds and mortgages were taken in exchange for the company’s stock, and comparatively few of them were lodged with the comptroller. Beyond the two sections to which I have referred, and for the purposes therein indicated, I know of no authority of the bank to.accept securities of this character. Yet nobody seems to doubt
It was a point much relied upon at the hearing, that these instruments were promissory notes payable on time And with interest, within the decisions before referred to, and not bonds or specialties, because there was no such seal upon them as is required by law. They certainly possess' some of the qualities of promissory notes. They are written promises for the payment of money absolutely, and at all events. In this respect, bonds for the payment of money and promissory notes,are not unlike. They have also the quality of negotiability in some sense, for they are payable to Walter Mead or his assigns, and upon them is written an assignment executed by Mead, under his hand and seal, with a blank, where the name of the assignee may be inserted. This formality of transfer is seldom found in connection with a promissory note. On the other hand, the form of the instruments is that of bonds. This is the designation given to them in the instruments themselves, and also in the trust deed. They have also a formal attestation clause, in which it is said the banking company have caused this bond to be attested in their behalf by their president and cashier, and their seal to be thereunto affixed. Then follows the corporate seal, impressed with, a screw press, and standing in plain relief upon the paper. There
In respect to the claim of Holford & Co., and the transactions with the Philadelphia banks, I deem it unnecessary to say more than to express my concurrence in the opinion just read by Judge Comstock.
I shall, in the first instance, examine the primary and fundamental question, viz., what power or capacity this bank possessed of incurring obligations, and whether it extended to the borrowing of money. This question is antecedent to and independent of the further
It is admitted the legislature had the constitutional power to create banks, with such faculties as they chose, in respect to the business they were to transact, the obligations they could assume, and the evidences they could furnish of such obligations. The question is, therefore, not one of power but of intention. The act itself is the only legitimate source of the bank’s powers, and to its language the court must be confined in the work of construction. But in legal enactments, as in all human composition, words are often used symbolically, or . with a secondary meaning. Hence, frequent ambiguity, and hence the necessity of exegesis and construction. In determining the powers of this bank, while we must confine ourselves to the language of the act, yet we may look to all other sources of information to evolve the true meaning of that language.
The fifteenth section of the act authorizes persons to associate, and establish offices of discount, deposit and circulation, on the terms prescribed. The eighteenth section confers the power on such associations to “ carry on the business of banking, by discounting bills, notes and other evidences of debt, by receiving deposits, by buying and selling gold and silver bullion, foreign coins and bills of exchange, in the manner specified in their articles of association, for the purposes authorized by this act, by loaning money on real and personal security, and by exercising such incidental powers as shall be necessary to carry on such business.” It will be seen this language confers the same powers as were possessed by the old banks, by virtue of their charters (Laws of 1831, ch. 178, and other acts), and was probably intended to put them upon an equality in regard to their powers; although the old bank charters contained restrictions peculiar to them, and not found in this general act. The receiver’s counsel contend that the powers enumerated in the eighteenth section exclude all
The power to receive deposits is given specifically, and without limitation. But what are deposits, and what, in commercial law, are the obligations which are, or may be, assumed by the parties to that species of contract ? Originally, a deposit of money was made by placing a sum of money in gold or silver with a bank or other depositary, to be returned, when called for, in the same indent!cal coin, and without interest, the depositor paying the depositary a compensation for his care. But, for more than a century prior to the passage of the act in question, the term “deposit” had come to mean quite a different transaction, as to the rights and liabilities of the parties to it. It became customary to deposit money for a particular period, and on interest, or payable at certain prescribed periods after notice. In short, the term deposit became a symbolical word to designate not only a deposit, in its original sense, but all that class of contracts where money in any of its forms, as specie or bank bills, was placed in the hands of banks of bankers, to be returned in other money, on call or at a specified period, and with or without interest. The transaction it designated, in this figurative use of the term, was in reality the same as that called a loan of money, when it occured between individuals. In this last and widest acception of the term deposit, it was most probably used by the legislature of 1838; for it was well know in all commercial communities, at that period, and to all competent legislators, that borrowing money to lend again is a part of
I am unable to perceive any reasons of policy to deny to the banks the privilege of incurring obligation by way of loan while they can incur the like obligation by taking in deposits. In truth, the obligations we have seen are the same, except in name. The act does not define the mean ing of the term deposit, nor does it in any way restrict its meaning. Hence we are at liberty to assume it to have been used in that sense in which it was used and understood amongst banks and bankers. These considerations tend to the conclusion that the legislature intended to include the power or privilege of borrowing money in the power to receive deposits, that it meant the same thing, in commercial language.
That the power to borrow money is a legitimate inference from the power to take in deposits, and is indeed a unit with that power, is proved by the decision made in reference to other clauses of this act, and other similar charters. In Safford v. Wyckoff (4 Hill, 422), the question arose whether d bank organized under this act could bind itself by a bill of exchange not countersigned and registered by the comptroller. The Court of Errors held that it could, and that the power to sell bills of exchange included the power to draw bills of exchange; and that as the drawing such bills was a usual, ordinary business of banking, it could not be presumed the legislature intended to prohibit it. There is another class of obligations into which these banks can enter, and which, though not expressed, are yet inferred as incidental to the power of receiving deposits. It is that of assuming to charge endorsers of the notes of its customers left with the bank for collection. This obligation springs
In addition to the express powers enumerated, the act confers all necessary incidental powers to carry on the business authorized, viz., the business of banking in the three departments of issue, deposit and discount. The word necessary, as here used, does not mean physical, or logical, or moral necessity; because, if it did, then the opinion of the chancellor, in the case of Safford v. Wyckoff, and every other member of that court whose opinions are reported, cannot be sustained. They all concurred in holding that the bank could incur indebtedness for rent, clerk hire, &c. But if the word necessity is to be construed in logical strictness, it is impossible to hold that these banks can incur any sort or degree of indebtedness, for the reason that they can always pay down or in advance. The term is used to mean that kind of necessity which custom and usage impose on
Although the power to borrow money may be justly predicated on the express power to receive deposits, on principles of construction above indicated, or may be found amongst the mass of unenumerated, incidental and necessary ones, I prefer to put my opinion upon the broad ground that every corporation, unless prohibited by law, can incur obligations, as a borrower of money, to carry on the legitimate business for which it was incorporated, although not specially authorized to borrow by its charter. Such has been the uniform language of the courts in this country. I refer to the following authorities, which cover the question,, and affirm the power in so many forms and aspects, that it ought no longer to be doubted. 12 S. & R., 256; 16 Mass., 94; 7 Wend., 31; 6 Humph., 515 ; 1 Sandf. Ch. R., 283 ; 1 Seld., 547 ; 2 id., 412; 3 W. & Mino:, 105 ;
The capacity or liability to incur obligations in conducting the legitimate business of banking is not a power, in any just sense. The term is used in a sense synonymous with franchise, and the borrowing money is not a franchise. A franchise is a special privilege conferred by government on individuals, and which does not belong to the citizen of a country generally, by common right. (Bank of Augusts v. Earle, 13 Peters, 519.) The right to issue a circulating medium, to hold property in a corporate capacity, and to perform the general functions of a banking institution, are powers, or franchises ; but the mode by which the money shall be obtained for carrying on the operation, whether by the sale of property, or by borrowing, or donation, cannot be a franchise. As well may it be said that the privilege of Keeping their money in an iron safe is a franchise or power.
Nor is there reason for the opinion advanced by some, that the legislature of 1838 intended to withhold from the banks the capacity to incur debts; but much to show the contrary intent. Prior to that time, the holders of bank bills and other creditors stood on an equality, the former having no better security than the latter, in case of the bank’s insolvency. Hence, the necessity of the prohibitions contained in the twenty-seventh and thirty-fifth sections of the act of 1829, called the safety fund act; the first named section limiting the amount of the bank’s circulation, and the' latter forbidding the issue of time paper. Both served to limit the total amount of indebtedness of banks, and contributed to the security of all classes of creditors. Hence, too, the absence of these provisions in the act of 1838. They were unnecessary, because the circulating notes of this class of banks were secured by the pledge of stocks and mortgages, deposited with the comptroller. The other creditors were left to rely on the general solvency of the banks to which they had Trusted.
The North American Trust and Banking Company had, at the time of this loan, millions of assets, in bonds and mortgages, but little or no cash capital. It became necessary to turn these assets into cash in some mode, or cease business. That it could have sold every dollar of these assets is not denied. It chose to hypothecate them instead. It may have been unwise, in a business point of view. But here the question is not one of prudence, but of power or capacity. Í have no doubt it had full power to borrow money in the manner it did, both as a necessary incidental power to carry o«t the enumerated powers specifically granted, and also as a capacity inherent in every corporation, unless expressly forbidden.
Assuming it as an established proposition, that banks organized under the law of 1838 may incur obligations, in conducting the business of banking, the next question in order is, whether any prohibition existed, prior to the law of 1840, to their executing and delivering written evidences of such obligation. It has been decided by this court, that banks organized under this law are moneyed corporations, and therefore within the provisions of title 2, of ch. 18, of part 1, of the Revised Statutes ; and to this decision we ought to adhere, whatever might be our views, were it res nova. Conceding this to be so, still I find no express provision against this class of banks executing any evidence of indebtedness they saw fit, either in the eighteenth chapter aforesaid, or in the act of 1838. In the absence of prohibition, there can be no doubt they had the right. The safety fund law of 1829 did not apply to these banks, but to such institutions only as were organized between 1829 and 1838, and to those the charters of which were amended and made subject to the provisions of that act. It is true, the first section of the safety fund act declares “ every moneyed corporation, having banking powers, hereafter to be created
As most of the obligations referred to in the trust deeds were issued before the act of 1840 took effect, that portion of them which fell into the hands of purchasers for a valuable consideration, and without notice, must be held valid securities. If any of them were issued after the act took effect, they are ineffectual as securities. It has been vehemently urged, by counsel for the appellant, that it is contrary to the policy of this state to allow banks to issue time paper. I know of no general or settled policy on the subject, nor of any source from whence it can be learned, other than the statute laws of the state. It is true that in 3829 the banks, subject to the safety fund law, were prohibited from issuing bills and notes payable in future. But this act was not general, and did not extend to the large number of banks then in existence, nor to those under the act of 1838. I have already suggested the reasons why limitations were imposed on the banks, under the safety fund system, and that those reasons do not apply to the new banking system of 1838. Not until May 14th, 1840, was the prohibition against issuing notes and bills on time extended to banking associations by name; and at the same period many other provisions, peculiar to the safety fund system, were extended to them, which clearly did not previously affect them. The legislature, by thus classing the prohibition of time paper with other provisions, which confessedly did not previously apply to the banks of 1838, seem to admit that, before that time, it was lawful to give time paper. If it had been the intention or policy of the
The appellant contends that if the obligations called bonds are valid in other respects, they are void for ustiry, whether regarded as English or New-York contracts. As these bonds were payable in England, and sold there, or the loan obtained there, it is clear that they must be considered as English contracts, and the question of usury be determined by the English law.
The respondents seek to avoid the defence of usury by three answers: First. That by the laws of England the contract is not usurious; Second. That the receiver cannot seek relief and discovery without offering to pay what is justly due, as he is not the borrower; and Third. That by the act of 1850 corporations are disabled from interposing the defence of usury. As the last answer is a valid answer to the defences, I shall pass the other two without remark, except that I am of opinion, the receiver representing the corporation for all legal purposes, that he is a borrower within' the true meaning óf the act of 1837, and is the corporation within the true meaning of the prohibition in the act of 1850. It was competent to the legislature to make this law. It did not impair the obligation of this contract, but affected the remedy only, by depriving the borrower of a defence in the nature of a penalty or forfeiture.
In 1837, the legislature altered the remedy in favor of this defence of usury, by allowing borrowers to file bills
That the act applies to contracts already made, is apparent from the explicit language used. “ To interpose the defence,” means not only to plead it and give evidence thereof, hut also to use it at the trial as a defence. The inhibition extends to the entire series of acts which constitute the defence, and to each of them. All will admit that the language of the act will include the case of such a defence, where the plea was not interposed when the act passed. But it would be unreasonable to make a distinction between such a case and one where the plea is already put in but not tried. Hence, we should hold the act to include all cases where the defence was yet to be made complete.
The next questions arise on the validity of the instruments called trust deeds. Whatever may be the most appropriate name for those instruments, I am of opinion they were such assignments, or sales of the effects of the corporation, as fall within the scope of the eighth section of the act, entitled “Of moneyed corporations” (1 R. S., 589). I am also of opinion that no such resolution, as the said section requires, was passed by the board of directors previous to such assignment. I am also of opinion that a resolution, passed subsequently, will not render valid a previous assignment, made without the requisite authority. The language of the section is positive, and admits of no other construction. The validity of the trust must depend, so far as this section operates upon it, on the fact whether the holders of the bonds were purchasers in good faith, without notice that the assignment was made without a previous resolution. The jiurchasers of those bonds, and those who advanced money upon them as pledges, are purchasers of the securities assigned by the trust deed. They obtained an interest in them the moment they advanced money upon the faith thereof; and if the trust deeds come
It is further claimed by the receiver that the trust deeds are void, because made while the company was insolvent or in contemplation of insolvency, with intent to give a preference to particular creditors over other creditors, contrary to the ninth section of the act above cited. The bonds were made to secure a loan of money to the company, to be used in the payment of the debts of the latter. It is not proved that the money to be obtained was intended to be paid to any particular creditor, or that any preference was in the contemplation of the directors. The case is not within the ninth section of the statute, for the reason that the assignment was made, not to secure existing creditors, but to secure a new class of creditors, to be thereafter created on the faith of these very assignments. The object of the section was to prevent preferences amongst existing creditors, when the company was insolvent. It did not
The trust deeds are also claimed to be void upon their face, as against creditors, because made in trust for the use of the company. In support of this position, the counsel rely on 2 R. S., 135, § 1, and some decisions of this court. (Barney v. Griffin, 2 Comst., 365; Leitch v. Hollister, 4 id., 211; Goodrich v. Dowms, 6 Hill, 438.) From a careful examination of the above section, and its origin, I am satisfied that it is to be confined to cases of trusts created for the sole benefit of the grantor of the property in trust, and is not applicable to a case like this, where the sole object of the trust is to secure third persons for a loan of money, although some trust may happen to be expressed in the deed, incidentally beneficial to the grantor.
In the case of Goodrich v. Downs, the opinion of the court alludes to the first section of this statute, and seems to rely upon it, as in point, to prove that the question of intent need not be submitted to the jury. In that respect the court probably erred, in that case, as the section cited had no bearing on the point in judgment. The question in Barney v. Griffin was on an assignment of real estate, and the said first section relates only to personal property.
I am of opinion that, in all, cases of conveyances, &c., where third persons are made beneficiaries, the case falls under 2 R. S., 337, §§ 1, 4 and 5, and the question of
Having determined that the company had capacity to sorrow money; that it was not prohibited from issuing written evidence of its promises, in any form it chose to contract, prior to the act of May 14, 1840 ; that the million and first half million trust deeds are valid in behalf of th purchasers of the bonds they were intended to secure still remains to determine who, amongst the holders • those bonds, come within the saving clause of the eighth section of the act. Clearly, none but “ purchasers for a valuable consideration and without notice ” can claim to have a good title within that section. Those bonds which were sold in London, out and out, passed to the vendees a good title or claim to the fund created by the trust, or so much thereof as will satisfy them. There is not any evidence that those several purchasers had notice of any defect in the title, and they paid valuable considerations for the said bonds.
I am also of opinion that the bonds pledged to the Messrs. Palmers, in February, 1840, for advances then and thereafter made, and in consideration of the state stocks surrendered up by them, on the faith of such pledges, place them in the position of purchasers for value, within the meaning of the said section and of the law merchant. These bonds were pledged to cover the general balance of accounts, as
The claims of the Messrs. Holford stand on different facts. It is charged in the cross bill, and is admitted in the answer of the trustees and of the Palmers, that twenty-four of those bonds were delivered to James Holford & Co., as collateral security for a preexisting indebtedness of the company, and that nothing was advanced at the time as a new consideration for said bonds; and none is alleged in the said answers. Holford & Co. have suffered the bill to be taken as confessed; but the trustees and their counsel claim ta represent their interests. Admitting this to be so, I incline to the opinion that they cannot sustain the Messrs. Holford’s claim to hold those bonds for any purpose. The Messrs. Holford are not purchasers for valuable consideration , using that term in the commercial sense; and, as applied to bills of exchange and promissory notes, the taking of the bonds, as collateral security for an antecedent debt, is not paying value within the rule, either in England or in this state. The farthest any court in this state, or the supreme court of the United States, has gone, is to hold him a purchaser for a valuable consideration, who takes a note in payment of a precedent debt. (16 Peters’ U. S. R., 1; 2 Kern., 551.) If the proof in this case would have sustained an answer, alleging that the time of credit was extended, in consequence of the deposit of those bonds, and that such fact in law would furnish the requisite valuable consideration, yet, the fatal answer is that no such fact was put in issue, and cannot be available as proof. It must be
The United States Bank of Pennsylvania and the Girard Bank, loaned to the company $250,000 in July, 1840.
[The learned judge here stated the facts in relation to the making of the loan, and issuing of the certificates of deposit, and proceeded. ]
These certificates of deposit are essentially bills or notes, and are void promises, because issued after the act of May 14, 1840, took effect. They fall within the description of paper condemned in Leavitt v. Palmer (3 Comst., 19) ; and the mortgage bonds having been taken as collateral security for the performance of those void promises, cannot be enforced. Those bonds are not bills or notes, within the act of 1840, nor are they specialties, for want of a common law seal; but I hold them to'be special agreements not under seal. They are not bills or notes, because they are not negotiable, although they, are assignable. Prior to the Code, they would have been suable in the name of the payee only. They are, in this respect, like the case of the India bonds, reported in 13 East, 510. They contain a power, in addition to a promise to pay a specific sum of
I do not deem-it necessary to inquire into the origin of all the debts due the Messrs. Palmer, which resulted in the large balance due them, on account, from the company. But in respect to that portion of it growing out of their acceptance and payment of the Davis bills, it is clear that it was not illegal in the Messrs. Palmer. The stock of the company had been purchased and paid for before the bills were drawn; and whether the purpose of the company, in allowing Davis to draw on the Palmers, was known to the latter before they accepted those bills or not, is of no legal importance. I hold it to be legal for one man to loan another money to pay an illegal debt, although he knows
It is quite uncertain whether the Messrs. Palmer sold the South Carolina Stocks to the company as principals, or as agents for one Simon, in August, 1840. But whoever was the vendor, the stocks were paid for soon after, by the company, out of the moneys received from Sanderson & Co., to whom those stocks were pledged. The purchase of those stocks, to sell again, was an unauthorized transaction, according to Talmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328). Was the same question in this case as in that, I should feel bound to follow that case, however, I might doubt its correctness. But the question is quite different. In that case, the State of Ohio was attempting to enforce payment of securities turned out to it, as collateral to promises to pay for state stocks sold the company, in opposition to the rights of the receiver, who claimed to repudiate the contracts, and to reclaim the securities. The court held the purchase ultra vires, and, therefore, not binding on- the company. Of course, the direct promise .to pay being held illegal, the collateral securities failed also. In this case, the stocks have been sold, transferred and paid for specifically, and the Company have since transferred them, by pledge or sale, to Sanderson & Co. The receiver now seeks, in effect, to recover back the money paid for those stocks, without offering to return them to the Messrs. Palmer
The eminently just principles enunciated by this court, in the case of Tracy v. Talmage, involving the claim of Indiana, will rescue all the other items in the accounts of Messrs. Palmer from the charge of illegality; and I forbear, therefore, to comment upon them in detail.
The first question which I propose to examine, is the one embraced in the proposition of the receiver: that the million and the first half million trust deeds, and the assignments of bonds and mortgages connected therewith, are void because not authorized by a previous resolution. The examination of this question necessarily involves the consideration of the question, whether the provisions o:i the title of the Revised Statutes, in relation to moneyed corporations, are applicable to banking associations organ ized under the general banking law. If this latter question was res integra, I should have very little difficulty in disposing of it. The act authorizing the business of banking contains intrinsic evidence that the legislature which passed it did not intend to authorize the creation of moneyed corporations. The word corporation is not to be found in any part of the act. The provisions inserted in every bank charter since 1828, conferring the general powers of a corporation, as defined in the Revised Statutes, are studiously omitted. The act also omits to confer, in express terms, in accordance with legislative usage, prior to the adoption of the Revised Statutes, the power to make and use a common seal, to adopt a corporate name by which to sue and be sued, and to grant and receive property, and to make bylaws for the government of the association; three of the ordinary incidents of a corporation. (Laws of 1823, § 16; 2 Kent’s Com., 278.) There is also convincing evidence in the circumstances under which the system of free banking was proposed and adopted by the legislature, independent
But, conceding the necessity of defeating the legislative intent, to authorize the formation of banking associations without imparting to them a corporate character, there certainly was no necessity for defeating the intent of the legislature, that the statutes of the state previously enacted, which related specially to moneyed corporations with banking powers, organized under the then existing system, should not apply to such associations. If the legislature intended that these associations should be partnerships merely, and not moneyed corporations, it needs no argument to show that it could not have intended that such associations should be subject to such statutes. An intent that these associations should not be moneyed corporations, necessarily embraces an intent that they should not be subject to statutes which related specially to such corporations. Besides, the act to authorize the business of banking contains internal evidence that the legislature neither contemplated or intended that such associations should be subject to the general statutes applicable to the'then existing moneyed corporations. It provides (§27) that these
The act to authorize the business of banking, also provides (§28) that if any portion of the capital of the association shall be withdrawn, whilst any debts remain unsatisfied, no dividends shall be made until the deficit of capital shall be made good. This provision is inconsistent with the provisions of the Eevised Statutes, in relation to withdrawing the capital of moneyed corporations, and the prohibition of dividends in case of a reduction of capital by losses, and shows that an entirely new system of banking was intended to be inaugurated, to which the provisions of the Eevised Statutes relating to the old system wrould not be applicable. (1 R.. S., 589.) The several acts of the legislature, passed subsequently to the act to authorize the business of banking, applying specially to banking associations provisions in previous statutes relating to moneyed corporations, especially the act of May 14, 1840, are a legislative construction of the general banking law, and are emphatic legislative declarations that banking associations were not subject to the general statutes above mentioned. It is a rule of construction of statutes, that such a construction should be put upon them as will best effectuate the intent of the makers. In my judgment, the provisions of the act to authorize the business of banking, in connection with the proceedings of the legislature attending its introduction into and passage through its two houses, clearly show an intent, on the part of the legislature, that the
There is a distinction between the statutes, exclusively applicable to moneyed corporations, and the general laws of the state, written and unwritten, applicable to all corporations. It may very well be that the determination that these associations are corporations, may necessarily subject them to such general statutes as are applicable to all corporations, as they .undoubtedly are to the rules of the common law in respect to corporations in general; bu* from these - concessions, it by no means follows that thi statutes exclusively applicable to a particular class of corporations, must be applicable to these associations, in opposition to the intent of the legislature. There is no necessity for this application. These associations may be corporations without being placed in that particular class of corporations . designated in the Revised Statutes as moneyed corporations.
If 1 am right in this conclusion, the title of the Revised Statutes in relation to moneyed corporations, is not applicable to these banking associations. But although I entertain no doubt in respect to the soundness of this conclusion, I apprehend that we cannot give effect to it in this case, in consequence of several decisions of this court the other way. In Gillett v. Moody (3 Comst., 479), where the directors of the St. Lawrence bank (a banking association), after such bank had stopped payment, purchased of the defendant, a director,' his stock in the bank, and paid him for the same an equal amount in Arkansas bonds, it was held by this court, Judge Bronsok delivering the opinion of the court, that the act was forbidden by the second and fifth subdivisions of the first section of the title of the Revised Statutes, in relation to moneyed corporations, which prohibit the directors from dividing, withdrawing or paying to the stockholders any part of the capital stock of the corporation, &c., and the application of the funds of the corporation, except siuqfius profits, to the purchase of
In Talmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328, 340), Judge Gardiner expresses the opinion that banking associations, as banking corporations, were'subject to all the general laws relating to that class of corporations, except so far as those general laws have been modified or superseded by the general banking law; and he says this proposition is the necessary result of the decision in the Supervisors of Niagara v. The People (7 Hill, 504), and Gillet v. Moody, in this court. Judge Gardiner proceeds and says, p. 341: “ If banking associations are subject to taxation, and to the act to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations, as settled by the adjudications, no reason is perceived why they are not bound by all general laws relating to moneyed corporations not in conflict with the one under which they were created.”
In Gillett v. Philips (3 Ker., 116), where the St. Lawrence Bank, a banking association, in December, 1841, stopped specie payments, and was then insolvent, and afterwards, in April, 1842, the cashier sold to the defendant, a stockholder in and a director of the bank, three promissory notes owned by the bank, amounting to $2016, for $1200, for the purpose of raising funds to redeem the circulating notes of the bank, it was decided by this court, Gardiner, C. J., delivering the opinion of the court, that the sale of the notes was void, being made in violation of the eighth section of the title of the Revised Statutes in relation to moneyed corporations.
We are asked by the counsel for the respondents not to regard these decisions as authority, for the reason that the point, of the applicability of the title of the Revised Statutes, in relation to the moneyed corporations, to banking associations, did not arise in the case of Talmage v. Pell,
It is quite clear that this question has never been fully considered by this court; but inasmuch as it has been expressly determined by the court in two cases, I do not feel at liberty to disregard the determination, although I believe it to be erroneous, for I do not think that the correction of the error will compensate for the mischief of shaking the stability of the decisions of the court. “It is essential to the security of property that a rule should be adhered to when settled, whatever doubt there may be as to the grounds on which it originally stood.” (Per Sir Wm. Grant, 18 Ves., 110.)
If the title of the Revised Statutes in relation to moneyed corporations is to be deemed to apply to banking associations, the next question to be considered is, whether the million and the first half million trust deeds, and the accompanying assignments of bonds and mortgages, were authorized by a previous resolution of the board of directors. The only previous resolution of the board of directors, in relation to the million trust, previous to the execution of the final million trust deed and of the accompanying assignments, was that of the 6th January, 1840. That resolution furnished no authority for executing the trust deed anJ
The eighth section of the title in relation to moneyed corporations inhibits the assignment by such corporations of any of their effects, exceeding the value of $1,000, unless authorized by a previous resolution of the board of directors. This statutory provision limited the jus disponendi of these corporations, and should have been strictly pursued by the directors of the North American Trust and Banking Company. The previous resolution adopted by its board of directors should, at least, have specified the names of the trustees and the amount of the securities to be assigned. There was no previous resolution of the board of directors, of any kind, authorizing the execution of the first half million trust deed and its accompanying assignments.
The want of original authority, to execute the million and the first half million trust deeds and accompany assignments, could, not be supplied by a subsequent ratification, because the statute peremptorily calls for a previous resolution, and the statute is to be strictly pursued. Even in the case of conventional powers, where the nature and
The cases referred to by the receiver’s counsel, on this point, relate to the construction of statutes granting statute powers, and to the subdelegation of judicial powers con ferred by statute, and of a delegated private authority, involving personal trust and confidence. (3 Comst., 396 ; 2 Seld., 92; 26 Wend., 485; 16 Vesey, 27.) I, however, entertain doubts whether the articles of association, and the by-laws, of the North American Trust and Banking Company, did delegate authority to its committee of investment and finance, to pass the resolution of the date of 20th April,
The remaining question under this branch of the case is, whether the holders of the mortgage bonds, issued under the two trusts, are purchasers for a valuable consideration without notice, within the meaning of the saving clause ¿1 the eighth section, before mentioned.
[The learned judge here states the disposition made of the several bonds, and proceeds. ]
The receiver insists that the saving clause of the eighth section, does not apply to a party who takes the transfer directly from the corporation; that the previous resolution is part and parcel of his title; that he is• chargeable with knowledge of the law, and is bound to see that the officers of the corporation are authorized to make the transfer; that the trustees were not purchasers for value; and that they purchased with notice that there had been no previous resolution.
Neither the letter nor spirit of the saving clause, in my judgment, authorizes the construction that it does not apply to the party who takes directly from the corporation. The language of the clause is, that the section “ shall not be construed to render void any conveyance, &c., in the hands of a purchaser, for a valuable consideration and without notice.” By these terms any purchaser, whether immediate or remote, from the corporation, is protected if he purchases for a valuable consideration, and without
In this case there is no evidence that the English bondholders had either any knowledge of the title of the Revised
If Graham, one of trustees, was chargeable, as director of the company, with knowledge that there had been no previous resolution, notice to him was not notice to his cestuis que trust. He did not stand to them in the relation of an agent. He was selected and appointed as trustee by the company, not by the cestuis que trust. His powers and duties were conferred and prescribed by the company, not by the bondholders. There were at the time of the execution of the trust deeds no bondholders; no cestuis que trust. It is a necessary attribute of an agency that it should be created by the principal; it is an agreement by which the principal confides to the agent the management of some business to be transacted in his name and on his account, and by which the agent assumes to do the business and render an account of it. (1 Bow. Law Dic., 91, tit. Agency ; 2 Kent's Com., 612; Paley on Agency, 1.) The doctrine that notice to an agent operates as constructive notice to his principal, is applicable only to cases where an agency m fact has been created; and in such cases only where the notice is to the agent while engaged in the same transaction or negotiation to which the agency applies. (Dunlap’s Paley on Agency, 262-266, and notes.) In this case, as the relation of principal and agent did not exist between the bondholders and Graham, notice to him, or knowledge by him that there was no previous resolution, was not con structive notice to the bondholders.
The purchasers of the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds, issued under the million trust, and the Palmers, as pledgees of the unsold bonds of both trusts, were purchasers for value, within the eighth section of the title in relation to moneyed corporations. The purchasers of the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds paid cash for the same, and the Palmers advanced cash, on the credit of the pledge to them of the unsold bonds as security for such advances. Mortgagees, who, at the time of becoming such, part with a new consideration on the faith of the mortgage, are bona fide purchasers for a valuable consideration, within the recording acts (1 R. S., 756, 762, §§ 1, 38,1st ed.; 4 Paige, 221; Rev. Notes to ch. 3 of 2d part of R. S.), and they are also purchasers within the statute in relation to fraudulent conveyances. (2 R. S., 134, 137, §§ 1, 7; 4 Greenl. ed. of Cruise, tit. 33, ch. 78, §§ 38, 39; Chapman v. Emery, Cowp., 279; Lister v. Turner, 5 Hare, 281.) Mortgagees of real estate, and mortgagees or pledgees of personal property, are, upon principles in analogy to those applicable to such statutes, also purchasers within the eighth section above referred to.
The only question, in this branch of the case, arises out of the delivery of the twenty-four bonds to Holford & Co.as security for a preexisting debt. Holford & Co. cannot
A preexisting debt is in all cases a good and valuable consideration for the transfer of either real or personal property, as between the parties to the transaction. It is a valuable consideration also for a sale or mortgage in good
The contest in the present case is between creditors of the corporation, to whom the twenty-four bonds in question have been pledged as security for a preexisting debt, and the receiver of the corporation, appointed subsequent to the
The next question to be examined is, whether the trust deeds and accompanying assignments are void under the ninth section of the title in relation to moneyed corpora • tions, because made by the company when insolvent or in contemplation of insolvency, with the intent of giving a preference to particular creditors. To bring these securities under the condemnation of this section, they must have been executed by the officers of the company, with the intent of giving a preference to certain particular creditors over other creditors, when the company was insolvent, or when its insolvency was contemplated by its directors and officers. The intent to give a preference, and either an actual insolvency or a contemplation of insolvency, must be proved as facts. The intent and the contemplation of insolvency may be proved either by direct evidence, or inferred as the necessary consequence of other facts clearly proved. If insolvency is relied upon to defeat the securities, knowledge of the insolvency by the directors of the company, or a belief by them that it existed at the time the securities were made, must be proved ; for an intent to give a preference to particular creditors, in fraud of all other creditors of the company, cannot be conceived, except as connected with a knowledge or belief that the company is insolvent, or with a contemplation of its insolvency. It is the intent to give a preference in violation of the statute, and in fraud of the general creditors of the company, which stamps the conveyance or assignment with criminality, and subjects the directors cooperating in such violation of the statute,
There can be no criminal intent to violate the statute and defraud the creditors, unless the conveyance or assignment is made with knowledge or belief of insolvency, or in contemplation of insolvency. If these elements are wanting in the transaction, the conveyance or assignment must be deemed to have been made in good faith, as a payment or a security, for a preexisting debt, and not with intent to give a preference. (Jones v. Howland, 8 Metc., 382, 386 ; Denny v. Dana, 2 Cush., 171, 172; 1 R. S., 591, 592, §§ 9, 10, 11, 1st ed.) It is quite apparent from the evidence, and especially from the correspondence of the managing directors and financial officers of the company, in respect to the million and first half million trusts, and the accompanying assignments, and the negotiation of the ^mortgage bonds issued under such trusts, that they had, at the time of the execution, and of issuing these instruments, no knowledge, suspicion or belief that the company was insolvent, and did not at that time, in the event of the sale of such bonds, contemplate its insolvency. I use the term insolvency, as meaning an insufficiency of the property and assets of the company to pay all its debts. The uniform and concurrent language, at this period of the history of the institution, held by its managing directors, in their letters to their foreign correspondents, expressed an earnest desire that the mortgage bonds should be negotiated in England, and a confident belief that if they should be cashed, all the engagements of the company could be met as they became due.
It is apparent, also, that the million and first half million trust deeds, and the accompanying assignments, were not made with any reference to the stoppage of payment by the company, and the liquidation and winding up of its affairs, but for the sole purpose of enabling it to continue its business, and to meet all its outstanding liabilities as
The word insolvency is defined by Webster, the “ inabilty of a person to pay all his debts ; or the state of wanting property sufficient for such payment.” Bell, in his Com
The title containing special provisions relating to certain corporations (§ 4), and the safety fund act (§ 25), recognize a distinction between a refusal to pay debts and insolvency. The same distinction is recognized in the article in relation to proceedings against corporations in equity. (2 R. S., 463, 1st ed.) Questions in respect to the meaning of insolvency, in cases arising under bankrupt acts, are exceptions to the general rule. In such cases, the signification of the word is determined by the peculiar provisions of those acts.
Within the meaning of the English bankrupt acts, a trader is an insolvent when he is not in a condition to pay his debts in the usual and ordinary course of trade and business. (Shone v. Lucas, 3 Dow & Ryl, 218 ; De Tastet v. Le Tavernier, 1 Keen, 161, 171; Bayley v. Schofield, 1 Maule
If the company was not insolvent at the time of the execution of the trust deeds and accompanying assignments, within the meaning of the ninth section of the title in relation to moneyed corporations; or if it was insolvent, but the directors of the company had no knowledge or belief of such insolvency, and there were no circumstances which must or should have reasonably led them to believe that such insolvency existed; and if they did not at that time contemplate or anticipate the insolvency of the company,' these deeds and assignments are not void under the sections referred to, although the company may at the time have been in an embarrassed condition in consequence of its want of a cash capital to enable it to meet its maturing obligations.
Although a moneyed corporation is embarrassed in its financial condition; although it fails to discharge its liabilities as they mature, and even stops payment; yet if it is entirely solvent, and there is no probability of insolvency, and no contemplation of it, its directors, entertaining a bona fide expectation of extricating .it from its embarrassment, may sell, or assign, by way of hypothecation, a portion of its assets for the purpose of raising money to
Under the English bankrupt acts, if a debtor, after committing an act of bankruptcy, pays a demand to his creditor, on a surrender by the latter of a lien for such demand, such creditor cannot be divested of the money so paid to him; as he cannot be placed in a worse situation than he would have been if he had retained Ms security. ( Thompson v. Beatson, 1 Bing., 145; Mavor v. Croome, Id., 261.) The principles of these cases applies to the pledge of the mortgage bonds to the Palmers, as a substituted security in place of the state stocks surrendered by them to the company, upon the faith of such pledge.
Under the English bankrupt acts, contemplation of bankruptcy cannot be inferred from mere insolvency; there must be an actual contemplation of a failure in business, a
It is said a party must be supposed to intend the natural results of his condition and acts. But this proposition must be received with qualifications. The result cannot always be relied upon as evidence of the imputed intent. We must judge of the acts as they appeared to the debtor at the time they were transacted, not as they appear to the observer after the result is known. We all know that an embarrassed debtor often goes on after his condition is irretrievable, with confident hopes of relief. (Jones v. Howland, 8 Metc., 386, 387, per Hubbard, J.)
The next question to be examined is, whether the- trust deeds are void upon their face, because made in trust for the use of the company, and also whether they were made with intent to hinder, delay and defraud creditors.
If the trust deeds and accompanying assignments were made, and intended to operate only as mortgages of a part of the capital of the company, to secure future advances to the company by way of loan for lawful purposes, they do not come within the condemnation of the section in relation to transfers of personal property in trust, for the use of the vendor. (2 R. S., 135, § 1.) That section has no application to assignments or conveyances in trust given by way of mortgage, or hypothecation, as a security for a loan of money, or a preexisting debt. It applies to a conveyance or assignment made in trust, where the principal motive of the person making it is, to reserve or secure to himself the entire, or at least a part of, the beneficial use of the property. If the only object of the conveyance or assignment is to secure the payment of a loan of money, or of an existing debt, and the express reservation or resulting of the
Such an express reservation has not the effect of hindering or delaying creditors. The assignee acquires no legal or equitable title to the property, only a specific lien thereon. The residuary interest of the assignor may be immediately reached by his creditors by means of an execution, if the property assigned is a chattel, or by a complaint in the nature of a bill in equity, or by proceedings supplementary to an execution, if the property is a chose in action. The creditor without any delay, can attach the interest of the debtor in the property, and can enforce its sale, subject to the specific lien, to obtain satisfaction of his debt; and if the debtor has given the mortgage security in the form of a trust, the creditor will not be compelled to postpone proceedings against the property until the determination of such trust. These principles were advanced by Judge G-ardiner, and unanimously adopted by the Court of Appeals, in Leitch v. Hollister (4 Comst., 216), and they are conclusive upon the point I am now discussing, if the trust deeds and accompanying assignments are in legal effect mortgages to secure the payment of the mortgage bonds. In the case of Leitch v. Hollister, the debtor assigned to three creditors a chose in action, declaring therein that the amount realized by them should be applied in the payment of his indebtedness to each of them, in equal proportion to the amount of
It is apparent upon the face of the trust deeds and accompanying assignments, and from the evidence in the case, that the object of the officers of the company, in making the instruments, was to obtain a loan of money by creating a mortgage or pledge of the bonds and mortgages assigned, to secure the payment of the mortgage bonds to all persons who .should thereafter advance money on such bonds to the company on the credit of such securities ; and it is furthermore apparent that it was not one of the objects of these securities to create a trust for the use of the company. A trust as to the surplus, after the mortgage bonds should be satisfied, was not one of the objects had in view when the trust deeds were executed. The uses reserved in the deeds in favor of the company are precisely those which would have resulted in its favor by operation of law. The deeds declare that the trustees shall hold the bonds and mortgages assigned, in trust for the company, until default be made in payment of the mortgage bonds, and until that time to permit the company to receive the interest which shall accrue thereon; and upon such default, to make collections on the bonds and mortgages, and to pay the same to the London agents, to be applied by them in payment of the mortgage bonds, and after the bonds are paid to return the securities to the company. The uses thus reserved are the same, and no other, as would have resulted to the company by operation of law, in case no such reservation had been made. It is, therefore, evident that these trust deeds, being nothing but mortgages given to secure the payment of a loan of money, and for that object only, do not belong to that class of instruments which are condemned by the section of the Revised Statutes in relation to conveyances of personal property in trust for the use of the vendor. (2 R. 8., 135, § 1.)
If the trust deeds, and accompanying assignments, were executed for the sole purpose of borrowing money to enable the company to pay its existing debts, and to continue its business, and not with reference to. its insolvency and a liquidation (as I think the case shows); and if these instruments do not contain provisions which necessarily have the effect of hindering and delaying creditors, we are not authorized, in the absence of any proof of actual fraudulent intent, to infer from the evidence that they were made with intent to hinder, delay and defraud creditors.
I think the error of the counsel of the receiver, in this part of °the case, consists in assuming that the trust deeds had the effect of hindering the creditors in the pursuit of their ordinary legal remedies, in respect to the assigned
It is an established principle, that a mortgage, executed to secure the repayment of future advances, is valid in respects to all such advances as shall be made prior to the time when creditors shall obtain a lien on the property mortgaged. (16 John., 165; 2 John. Ch. R., 309; 5 id., 326 ; 6 id., 429.) The present case comes within the prinple of these decisions. Whenever the design of a debtor is to raise funds for the payment of debts and the continuance of his business, an assignment or transfer of a portion of his property as security for present or future advances is unobjectionable, although a trust as to the surplus results by operation of law, or by virtue of an express reservation in the deed. But if an assignment is made by a debtor when in failing circumstances, which looks to a final liquidation, and implies an inability to meet his engagements, it will be invalid, unless it is an unqualified devotion of the assets assigned to the payment of all his debts, without any reservation of an interest therein to the prejudice of his creditors. The trust deeds and assignments, in question in
The next question to be examined is the proposition of the receiver, that the trust deeds are void, because given to secure the payment of instruments called bonds, which were illegal contracts, the company having no power to give them, and the issuing of them being expressly pro hibiteu by statute; and that the coupons annexed to the bonds are open to the "same objections as exist against the bonds. Under this general proposition, it is insisted by the counsel for the receiver: First. That the company had no power to borrow money; Second. That it had no power to issue time paper, sealed or unsealed, for that purpose; Third. That the banks had no such power previous to the safety fund act of 1829, and the act of 14th May, 1840, prohibiting its exercise, the issuing of such paper being contrary to public policy; Fourth. That the bonds issued, after the act of 1840, were forbidden by that act; Fifth. That they were prohibited by the safety fund act; Sixth. And that they were issued in violation of the restraining law.
The statutory declaration, that a corporation has no corporate powers except those expressly given in its charter and such as shall be necessary to the exercise of the powers so given, is only declaratory of the common law rule on the subject. (1 R. S., 600, §3, 1st ed.; 15 John., 358, 383.) Every corporation has certain powers and capacities, which are, at common law, incidental to its existence. Among these are the powers to take and grant property, and to contract obligations. (2 Kent's Com., 278; 15 John., 383 4 Wheat., 658 ; 1 Kyd on Cor., 13, 69, 70.) These general powers may be curtailed by the act of incorporation, and restrained and qualified by the nature and object of the corporation. When the charter is silent as to the contracts which a corporation may make, it has, as incidental to its existence, the power of making all such contracts as are necessary and usual, in the course of the business it trans
The power of the North American Trust and Banking Company to borrow money may be maintained, as an incidental power necessary to carry on the.business of banking. This power has always been claimed and exercised by banks of discount in all commercial countries. In the original charter, granted in 1694, to the Bank of England (Act of 5 and 6 William and Mary, ch. 20), the power of that bank to borrow, as an incidental power, was conceded by imposing a restriction in respect to the amount to be borrowed. The same concession was made by the enactment of the sevéral acts of the British Parliament, restraining in favor of the Bank 'of England, all corporations, &c., from borrowing money on their notes, payable at a less time than six months. The Scotch banks exercise this power. It is one of the principal sources of their profits, to borrow, at a low'rate of interest, and lend at a higher. (3 Edin. Encyclo., tit. Bank, 220, 224; Cyclopaedia of Arts, &c., tit. Bank; 1 Chitty on Bills, 15, 16.) Beawes, in his Lex Mer catoria, 384, says: “ That the legitimate business of a bank of discount, deposit and circulation, consists in borrowing money upon their own credit; lending money on good securities ; buying and selling bullion ; discounting bills of exchange or other secure debts; and receiving and paying the money of other persons.” And at p. 398, he says: “ The Bank of England may borrow money on any contracts, and may give such security as shall be satisfactory to the lender.” This power was always exercised by the old incorporated banks of this state, and it has also been exercised by the banking associations since the passage of the act authorizing their formation. It has been exercised by these banks as a legitimate power of banking, and as the necessary and usual means to enable the banks to carry
The banking powers granted to the safety fund banks, and to banking associations, are substantially the same, and are specified with equal particularity and definiteness. (Laws of 1838, 246, 249, 250, §§ 3, 18, 24; Laws of 1832, 240, §§ 3, 4, 5, and pp. 43, 44, §§ 3, 4, 5, &c.) The only restrictive clause, in the charters granted prior to the safety fund act, was the same as the one contained in the banks incorporated under that act.
The restrictive clause in the charters granted previous to 1838, in relation to trading in goods and stocks, was unnecessary. The chartered banks would not have possessed
This power may be exercised under the general power tacitly annexed to every corporation, when created, to contract obligations as a necessary and directly appropriate means to enable it to conduct the business for which it was created. (2 Kent’s Com., 278, and note c; Ang. & Ames on Cor., 245.) Under this general power to contract obligations, a banking association may make all such contracts as are necessary and usual in the course of its business, as a means to enable it to carry on the business of banking.
This power to borrow money for the legitimate purposes of the company may also be maintained as a power conferred upon it by the express terms of the general banking law, as an incidental power necessary to carry on its business of banking. It may be supported as an incident to some, if not to all, of the specific powers expressly granted, viz., the power to discount notes, &c., to receive deposits, to buy and sell gold and silver bullion, and bills of exchange, to loan money, to purchase public stocks to deposit with the comp trailer, and such real estate as it was authorized to purchase The old chartered banks exercised the power to borrow, to enable them to discount notes. I can see that a prudent exercise of this power by a bank, in anticipation of receipts from the payment of its outstanding paper, for the purpose of accommodating its customers, may be' an appropriate means to enable it to exercise the power of discounting notes. So borrowing money to provide funds to. be placed temporarily in the hands of a foreign correspondent, in anticipation, of those to be. supplied in the regular course of business, may be so useful and appropriate as to be regarded as an incidental power necessary to the sale of bills of exchange. But whatever may be the better opinion in respect to the exercise
The exercise of the power to borrow money for the specific purpose above mentioned, comes within the definition given by Judge Ellsworth, of an incidental power, in the case of Hood v. New-York & N. H. R. R. Co. (22 Conn. 16), cited by the counsel of the receiver. He defines such a power to be one which “is directly and immediately appropriate to
I am aware that it is objected to the necessity of the exercise of this power to borrow, that a banking association may meet its liabilities by the re-discount of its discounted paper or the sale of its other assets. I apprehend that this is not a sound objection to the exercise of the power to borrow. It may not in all cases be possible for the association to obtain a re-discount of its paper, or to sell any portion of its assets in time to meet a pressing emergency; while it may be able, upon the credit of its corporate liability, in connection with an hypothecation of a portion of its assets, to obtain a loan. And, if it should be able to obtain a re-discount of its paper, it would probably be required, in accordance with the usage of banks to superadd its guaranty or endorsement.
If the object of denying to banking associations the power to borrow money, and the use of their credit, is to confine their operations to the use of their capital, in order to create a check against their improvidence, the absolute sale of 'securities which form their capital, accompanied by covenants of guaranty and indemnity, would have a like tendency, to defeat this object, as a loan secured by an hypothecation of such securities. In both cases an indebtedness would be created, although in one case it would be contingent, and in the other absolute. The same objection which is made to the exercise, by an association, of the power to borrow, may, for like reasons, be made against the power to alien. Neither of these powers are enumerated in the act to authorize the business of banking, and the one does not violate the principles of public policy any more than the other. Neither can exist except as incidental powers, or as general powers which the common law tacitly annexes to every corporation eo instanti it is created, unless expressly prohibited by law or its charter. (2 Kent's Com., 281; 3 Barb. Ch. R., 122; 3 Comst., 238; 3 Wend., 13.) lean clearly
A banking association may unquestionably buy gold and silver bullion, &c., on credit. The act expressly grants the general power to buy, without restricting the exercise of the power to either a purchase for- cash or on credit. It follows, necessarily, from this unrestricted grant, that the purchase may be made in either mode. Now, what is a purchase on credit but a buying of the article sold, and a borrowing of the price. It is in substance the same transaction, as if the purchaser had paid the price to the seller, and then had immediately received it back on a loan, The contract of borrowing, for all practical purposes, exists as much in the one case as in the other. Is not this, then, an emphatic recognition of the right of a banking association to exercise the power to borrow money, as an incidental power. The same remarks apply to the powers to buy bills of exchange, public stocks and real estate. Again, what is the power to receive deposits, but a power to borrow ? It is, in every sense of the term, a loan. The money deposited, if a general deposit, becomes the property of the deposit bank, and the latter becomes a debtor, and the depositor a creditor to the amount of the deposit. (2 Seld. 416, 417.) This express power to receive deposits is another recognition of the right to exercise the power to borrow.
The general understanding in respect to the construction of a statute, and the usage of all persors in a particular business in accordance with such understanding, is always regarded as of great weight in fixing the construction of such statute. “Contemporanea expositio est optima et fortisima in lege." (Broome's Legal Maxims, 532.) The general understanding of bankers and the usage of the banking associations have, ever since the passage of the general banking law, been in accordance with the right claimed by these associations
An express authority is not indispensable to confer upon a corporation the right tb borrQW money, to deal on credit, or to become a party to a promissory note or bill of exchange. It is generally sufficient, if such right be implied, as the usual and proper means to accomplish the purposes of the charter. (Ang. & Ames on Corp., 86, 234, 3d ed.; Grant on Corp., 276; 3 Sandf. Ch. R., 339, 347, 349; 1 id., 280 ; 3 id., 34; Chitty on Bills, 15; Story on Bills, § 74,15 John., 44, 52; 3 Bar. & Ald., 1, 7, 11; 2 Kent’s Com., 299.) Best, J., in Broughton v. Salford Water- Worlcs. (3 Bar. SfAld., 1, 11), says: “When a company like the Bank of England or East India Company are incorporated for the purposes of trade, it seems to result, from the very object of their being, that they should have power to accept bills or issue promissory notes.” It has been repeatedly decided in this state that a corporation, without any express power in its charter for that purpose, may, when not expressly prohibited by law, make a promissory note payable either at a future time or upon demand for a debt contracted in the course of its legitimate business; and that this power is incident to all corporations. (9 Paige, 476; 2 Hill, 267 ; 1 Cow., 513; 3 Wend., 94; 4 Hill, 265.)
The power of the North American Trust and Banking Company to borrow money may also be maintained upon judicial authority. There has not been a single decision of any court of this state, which has come to my knowledge, against the existence of this power, while several have been made in favor of it. Vice-Chancellor McCow decided, in Leavitt v. Yates (4 Edw. Ch. R., 165), that banking associations possessed the power to borrow, as incidental to the power of discounting notes, of buying bills of exchange, bullion and foreign coin, and also of buying state stock to be deposited with the comptroller. A like decision was made by Assistant Vice-Chancellor Sandford, in Boisgerard v.
The reasons above stated, in my judgment, clearly establish the proposition that the mortgage bond» in question in this suit are not invalid, upon the ground that they were given to the holder for money borrowed by the company.
It is also insisted, on the part of the receiver, that the company had no power, prior to the act of 1840, to issue time paper, upon the ground that the isusinj; of such paper was contrary to public policy. The case of Safford v. WyTcoff (4 Hill, 442), in the Court of Errorj, establishes a contrary doctrine. In that case, a negotiable draft, upon the cashier of the North American Trust and Banking Company, issued by a banking association in favor of a third party as payee, payable on time, and signed only by the cashier, but not countersigned by the comptroller, was decided to be a valid instrument, and binding on the association. Senators Hopkins and Bockee delivered the prevailing opinions, and it must be presumed,' especially under the decision in James v. Patten (2 Seld., 15,16,18,19), that the opinions expressed by them, in respect to the questions which arose in the cause, and in which they agreed, were adopted by a majority of the court. They held, that as the draft bore no resemblance. to a bank bill or circulating note, and was not calculated to form a part of the circulating medium, and as there was no evidence that it was put in circulation as money, it was not a violation of the restraining law; and that the association had a right to issue it as an incidental • power necessary to the carrying on of the business of banking,” and especially as necessary to the exercise of the expressly granted power to buy and sell bills of exchange; and that the draft having been issued before the act of 1840, its being payable on túne was no objection to its validity. This decision is a direct authority in. favor of the right of
If the views urged upon us by the counsel for the receiver, in respect to this question, had been entertained by the majority of the members of the Court of Errors, in Saffcml v. WycJcoffj who united in a reversal of the judgment of the Supreme Court, their decision in that case must necessarily have been the converse of the one actually made. For, if that majority believed that banking associations had no power, even prior to the act of 1840, to issue paper on time, they must necessarily have decided that the draft in question was void. Their decision in favor of the validity of such draft is, therefore, an express adjudication that banking associations, prior to the act of 1840, possessed the power of issuing time paper. This decision, being directly in point upon this question, must be regarded as conclusive, upon the principle of stare decisis.
But, irrespective of its being an authoritative adjudication, I think it can be sustained upon both principle and authority. Prior to any statutory prohibition against the issuing by banks of promissory notes or bills of exchange, payable on time, they exercised the power of issuing such paper, without its being questioned by either the civil authorities or judicial tribunals. Judge Hand says, in his opinion in the Indiana case, that he knew of no principle of the common law which required the bills or notes of banks to be made payable on demand. In the absence of any statutory prohibition, a chartered bank, under an express grant of the general power to issue notes and bills without any limitation or qualification, as to the mode or manner in which they are to be issued, may issue such paper either on demand or,, on time. The effect of time paper, upon the circulating medium and upon the banks, proving mischievous, a prohibition against issuing it was inserted in the safety fund act of 1829. This prohibition, however was applicable only to the banks subject to the provisions of that act. Banking
I think these bonds are not, by the law as established in this state, sealed obligations. The common law intended, by a seal, an impression upon wax, or wafer, or some other Similar tenacious or adhesive substance, .capable of b.eing impressed. (4 Kent's Com., 452; 5 John., 224.) It was expressly decided, in Coit v. Millikin (1 Denio, 376), and in Fanners' and Mechanics' Banlc v. Haight (3 Hill, 494), that an impression upon paper alone is not a seal, except where it has been made so by statute. (2 Hill, 227.) The provisions in the Revised Statutes (1 R. S., 404, § 74, 3d. ed.), and the act of April 7,1848 (Laws o/'1848, 305), in relation to seals, are legislative declarations that an impression upon paper alone is not a seal at common law. Independent of statutory enactments, the seals of private corporations and
The mortgage bonds were not issued in violation of the restraining law. They were neither issued for the purpose of being loaned, or of being put into circulation as money. (1 R. S., 712, § 6, 3d ed.) The evidence, and the instruments on their face, show that the company did not intend that they should perform the office of a circulating medium, and it is apparent that they were not capable of performing that office. (9 Paige, 470; 4 Hill, 450, 452, 463.) They are not made in the similitude of bank notes ; they are pay able in sterling money; and are in the form of bonds, and contain a provision making them convertible into stock; they were made to be negotiated in England, and are for the payment of large amounts, and at a distant day, and were intended to be payable in England; and the interest is payable there. These characteristics prevented the circulation of these bonds as money.
The mortgage bonds being valid, the coupons annexed to them must be valid also. The latter have no existence or vitality independent of the bonds; they together form but one agreement. The coupons are intended to be cut off when the interest is paid, and delivered to the obligor, to bo retained by him as receipts for the interest paid. They are attached to the bonds for the double purpose of being used as receipts for interest paid, and as evidence to the purchaser of the bonds, of the non-payment of the interest represented by such of the coupons as remain attached to the bonds. ( Clark v. City of Janesville, Dist. Court U. S. for
It is also insisted, on the part of the receiver, that the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds secured by the million trust negotiated in England are void for usury. The documentary and oral evidence shows that the contract for the sale of these bonds was made and the money advanced on them paid in England; that the semi-annual interest to accrue thereon was to be paid in London, and the principal ultimately to be repaid there. The purchasers, at the time of the purchase, resided and still reside in England. These facts make the contract an English contract; and the question of usuiy, therefore, is to be determined by the English law. It is a general rule that the law of the place, where contracts purely personal are made, must govern, as to their construction and validity, unless they are to be performed in another state or country, and were made in reference to the laws of such state or country, in which case their construction or validity depends upon the laws of the place of performance. (6 Paige, 630; Story on Confl. of Laws, § 242 ; 2 Kent's Com., 457, 7th ed., note a; Parsons on Cont., §§ 95, 96; 1 Cow., 108; 2 Burr., 1077; Story on Confl., §§ 653, 654; 13 Peters' U. S. R., 65; 4 Cow., 510, note ; 17 John., 518.) If no place of performance is expressly stated or can be implied from the terms of the contract, the law of the place where it was made will govern. (Story on Confl. of Laws, § 282.) It is a settled principle, where no place of payment is mentioned in the contract, that its legal construction is, that the money is to be paid to the creditor where he resides, or wherever he may be found. (6 Paige, 630; 10 Wheat., 367; 2 Parsons on Cont., 95, 99.) Where the contract for a loan -of moneys is made in one countiy and payable in another, the parties may stipulate for the payment of interest according to the laws of either countiy. (2 Parsons on Cont., 95, 96; 20 Martin's Law R., 1; 14 Verm., 33; 6
The fact that the mortgage bonds were secured by the assignment, to the trustees, of mortgages on lands in this state, will not, in my judgment, make the contract of loan in this case a New-York contract. (Story’s Confl. of Laws, § 287, a, 293; DeWolf v. Johnson, 10 Wheat., 367, 383; 13 Peters, 65, 78.) The case of Chapman v. Robinson (6 Paige, 630), which seems to lay down a different rule, is in many respects unlike the present case. In that case the contract was partly made in England and partly in this state, and the securities were actually executed in this state, and the money was payable generally. In this case, the contract was wholly made in England, the money was advanced in England and was to be repaid there, and the denomination of English money used in the contract stamps it as an English contract.
Although the contract for the sale of the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds is an English contract, it will be unnecessary for me, in consequence of the construction I havf given to the act of the 6th of April, 1850, to discuss the question whether the contract is usurious under the act of 12th Anne, ch. 16, or is taken,out of the operation of that act by the act of the 2d and 3d Victoria, ch. 37. The act of 1850 (Laws of 1850, 334, § 1) declares “ that no corporation shall hereafter interpose the defence of usury in any action.” The second section declares that the term corporation shall be construed to include all associations and joint-stock companies. The prohibition is, that no corporation shall, after the passage of the act, interpose the defence of usury in any action. This prohibition is not directed merely against pleading or proving the defence, but it is against interposing it; that is, either by plea or by proof, or by claiming the benefit of it at the trial or hearing. The statute was intended to embrace, in the prohibition, the setting up as a defence usurious agreements, made as well before as after the passage of the act. This intent is evident,
It is a settled principle that the repeal of a statute, imposing a penalty, instantly takes away the penalty, although a prosecution for it is pending; and if the repeal takes place after conviction, it arrests the judgment. (Butler v. Palmer, 1 Hill, 330; 11 Pick., 350.) No penalty can be enforced after the repeal of the law imposing it, unless saved by express words in the repealing act. (5-Cranch, 181, 283; 6 id., 329.) The repealing statute “ obliterates the statute repealed, as completely as if it had not been passed, and it must be considered as a law that never existed, except for the purpose of those actions which were commenced, prosecuted and concluded while it was an existing law.” (Per Lord Ch. J. Tindal, Key v. Goodwin, 4 Moore & Payne, 341, 351.) As soon as the statute imposing the penalty is repealed, the very foundation of the action to recover it is taken away, and the action must fall with the law. The act of 1850 is in substance a repeal of the statutes of usury, so far as relates to corporations. The language as well as
The next question to be considered is, whether the two hundred and seventy bonds delivered to the two Philadelphia banks, to secure certificates of deposit given upon the loan of $250,000, made by those banks to the company, or to secure the payment of such loan, are void, because delivered to secure a usurious loan, and because such certificates were prohibited by the act of 14th May, 1840. [The learned judge here states the facts substantially as stated on pp. 28— 32, ante, and then proceeds.] The provisions of the contract made it a Philadelphia contract, and the usury laws of that state must be applied to it. If, under the laws of that state, the contract was usurious, the two banks would nevertheless be entitled, under such laws, to recover the sum actually advanced, with six per cent interest, as the penalty in that state for usury is limited to the illegal excess of interest stipulated to be paid by the borrower. (Col. Act of Penn., 2 March, 1723 ; Laws of Penn., by Brown, ed. of 1803, 191, 192; 7 Paige, 636, 637.) I do not, however, think that the loan was usurious by the laws of either Pennsylvania or New-York. Where a bank discounts a note payable at its place of business, and at the request of the borrower, it advances him the proceeds at some distant place, it may deduct therefrom the difference in exchange between the two places. (10 Paige, 113; 2 Hill, 460 ; 13 Peters, 65, 76, 77; 9 Peters,. 378; 13 How. U. S. Pc, 152, 171, 172; 19
If the agreement for the loan had provided that the two hundred and seventy bonds should be delivered to the two Philadelphia banks, to be held by them as security for the payment of the loan, instead of being held as security for the payment of the twelve time certificates of deposit, no doubt could have been entertained in respect to the right of the two banks, under the contract of loan, to hold the bonds as valid securities, with all the rights of purchasers for a valuable consideration, secured by the first half million trust need, and accompanying assignments, unaffected by the act of May 14, 1840, inasmuch as these bonds had been issued and pledged to the Palmers, and, therefore, had a legal existence prior to the 3d of June, 1840. But as the agree ment declares that the company had directed their agents ¿o deliver the bonds to the two banks, “to be held as collateral security for the payment of the certificates,” the question arises whether the pledge of the bonds to the banks is not invalid, within the decision in Leavitt v. Palmer (3 Comst., 19). My first impressions were very decided, that the pledge to the banks could not be sustained, if we adhered to that decision. Upon subsequent reflection, however, I have come to the conclusion, although with some hesitancy, that the case of the Philadelphia banks may be distinguished from that of Leavitt v. Palmer. Leavitt v. Palmer carried the doctrine of the strict interpretation of written instruments in opposition to the manifest intent of the parties, as far as the principles of law and equity will justify. In that case, the North American Trust and Banking Company, being under a contingent liability to the Palmers for their acceptance of the Davis bills, on the 30th of November, 1840, made forty-eight negotiable promissory notes, payable on time, aid delivered them to the Palmers, on account of such
If, then, as is insisted by the receiver, the pledge of the two hundred and seventy bonds to the two Philadelphia banks is invalid, the receiver has no interest in these bonds, except to the extent of any contingent surplus which may remain, after satisfying the entire indebtedness of the Palmers, for which the unsold bonds, including the two hundred and seventy, were pledged to them. As the evidence shows there will be no such surplus, the receiver has no such interest in these bonds as authorizes him to question the title of the two banks to them. The Palmers, who alone, in the case of the invalidity of the pledge to the two banks, can assert a claim to the two hundred and seventy bonds, having omitted to assert any claim thereto, I can see no objection to these banks retaining the bonds as a security for their loan, in accordance with the original intent of all the parties. The agreement in relation to the loan, consists of several distinct provisions. The provision as to the loan is separate and distinct from that in respect to the certificates. The latter were not received in payment of the money lent, but merely as security for its repayment. The two provisions can be separated ; the one in relation to the certificates may be void for illegality, while the other, in relation to the loan, may be sustained as legal and valid. As, then, the contract of loan is valid, and as the bonds were delivered to the two bank by the Palmers, for the purpose of securing the repayment of the loan, and as this was the object of the company in directing their delivery, I am not able to see why we cannot give effect to the substance of the agreement between the two banks and the company, and to the intent of all the parties to the same; and why, notwithstanding the illegality »f the certificates, we cannot adjudge that the two banks
It was manifest, from the evidence, that the two Philadelphia banks made their loan upon the credit of the pledge of the two hundred and seventy bonds, as a security for its repayment, and that such was the agreement of both parties to the loan. This distinctly appears from two letters of Beers, one to the Palmers and the other to Murray, both of the date of the 1st of July, 1840, the day of the date of the written agreement for the loan. In Beers’ letter to Murray, he states that the company had made a loan of $250,000 from the Philadelphia banks, upon a pledge of the mortgage bonds; and in his letter to the Palmers, he says that the loan had been made upon a pledge of three hundred bonds, as collateral to the certificates of the company. The order of the company, of the 1st. of July, 1840, to the Palmers, to deliver to the agent of the two banks the two hundred, and seventy mortgage bonds, was a part of the original contract of the loan; but it contained no reference to the certificates, and was not so connected with them as to be tainted by their illegality. There is no evidence that the directors and officers of the two banks had any knowledge of the illegality of these certificates, and, as they were residents of another state, the presumption is that they had no such knowledge. They could not, therefore, have been guilty of any wilful cooperation with the company in the issuing of these certificates. Inasmuch, then, as the two banks were entirely free from guilt in this transaction with the company; and as the contract of loan, being separate and distinct from the agreement to deliver the illegal certificates to secure its payment, was legal and valid; and as the order upon the Palmers to deliver the bonds, and their delivery by them to the two banks, had no necessary connection with the certificates; and as the loan was made upon the credit of the bonds; and as the intention of all the parties Was that the mortgage bonds should be delivered to the two
But if I am wrong in my conclusion as to the validity of tire pledge of the two hundred and seventy bonds as a security for the loan of the two Philadelphia banks, these banks have, nevertheless, .or rather those who now own their claims have, upon the principle settled in the Indiana case, a valid and meritorious debt against the company, to the extent of the sum advanced to the latter, with interest at the rate of six per cent, and are entitled to have such debt allowed as a claim against the company, to be paid ratably with the other creditors out of its assets.
It is claimed, on the part of the receiver, that the two Philadelphia banks have no valid debt against the company, because the loan on which it is founded is usurious; and because it was made upon an illegal agreement that the company issue and deliver to them, as a security for the payment of the loan, time certificates of deposit, prohibited by the act of 1840. The answer to this proposition is: First. That the loan was not in fact usurious; and if usurious, that the company and its receiver are prohibited by statute from interposing the usury as a defence; and Second. That the illegality of the time certificates is created by a statutory prohibition, which is malum prohibitum merely, and by the
The decision in the Indiana cz.aj mo As with my unqualified approval. It stands upon ih/. b/rpregnable foundation of
It is also insisted by the receiver, that the Palmers have no valid debt against the company, because the debt claimed by them arises, in part, out of an illegal sale of South Carolina state stocks to the company, and out of payments made to take up Murray debentures, time certificates of deposit, and time bills of exchange, all which were illegal; and because they cooperated with the company in conducting all the illegal transactions connected with these securities. The evidence, I think, shows that the South Carolina state stocks, purchased by Murray for the company, and pledged to Sanderson & Co., for a loan of money made by them and Samuel Mills to the company, belonged to L. M. Simon, and were sold by the Palmers to the company, as his agents. The Palmers advanced the purchase money for these stocks, being ¿£34,800, on a draft of Murray on them, and charged it in their general account as of the date of 13th August, 1840. The proceeds of the loan obtained by Murray, on the pledge of these stocks, and of ¿£40,000 of Indiana stocks, being ¿£52,187, were paid by Murray to the Palmers, and credited by them to the company. The South Carolina bonds, after the purchase by Murray, and after the loan
I am inclined to believe that the condition of the Palmers, in respect to their relation to the alleged illegal purchase by the company of the South Carolina stocks, would have been substantially the same whether they sold the stocks as principals, or as agents of Simon. For if the sale was illegal, they, although making the sale as agents, would be parties to the illegality, in like manner as-if they had made the sale as principals. It is for this reason that if an agent is connected with an illegal transaction of his principal, and advances money for him in furtherance of such transaction, he cannot recover the money advanced from his principal. (Paley on Agency, 116, Dunlap’s ed., 102; Story on Agency, §§ 346, 347.)
The purchase of the South Carolina stocks by Murray, as agent of the company, for the purpose of pledging them for a loan of money, was, under the decision in Talmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328, 348), ultra vires, being unauthorized by the general banking law, and the act of the 14th of May, 1840, amendatory of the same. The purchase of state stocks for the purpose of selling at a profit, or as a means of- raising money, except when received as security for a loan, or a debt due to the association, or when taken in payment of such loan or debt (3 Seld., 343, 348), is not expressly prohibited; but it is insisted that, being neither a power expressly granted, nor incidental to the business of banking, or, in other words, not necessary to the accomplishment of any of the purposes of the creation of a banking association, its exercise is ultra vires, an excess of corporate authority, and is therefore impliedly prohibited. (30 Eng. L. & Eq
The decisions in The East Anglian Railway Co. v. Eastern Counties R. R. (7 Eng. L. & Eq. R., 508); McGregor v. Manager of Deal & Dover R. R. Co. (16 id., 180); The Mayor of Norfolk v. The Norfolk R. R. Co. (30 id., 120), do not conflict with these view's. In all these cases the action was founded upon and was in affirmance of the unauthorized contract. And in the last cited case, the rule that no action can be sustained upon the contract of a corporation, which it had no authority to make, is applied only to cases where the excess of authority of the corporation was known to both parties, or at least to the party suing upon the contract, at the time of the making of the same. (30 Eng. L. & Eq. R., 128, per Erle, J.; id., 143, 144, per Lord Campbell, C. J.; Royal British Bank v. Turquand, 5 Ellis & Black., 260.) In the case of The Royal British Bank v. Turquand, Lord Campbell says: “A mere excess of authority by the directors, we think, of itself would not amount to a defenceand he also says, if no illegality is shown, as against the party with whom the directors contract under seal of the company, excess of authority is a matter only between the directors and shareholders. I am aware that in the cases in 7 Eng. L. & Eq. R., 508, and in 16 id., 180, it was held that the acts incorporating the railway companies which were parties in those suits were public acts, and that parties dealing with
If the purchase of the stocks, for the purpose of pledging the same for a loan of money, is to be regarded as a purchase for an illegal purpose, questions might be raised, whether it was made a part of the contract of sale that the stocks should be so pledged, and whether the Palmers did anything in furtherance of such purpose. But the consideration of these questions; if they legitimately arise, is not important, as, if the charge of ¿£34,800, in the general account of the Palmers, for the advance for the company of the purchase money of these stocks, is rejected, an equivalent sum of the credit of ¿£52,187, the proceeds of the loan obtained on a pledge of these and of the Indiana stocks, must be stricken out of the same account; especially as the South Carolina stocks were subsequently sold, and the proceeds of such sale applied in liquidation of the loan. I may add that the evidence authorizes the inference that, at the time of the purchase of the South Carolina stocks (August 12, 1840), the Palmers had no knowledge of the passage of the act of 1840, limiting the deposit of state stocks with the comptroller to the stocks of this state (Laws of 1840, 306, § 1); and that they, at that time, had no knowledge that the company had no power to purchase state stocks for the purpose of selling for profit, or of pledging the same, as a means of raising money. The decision in Talmage y. Pell, establishing the non-exis
■Previous to the passage of the act of 1840, the company had an undoubted right to draw bills of exchange, either foreign or domestic, and payable either at sight or on time. This power is implied in the express power to buy and sell bills of exchange; it is at least incidental to the exercise of that power. This was decided in Safford v. Wyckoff (4 Hill, 462), and the existence of the power has, since the decision of that case, been expressly recognized by the Court of Appeals,in Leavitt v. De Laimy (4 Comst., 364). A bill of exchange may be drawn on funds in the hands of the drawee, or on the strength of the credit of the drawer, and it may be drawn on time in anticipation of funds at the place where the bill is payable. (3 Edw. Ch. R., 146; 2 Sandf Ch. R., 156 ; 15 John., 44.) The drawing, and buying and selling bills of exchange, is within the legitimate business of banking. It is one of the ordinary attributes of a bank of discount. (Beawes' Lex Mercaloria, 384, ed. of 1792.) The general power to draw, or buy and sell bills of exchange, implies the right to draw and buy and sell bills, payable either at sight or on time. The act of 1840 restricts the power to bills payable on demand, and the restraining act prohibits the issuing of bills for the purpose of loaning them and putting them in circulation 'as money, unless payable on demand, and countersigned by the comptroller. (Act of 1838, 246; 1 R. S., 712.)
The company, under the power to receive deposits, had the power to receive them under an agreement to repay them on time. This power is not prohibited by the general banking law. It does not violate any sound principle of banking, or any principle of public policy. It is a convenient . and useful power to the banks; it admonishes the managers when to provide means for repayment. It is a
The foreign bills of exchange, and foreign certificates of deposit, payable on time, issued prior to 1840 and taken up by the Palmers, were not, for the reasons before stated, violations of the restraining law. The moneys, therefore, advanced by the Palmers, at the request of the company, in paying or taking up these securities, constituted a valid debt against the company.
All the foreign time bills of exchange, except eight, were issued by the company prior to the 3d June, 1840. Seven of these were drawn upon the Palmers, by the company, on the 31st July, 1840, and one on the tenth day of August of the same year. These bills were drawn for the purpose of raising money to meet the liabilities of the company. The eight bills were paid by the Palmers at maturity. These bills of exchange, being payable on time, were prohibited by the act of 1840, and were therefore void. The officers of the company are presumed to have issued them with full knowledge that they were prohibited; but the Palmers, being residents of a foreign country, must be presumed, in absence of all evidence to the contrary, to have
The same remarks will apply to all the Murray debentures, issued after the 3d June, 1840, which were endorsed or guaranteed by the Palmers.
All the foreign certificates of deposit, taken up by the Palmers at the' request of the company, were issued prior to the 3d June, 1840.
The Davis bills of exchange were drawn prior to June, 1840, and the Palmers, under the letter of credit of the company, accepted them, or agreed to accept them, before notice that they were drawn to pay for the stock of the company purchased by Davis for its benefit.
If any of the bills of exchange or certificates of deposit paid by the Palmers on the request of the company were founded upon or arose out of illegal stock or other transactions, the claim to recover the moneys advanced is, nevertheless, legal and valid, because it is not founded upon such transactions, but arose out of subsequent and totally distinct contracts, and is supported altogether by new considerations. The test, whether a demand connected with an illegal transaction is capable of being enforced at law, is whether the plaintiff requires any aid from the illegal transaction in establishing his case. (Chit, on Con., 657, and cases cited in
Dissenting Opinion
The question is again raised in this case, whether associations, under the general banking law of 1838, are subject to the provisions of the act “ to prevent the insolvency of money corporations.” (1 R. S., 589.) This point has been directly passed up by this court, in the cases of Gillett v. Moody (3 Comst., 479); Talmage v. Pell (3 Seld., 328); and Gillett v. Phillips (3 Kern., 114).
It is indispensable to the due administration of justice, especially by a court of last resort, that a point once deliberately examined and decided, be considered as settled, and closed to farther argument. The counsel for the respondents suggest, as reasons for considering this as an open question, that in the cases of Gillett v. Moody, and Gillett v. Phillips, all serious argument of this point was by collusion intentionally omittedand that, in Talmage v. Pell, Judge Gardiner, without whose concurrence the resolution on this subject could not have been adopted, appears, from his own admission, not to have examined this question.
These reasons are, I think, without weight. The first is wholly unsustained by evidence, and the last derives no support from the case of Talmage v. Pell, as reported. Although Judge Gardiner says, at the close of his opinion, that, independently of the questions raised under the act to prevent the insolvency of moneyed corporations, the decree of the Supreme Court should be reversed, he had, nevertheless, previously come to the conclusion that banking companies, formed under the law of 1838, were moneyed corporations, within the provisions of that act. The decision was evidently put in the explicit and imposing form of a resolution, for the purpose of settling definitely this vexed question ; and it is not to be supposed that Judge Gardiner united with his associates in such a resolution, without a due consideration of the point.
Were the trust deeds in question in this case executed in accordance with this provision ? The only previous resolution of the board of directors, authorizing the execution of any such deed, Was that of January 6, 1840, which autho rized an assignment of bonds and mortgages', in trust, to Joseph D. Beers, Daniel E. Tylee and John L. Graham. This resolution is relied upon as an authority for the assignment made to Blatchford, Curtis and Graham. Without looking farther for discrepancies between the trust created and that authorized by this resolution, I have no hesitation in saying that a resolution, authorizing a conveyance in trust to three individuals by name, could not, by possibility, be construed to authorize a conveyance to one of the three, together with two others not named. Even if the trust was merely passive and nominal, it could hardly be said that a trustee could be substituted for the one selected. But here the trastees have important and responsible duties to perform. The large fund conveyed to them is placed in a great degree .under their control. They are authorized to borrow money upon it, as well as to collect and reinvest the sums due. If Blatchford and Curtis could be substituted for Beers and Tylee, so might two individuals not possessing a tithe of their acknowledged capacity and responsibility. In my judgment, no such substitution could be made.
It is, I think, equally clear that no subsequent ratification of the conveyance, by resolution or otherwise, could uphold the trust. The word previous, in the statute referred to, is a significant word. It is there for some purpose. To suppose that a subsequent resolution will legalize a trust previously made, is to leave this word wholly without force or meaning. This would not only conflict with all general rules for interpreting statutes, but would do violence to the plain meaning of the legislature in this particular instance.
It is unnecessary to cite authorities to show that every statutory power, especially when it relates to the transfer of property, must be strictly pursued, and that every regulation in regard to it must be rigidly observed, even where no reason can be seen' for the requirement. The position, that the committee of investments and finance could authorize the trust, is clearly untenable. It will not be doubted that the directors could do it,'because they were the managers of the corporation, and come within the very terms of the statute. Did the power then rest in two independent bodies? If so, suppose their action should conflict, which would prevail ? It was not a power which could be delegated, but one which must rest where the statute placed it. The committee of investments and finance might have been clothed with the power by making them the general managers of the corporation. But it is not pretended that this was done.
The trust, therefore, was clearly defective for want of a previous resolution; and the question arises, whether the house of Palmer, Dent & Co., and the other holders of paper intended to be secured by the trust deeds, are to be regarded as purchasers “ for a valuable .consideration without notice,” within the last clause of the section we are considering. It is not claimed, on the part of the receiver, that the Palmers had themselves any actual knowledge of the want of a previous resolution authorizing the trust, but it is insisted that they are not entitled to the protection of the statute as Iona fide purchasers, for the reasons: First. That neither they nor the trustees have put themselves upon that ground in their answers ; Second. That the saving clause in question does not apply to those who take directly from the corporation, but only to subsequent purchasers: Third. That the
The first of these points appears to be well taken. The answers allege, in substance, that the requirements of the statute were complied with; and the rule is clear that the proofs must correspond with the allegations. This is not a case, as claimed by the respondents’ counsel, where the receiver was bound to negative the fact that the respondents were bona fide purchasers. The clause in question is not incorporated into and made a part of the main provision, but is, in substance, a proviso. The rule relied upon, however, by the receiver’s counsel, is purely technical, and ought not, in a case like the present, to be suffered, if it can be avoided, to prevent the attainment of substantial justice. As no possible wrong could be done by allowing an amendment of the pleadings in this respect, this might, perhaps, be permitted. But it will, in my judgment, be found unnecessary to determine this question.
The position that the last clause of section eight applies only to such purchasers as do not take directly from the corporation, although supported by reasoning of some force, is nevertheless inconsistent with the structure and language of the section. It provides, first, that “ no conveyance, assignment or transfer, &c., shall be made,” and then, that this provision shall not “be construed to render void any conveyance, assignment or transfer in the hands of a purchaser for a valuable consideration,” &c. Now, if the last clause is intended to refer to the same conveyance, assignment and transfer as the first, and if by conveyance, assignment, &c., it means the instrument as well as the title, as I think it must, then the interpretation of the section is clear; because the conveyance, assignment or transfer which it forbids, would »f course be “in the hands” of the first purchaser. All
If, however, any doubt could-exist as to the construction of section eight, taken by itself, it would be entirely removed by the next section, which commences with the words, “No such conveyances,” Sc. If the words, “conveyances, assignment or transfer,” in the last clause of section eight, refer only to conveyances, not from the corporation itself, but from its assignees, then section nine, upon every rule of construction, must refer to the same, thus rendering the provision absurd. This shows, what indeed is sufficiently clear without it, that the conveyances mentioned in the prohibitory and saving clauses of section eight, and in the commencement of section nine, are all the same; and consequently that the purchasers intended to be protected by such saving clause, are, or at least may be, those holding conveyances directly from the corporation. The provision was evidently aimed at fraudulent combinations between the officers of a corporation and those taking conveyances from them. (3 R. S., 530, 2d ed., revisor's note.)
The next answer given to the claim of the respondents to be considered as bona fide purchaser®, is, that the trustees paid no consideration for the assignment to them. This position assumes that the court, in giving effect to the statute., can only regard the legal and not the equitable title. 1 cannot adopt this conclusion. The title of the trustees is in a great degree merely formal. The real purchasers are the cestuis que trust. Although not, perhaps, within the strict letter of the exception, they are clearly within its equity. The exception itself recognizes and is in fact based upon the idea of establishing an equitable in opposition to & legal title, and it would be singular if, in construing such a provision, equitable rights were not to be regarded.
I shall pass over the question raised under section nine of the same act, which prohibits, under certain circumstances, the giving of preferences; and the question also, whether the trusts are void, because made to hinder, delay or defraud creditors; as well as the various points made upon the internal structure of the- trust deeds, because the view I have taken of other parts of the case renders it unnecessary to consider them.
In regard to the usury alleged the receiver cannot, I think, avail himself of it as a defence. The act of 1850, provides
It may be said that the statute only prevents corporations from availing themselves of usury as a defence, but does not prevent them from commencing a suit to obtain affirmative relief against a usurious contract. . It will, however, be
We come then to the questions: First. Whether, in issuing the paper under which the respondents claim, viz., the bills of exchange, the so-called mortgage bonds, the debentures, and the certificates of deposit, or either of them, the banking company exceeded its powers ? And second. If it did, what are the consequences ? The receiver’s counsel takes the broad ground, that banking corporations cannot borrow money, or, at least, that they cannot borrow to supply the place of capital. They contend that it is the business of banks to lend money, not to borrow; that borrowing does not come within the scope of legitimate banking, and is in its nature a power which corporations created for banking purposes cannot properly exercise. This position is not supported by any direct authority; and a careful consideration of the nature of banking, together with an examination of its history, has satisfied me that it cannot be sustained. It is not in harmony with the present practice or the past-history of banks. Banking for profit is based primarily upon the idea of borrowing, without interest, the various sums which the individuals of a commercial community must necessarily keep on hand unemployed, to meet any sudden emergency, and reloaning the money or the greater part of it upon interest. It may be said that banks may borrow, that is, receive deposits without interest, but canuot borrow upon interest. This, too, is untenable. One of
Corporations are purely artificial beings. They have no existence independent of the act which creates them, and can therefore have no powers except such as that act confers. An enabling statute, enacted in reference to a natural person,.
It is plain, therefore, that our statute (1 It. S., 600, § 3), which forbids the exercise, by corporations, of any powers except such as are expressly given by their charters, or such as shall be necessary to the exercise of those so given, is simply declaratory of a preexisting rule of the common law. The rule being a necessary deduction from the very nature of a corporation as an artificial being, it follows that it is applicable to every corporation, whether created by special charter or by general law, whatever may be the objects or purposes for which it exists. It having been settled that associations, under the law of 1838, are strictly corporations, their powers are, of course, to be interpreted according to this general rule, unless it clearly appears that the legislature intended to exempt them from its operation. It cannot be assumed, as evidence of such an intention, that the legislature did not mean that these associations should be corporations at all. It would be a judicial solecism to hold, at the same time, that they are corporations, and that the legislature did not intend to make them so. Neither can it be assumed that the legislature was ignorant of the rule in question, or the statutory provision which declares it. In full view, then, of this statute (1 R. S., 600, §3), it provided for the creation of this important class of corporations, without an intimation that they were to be exempted from the operation of the rule. Is not the inferan e, that they are not exempted, irresistible ?
But the general banking law itself bears upon.its face strong evidence that it was framed with an intelligent refer
It is clear, therefore, that this corporation, like all others, must find its authority for every act in the law under which it was organized. If-not given in express terms, or necessary to the exercise of some power thus given, it does not exist. Can we find, then, in the general banking law, authority for issuing the various kinds of paper put forth by this company ? I will consider the different kinds separately.
First, as to bills of exchange. The law authorizes, in express terms, banks organized under it to buy and sell “gold and
On this subject I concur in the reasoning of Senator Bockee, in Safford v. Wyckoff (4 Hill, 442). He says: “Buying and selling bills of exchange is an expressly granted power. It seems to me that the power of drawing bills is fairly included in, or at any rate is incidental to, the power of buying and selling. In the business of exchange, mutuality is necessity. If a banking association buy bills of exchange, and its funds accumulate at any point, why may it not draw, as well as sell, bills of exchange ?” The accumulation of funds at remote noints, of which the senator here speaks, must inevitably attend the business of a bank authorized to deal in exchange, and it would seem difficult to deny the power to draw for such funds. A comparison of the reasoning of Senator Bockee with .that of Senator Hopkins, in the case of Safford v. Wyckoff, has satisfied me that that case "must have been decided upon the ground assumed by the former, viz;, that banks, under the general banking law have power to draw bills of. exchange, as incidental to tin power to buy and sell them. If, then, these banks may draw for their funds abroad, they must be permitted to draw in anticipation of such funds; otherwise^, much time, and of course interest, would be lost. The question is not presented, whether they would have the power to draw mere accom modation bills; as all the bills in this case appear to have
I will next consider the so-called mortgage bonds. These were issued for the sole purpose of borrowing money, to be used as capital in carrying on the business of banking. Now, although, as has been shown, the use of borrowed capital is within the scope of legitimate and well regulated banking, it by no means follows that corporations created for banking purposes- have a general power to borrow. That depends upon their charters and not upon the laws or rules of banking. No corporation in this state possesses the power to borrow money, unless that power has been conferred upon it by the legislature, either expressly or as incidental to some express power. It not being among the general powers enumerated in section one of the act concerning corporations, its exercise, unless authorized either specifically of by plain' implication, is expressly prohibited by section three of that act. The doctrine advanced by Assistant Vice-Chancellor Sandfobd, in the case of Barry v. Merchants' Exchange Co. (1 Sandf. S. C. R., 280), that any corporation, as such, has the capacity to take and grant property and to contract obligations, in the same manner as an individual, and that, unless specially restrained, it may borrow money for the purpose of accomplishing any object authorized by its charter, cannot be sustained.
The theory upon which this doctrine is based, viz., that corporations possess the same powers- as individuals, except so far as they are specifically restrained, is in direct conflict' with the statute, as well as with the common law rule, of which the statute is merely declaratory. We must look, then, to the general banking law, to ascertain whether, and
The distinction, which thus plainly exists between a certificate of deposit and a promissory note, demonstrates the existence of a similar distinction between receiving a deposit, and other methods of borrowing. If the appropriate written evidences of two transactions materially differ, there must be a corresponding difference between the transactions themselves. Let us recur for a moment to the origin of banks of deposit. They were places where the various individuals of a commercial community could deposit for safe keeping those small sums which they must necessarily keep on hand to meet any sudden or unexpected demand. As neither all, or any considerable number of the depositors, were likely to call for their deposits at the same time, the bank could safely use a large portion of the money. But as the depositors could not. in general, foretell when their respective shares would be wanted, it was indispensable that they be at liberty to call for the money at any time. It will be seen, therefore, that it was essential to the very nature of a bank deposit
It may be said that the specification of powers contained in section eighteen, was inserted for the purpose of exempting these associations from the provisions of the restraining act. This, however, is insufficient to account for that specification. The provisions giving power to buy and sell foreign coins and bills of exchange, as well as that of loaning money on real and personal security, could not have been inserted for that object, as they were wholly unnecessaiy for any such purpose. It would be disrespectful to the legislature, to suppose that it adopted a mere stereotyped phraseology, without motive or object. The rules for con-stfuing statutes require that significance should be given to every sentence and word. Besides, we have no right' to assume that the legislature was ignorant of the rule embodied in the very common maxim, expressio unius exclusio est alterius ; and the section in question, unless enacted in-the most entire unconsciousness of that rule and maxim, must have been intended to exclude all other modes of banking, except those' enumerated. Again, a power cannot be said to be conferred as incidental, when the power, of which it is claimed to be an incident, is itself withheld. Does section eighteen authorize these associations to carry on the business of banking at large, or only in the way there specified? Plainly, the
The express power to which borrowing may be most appropriately considered as incidental, is that given by section eighteen, to buy and sell “ gold and silver bullion, foreign coins and bills of exchange.” It must be conceded that if the doctrine advanced by the assistant vice-chancellor, in Barry v. Merchants' Exchange Co. (1 Sandf. Ch. R., 280), and upon which not only that case, but the case of King v. The Same (2 id., 692), appears to have been decided, is sound, the power to purchase would include the power to borrow. In the first of these cases, he says: “ A corporation, in order to obtain its legitimate objects, may deal precisely- as an individual may who seeks to accomplish the same ends. If chartered for the purpose of building a bridge, it may contract a debt for the labor, the materials, or the land upon which the bridge is abutted. If more advantageous, it may borrow money to purchase such land or materials, or to pay for such labor.” This doctrine entirely overlooks that manifest distinction between corporations and natural persons, upon which so many of the cases proceed. It is also in conflict with the statute. (1 R. S., 600, §3.) It assumes that corporations must be specially restrained, to prevent their exerting the same power as Individuals. This is the direct opposite of the true doctrine. It is true that a corporation, chartered to build a bridge, a hospital, or for any other specific object, may accomplish such object by means of its credit, and may give its bond or
This point does not appear to have received any consideration in this court, in the case of King v. The Merchants’ Exchange Co. (1 Seld., 547). rIt is not alluded to in the opinion delivered, and was probably not seriously argued. I cannot consider that case as settling the question. The reasoning here adopted is not only in entire accordance with the general principles applicable to corporations, but with the decided cases in this state, with the exception of those, referred to above, against the Merchants’ Exchange Company.
In Mott v. Hicks (1 Cow., 513), it was held that the Woodstock Glass Company, incorporated for the purpose of manufacturing glass, was liable on a promissory note, given by the president of the company, for wood furnished to canyon its legitimate business. No inference can be drawn, from this case, that the note would have been valid if given for money borrowed to buy the wood.
In regard to the case of Safford v. Wyckoff (1 Hill, 11); S. C. (4 id., 442), as already remarked, the Court of Errors, in reversing the judgment of the Supreme Court must have proceeded upon the ground assumed by Senator Bockee, that the power to draw bills was a necessary incident of the power to buy and sell them, and not upon that taken by Senator Hopkins, that every power which might be considered as incidental to the general principles of banking was conferred by the act. There is nothing, therefore, in this reversal which impairs in the slightest degree the force of what is said by Judge Cowen in the Supreme Court, and by Chancellor Walworth in the Court of Errors, so far as in applies to promissory notes and evidences of debt, other than bills of exchange. These cases, with others which might have been cited, show that any corporation authorized to carry on a particular business, to perform a specific work or to purchase a particular kind of property, may do either of these things upon a credit, and may give its obligations for the debts thus contracted, provided all its contracts are made in the direct furtherance of the authorized object. If, however, it goes one step beyond this in issuing evidences of debt
While, therefore, banks organized under the general' banking law may use their credit in the direct purchase of real estate within the prescribed limits, as well as of gold and silver bullion, foreign coins and bills of exchange, and probably also of state stocks to be deposited with the comptroller, and may give their obligations in appropriate forms for the debts thus incurred, they cannot borrow money for any of these objects, except in the modes specially authorized by-the act. I admit the difficulty of distinguishing between different modes of borrowing money, the most substantial part of the contract being in all cases the same. But the necessity of making- this distinction results from the nature of the limitations which law and reason impose upon the exercise of corporate power. Corporations are not only limited to the general objects for which they are created, but are required to accomplish-those objects in the manner specified.
In Banlc of the U. S. v. Dandridge (12 Wheat., 64), Mr. J. Story says: Corporations created by statute must depend both for their powers and the mode of exercising them upon the true construction of the statute itself.” • Chief Justice Marshall, also, in the case of Head v. The Providence Ins. Co., before referred to, speaking of the powers of the corporation, says: “ It may correctly be said to be precisely what the incorporating act has made it: to derive all its powers from that act, and to be capable of exerting its faculties only in the manner which that act authorizes.” There are niany other cases to the same effect.
When, therefore, a corporation is expressly enabled by statute tomorrow .in one mode, it is not authorized to borrow
It follows, from these views, that the acts of the North American Trust and Banking Company, in issuing the so-called mortgage bonds, avowedly for the mere purpose of borrowing money to carry on its business, were ultra vire$. This conclusion renders it unnecessary to consider whether these obligations are specialties or mere promissory notes; and we are brought directly to the question whether, having been issued without authority and in violation of law, they can be enforced against the corporation. Upon this point, we have listened to a most elaborate, learned and able argument from one of the respondents’ counsel, against the soundness of the decision of this court in the case of Leavitt v. Paimei
That case was elaborately argued, by counsel of great eminence, and the judgment of the court was unanimous. It- would, as a general rule, be inexpedient for this court to reconsider a point which it had thus deliberately decided; but the great importance of the question, the earnestness with which its consideration was pressed by the learned counsel, and the fact that the eminent judge by whom th i opinion of the court was delivered did not enter at large int -> the discussion of this point, have induced me to look wit.ii some care into the grounds of that decision. This examination has satisfied me that the decision, in the particular in which it is now assailed, rests upon a basis of authority which cannot be shaken, even if we consider it as going the full length of holding that corporations are not bound by contracts which are ultra vires, although not expressly prohibited ; which, perhaps, it does not do. The point has been repeatedly decided both in England and this country, and always in accordance with the decision in Leavitt v. Palmer.
The doctrine did not originate, in England, with the case of Last Anglian Railway v. Eastern Counties Railway Co. (7 L. & Eq. R., 505); nor, in this countiy, with the bank cases of this state or of the State of Michigan. The precise question arose in England in 1809, in the case of Lees v. The Proprietors, Spc. (11 East., 645). The action was for an alleged breach of covenant. To a plea that the corporation had not power to enter into the contract, the plaintiff demurred. The court of King’s Bench overruled the demurrer, upon the broad ground that corporations are not bound by contracts which exceed the powers conferred upon them by their charters;
The decision in East Anglian Railway Co. v. Eastern Counties Railway Co. (7 L. & Eq. R., 505), which was directly upon the point, has not only never been overruled in England, but stands confirmed by the dicta of several of the judges in subsequent cases. (Gage v. The New Market Railway Co. 14 L. & Eq. R., 57; McGregor v. The Oficial Manager, &c., 16 id., 180.) When to these cases, and those previously referred to, we add the cases in the Supreme Court
It is impossible, then, to support the mortgage bonds as valid securities. Although I entertain veiy little doubt that all the present holders of the bonds, including the Messrs. Palmers, were, in point of fact, unconscious that any law was violated by issuing them, and wholly innocent of any actual intention to aid in such violation, yet the settled rules of law must be upheld. According to these rules, there dan be no Iona fide holders of the bonds, inasmuch as the trust deeds to which they especially refer, and of the terms of which every purchaser must therefore be presumed to have had knowledge, showed upon their face that the bonds were made for the purpose of being “ sold” in market; in other words, for the purpose of borrowing money upon them. The purchasers are presumed also to have known the extent of the powers of the corporation, so far as those powers depended on the law under which it was organized. Knowing, as they must, that a positive act of the legislature was
It will facilitate our inquiries as to other parts of the case, to consider here the question, whether the purchasers of the bonds (I use the word purchasers, for convenience merely) have any remedy for the sums actually advanced by them in their purchase, upon the supposition that the only objection to the bonds is that the bank exceeded its powers in issuing them. It does not follow, because the special contract cannot be enforced, that the purchasers have no. equitable claim against the corporation. The latter has received the money and appropriated it to its own use.- It has given no consideration whatever in return; and upon the plainest principles of justice, therefore, it is bound to refund. Under such circumstances, the law, in all ordinary cases, implies a promise to repay. It would clearly do so in this case, where the equity is so strong and undeniable, unless there is some controlling reason to the contrary. The reason given by the counsel for the receiver is, that the contract, of which the bonds are the evidence, is illegal, and that the law* will not aid either party to such a contract.
Now there are some distinctions in regard to illegal contracts, which courts must observe if they would not be led
It was assumed upon the argument, that if the word illegal could be shown to be applicable to the contracts of the bank, then all claim against its effects, was at an end; thus mating this important question to turn, not upon the nature of the transaction or the culpability of the parties, not upon the questions .of public policy which the case involves, but upon a mere question of lexicography. I deny that one inflexible and unvarying rule is to be applied to all contracts which may be .said to be illegal, without regard to their nature or the relative guilt of the parties. It is substantially true, in respect to actions brought directly upon and alleging the validity of the illegal contracts. But in regard to the adjustment of the rights and equities of the parties between themselves, where the illegal contract, not being malum in se, has been executed, and money has been paid or property received under it, the rule has always varied according to the nature of the case, and the principles of justice and policy which it involves. The following passages from Story on Con., are in accordance with this position. In section four hundred and eighty-nine, he says : “ But although a contract is equally void, whether it be malum, in se or merely malum prohibitum, yet the position of the parties, as to their
That the question whether relief shall be granted to one party to an illegal contract, against another, when the contract has been executed, is not governed by one uniform, unbending rule, especially in equity, is shown by a great number of cases. See note four to the case of Hatch v. Hatch (9 Ves., 292), in which the editor says: “Where a transaction contravening public policy has taken place, relief may be given at the suit of a particeps criminisciting Lord St. John v. Lady St. John (11 Ves., 535); Jackson v. Mitchell (13 Ves., 587); Whittingham v. Burgoyne (3 Anst., 904); Gilbert v. Chudleigh, before Lord Hardwicke. In the last of these cases, Lord Hardwicke said: “It was urged for the defendant that this is a bill brought by one of the parties to this corrupt contract against a representative of the other, who is a stranger to it; and that, although an executor, might have claim for relief, for the sake of providing assets, yet the court will show no favor to either of the parties themselves. But the truth is, that in these cases of the violation of public policy, it is indifferent who stands before the court, if the intention of the contract be evident; because the court does not regard the state and condition of the parties so much as the nature of the contract and the public good.” There are many other cases to the same effect, but these are sufficient to show that, where the illegality of a contract consists, not in its being either malum in se or malum prohibitum,, but in its contravening public policy, relief may
If, that a contract made by a corporation is ultra vires, proves it to be illegal, the illegality belongs clearly to the class referred to in these cases, and not to the class styled mala prohibita. The statute (1 R. S., 600, §3), is simply declaratory of a preexisting rule. It prohibits no particular acts, or even class of acts, and adds nothing .indeed to the force of the common law. It is clear that contracts, which are ultra vires, are held void at the instance of the corporations making them, simply because public policy requires the enforcement of the rule which limits corporate bodies to the exercise of their legitimate powers. To hold then-express contracts void, if unauthorized, will no doubt.promote the observance of this limitation. It operates as a salutary restraint upon both parties, by depriving each of the power of enforcing an advantageous bargain. But, to go farther, and hold that corporations, when called upon not to perform that which formed the inducement to the contract with the other party, but simply to return what they have received without consideration, may set up their own violation of law as a defence, would be to offer a direct premium for the fraudulent abuse of their powers. I cannot doubt that a sound public policy will be promoted by restoring the parties, in all such cases, to their original position. It leaves no inducement for either party to contravene the law. The corporation is compelled to return just what it has received; the other party gets no more than he has parted with. It is believed that not a solitary case can be found which stands opposed to this just and salutary rule.
The most plausible branch of the argument against this doctrine is, not that which rests upon the law of illegal contracts, but that which is drawn from the law of principal and agent. It is said that the directors are merely the agents of the stockholders, and that all parties dealing with such agents are presumed to have knowledge of the extent of
It is indispensable, if we would avoid confusion on this subject, to distinguish between cases like the present and that class of English cases where the question of excess of authority by the directors of a company depends, not upon the extent of the corporate powers conferred by a public statute, but upon a deed of settlement, inter partes. These deeds of settlement not only specify the general purposes and objects of the company, but prescribe and limit the powers of the directors, as between them and the shareholders; and as provision is made by law for the registry of such deeds, all parties dealing with the company are presumed to know the extent of the authority conferred by the shareholders upon the directors. In actions against such companies, therefore, ultra vires frequently means no more than that the directors have exceeded the powers conferred upon them, by the deed of settlement, as the agents of the
For instance, the language of Lord Campbell,- in the case of Royal British Bank v. Turquand (5 Ellis Sf Black., 248), cannot be reconciled with his opinions in several other cases, except by observing this distinction. He there says: “ A mere excess of authority by the directors, we think, of itself, would not amount to a defence.” This might seem, at first, to be in direct conflict with the doctrine, that a corporation may set up in its defence that the contract sued upon is ultra vires. But this is explained by referring to the plea, which sets out the deed of settlement, and avers that the directors had exceeded the powers conferred upon them by this deed. Lord Campbell, in speaking of the plea, says : “ It alleges that, as between the directors and the share
In The Mayor of Norwich v. The Norfolk Railway Co. (30 L. & Eq. R., 120), Erle, J., says-: “ These suits in equity, between different members of the company, have no analogy to actions at law by third persons against the corporations, either in respect of the parties to the suit or the subject in litigation. As to the parties, in actions against, corporations the members thereof, in their individual capacity, are strangers-to the suit, and the rights of persons who contract with „ .corporations are unaffected by the rights of members inter se.” So in Edwards v. The Grand Junction Railway Co. (1 Myl. & Craig, 650),' it was argued that to enforce the plaintiff’s claim would be “ unjust towards the shareholderbut to this the chancellor replied, that the court could “ not recognize any party interested in the corporation, but must look to the rights and liabilities of the corporation itself.” This language of the lord chancellor is quoted with approbation by Lord St. Leonards, in the case of the Eastern Counties Railway Co. v. Hawkes (35 L. & Eq. R., 8.) There are other authorities to the same effect, but it is unnecessary to refer to them. It is clearly on the grounds of public policy that corporations are permitted to allege 'their own
In holding, however, that corporations are bound, upon a contract which the law will imply, to refund money obtained by means of an agreement which it had no right to make, it is proper to say that the receipt of the money, and its appropriation to the use of the corporation, must be established by proof, independently of the illegal contract itself. That contract, being void, cannot be resorted to for any purpose. In this case, however, the proof is abundant.
It is said, that, as all the transactions in which the directors of the bank were engaged were ultra vires, none of the moneys received and expended in the course of those transactions can properly be said to have been paid to and used for the. benefit of the corporation. This is a criticism which I think the case will not warrant. In the first place, the bills of exchange were valid, and consequently all moneys applied •to their payment, or in discharge of the debt created by their payment, were used in the strictest sense for the benefit of the company. So of moneys applied to the payment of certificates, post notes or debentures, in the hands of Iona fide holders without notice. This would undoubtedly cover a large proportion of the claims. But aside from this, I think all these operations having been carried on in the name of the bank, and avowedly for its benefit, as a part of its regular business, are to be considered, as between the bank and the persons with whom it dealt, at least after being carried into effect, as corporate acts; although so long as they remained executory, the courts, as a matter of policy, might have refused to recognize them as valid.
There can be no doubt that everything acquired by the directors in the course of these transactions, would be
It follows, from the principles which have been adopted, that all who have advanced money to the Company upon the mortgage bonds, have, so far as the defence rests upon the ground that the acts of the bank in issuing them were ultra vires, valid claims against the assets of the bank to the extent of the money advanced, with interest. To this the Palmers are no exception, even admitting their complicity in the transaction to be fully established; because, as we have already seen, where contracts are held void, as is the case with corporate contracts which are ultra vires, on grounds of public policy, relief will be given to the parties, as against each other, without regard to the question whether they are in pari delicto.
In Lord St. John v. Lady St. John (11 Ves., 526), Lord Eldon says: “ It is said, supposing the instrument void by the policy of the law, it may be of great importance at the hearing to see what has been the conduct of the plaintiff, as upon that the court may stand neuter and let him take the chance at law. I have considerable doubt upon that; for the authorities go to this, that where the transaction is against policy, it is no objection that the plaintiff himself was a party in that transaction which is illegal.” Similar language is used in many other cases. The same reasoning
But it is contended that both the mortgage bonds, and the certificates of deposit or post notes were issued in violation of the restraining act. (1 R. S., 712, §§ 3, 6.) If this be so, then the acts of the banks in issuing them were not merely ultra vires and against the policy of the law, but were specially prohibited. In that case, the question whether relief will be given depends upon principles somewhat different from those which apply to cases where the illegality of the contract consists merely in its being in contravention of public policy. It will not be necessary, however, definitively to decide whether the restraining act has been violated or not; because, in the view I take of the case, the determination of that point, either way, would not materially affect the result. This I shall proceed to show.
Here, again, we encounter the position, that one common consequence attends every contract which is for any cause illegal, not only in reference to the validity of the contract itself, but in respect to the rights and remedies of the parties, as against each other, upon its disaffirmance. I have already shown this position to be erroneous, as applied to the contracts of a corporation, where the only illegality consists in their being ultra vires. It is no less erroneous when applied to many contracts which are mala prohibita. When the contract is malum in se, it is conceded that neither party is entitled to relief as against the other; but, to use the • language of an elementary writer, “when the contract is malum prohibitum, and does not involve any moral turpitude or criminality, one party may, unde/some circumstances, have a remedy against the other party, on an executed or
The next case in order of time was that of Browning v. Morris (Cowp., 790). In this case, it is true, Lord Mansfield refers to a class of cases, in which he says the statute violated was enacted especially to protect one of the parties from oppression or imposition by the other; and it is no doubt to be inferred that he considered the case before him as belong
In the subsequent case of Jackson v. Withy (1 H. Bl., 65), the argument turned entirely upon the soundness of the doctrine that the party upon whom the penalty was imposed was to be regarded as the only guilty party. Sergeant Bond, for the defendant, argued that “ Though the penalty might only attach on one, both were, in the eye of the law, to a certain degree, criminal.” In speaking of the case of Jacques v. Golightly, he said: “Notwithstanding the doctrine laid down by Mr. Justice Blackstone in that case seems to imply that the office keeper alone was criminal, it was not necessary to decide so much,” and he cited Lowry v. Bordieu (Doug., 468). Sergeant Adair, in reply, said: “ In the case of Lowry v. Bordieu, the judgment of the court was founded on the circumstances of both parties being equally culpable. Here the keeper of the lottery office is the only person- upon whom the prohibition or penalty attaches.” It would, I think, be difficult to prove that this case was decided upon a ground not alluded to in it, and not upon that upon which the whole argument was made to turn.
By no fair analysis of the four cases here referred to, can it be shown that they do not directly and fully support the very reasonable doctrine that when a statute prohibits, under a penalty, an act not otherwise criminal or immoral, parties upon whom the prohibitions and penalties of the law do not attach, although they may participate to some extent in the illegal act, are not to be regarded as in pari delicto with
It is the prohibitory law itself, in all such cases, which discriminates as to the relative guilt of the parties. The courts do not determine whether they are in pari delicto, by scrutinizing the circumstances of the case, but adopt the distinction marked out by the statute.
Among the numerous cases cited by the receiver’s counsel, not one, so far as I am able to understand them, conflicts with this rule. They were mostly actions founded upon and seeking to enforce the illegal contract itself; and in none of them was this precise question considered. The case of Gillett v. Phillips (3 Kern., 114), which is one of the cases cited and relied upon by the counsel, tends impliedly to support the doctrine for which I contend. Chief Justice Gardiner there says: “The contract was not only unauthorized, but illegal. No action could be sustained upon it, if executory, in his favor, nor to set it aside if executed. Nor could it become the foundation of an implied assumpsit, in behalf of the offending party.” This qualification plainly admits that an implied contract may arise in such cases, in favor of a party who is not in pari delicto with the chief offender.
In Perkins v. Savage (15 Wend., 412), also cited by the receiver’s counsel, the plaintiff having been the party principally concerned in the illegal transaction, and for whose especial benefit it was devised, could not of course recover
The propriety of applying the principle which has been advanced to the present case is, I think, apparent, when it is Considered that public policy lies at the basis of the law óf illegal contracts, and that all general rules are made to yield to this policy. Judge Story even goes the length of
It may be objected to this doctrine, that there is a manifest incongruity in raising, by implication, a contract on the part of the corporation, which, it is at the same time held, would be void if expressly made. This objection however is, I think, without weight. If the incongruity referred to were real, it would be of little moment, as the implied contract is a mere legal fiction, resorted to simply for the purpose of complying with the forms of law. In equity no such implication is needed, and the objection, therefore, has no force when applied to the present case. The necessity of resorting to the fiction of a contract grows entirely out of the form in which justice is administered in common law actions. But the supposed incongruity does not really exist. It has never been held that a corporation could not promise to restore money or property acquired „
The conclusions to which I have thus arrived render it unnecessary to examine in detail the various claims, with one or two exceptions which, will be hereafter noticed. They are all limited to the amount actually advanced, with legal interest thereon. It remains, however, to be considered whether the respondents, or either of them, have any lien, for the sums so advanced, upon the securities assigned by the trust deeds. In the case of Leavitt v. Yates (4 Edw. Ch. R., 134), where a banking association had issued post notes in violation of the restraining act of 1840, and had, at the same time, executed a trust deed assigning certain effects to secure the payment of the notes, the vice-chancellor held that, the notes being void, the trust deed was also void. A similar decision was made by the Supreme Court at general term, in the case of Tylee v. Yates (3 Barb. S. C. R., 222). The principle adopted in these cases was fully confirmed by this court, in the case of Leavitt v. Palmer (3 Comst., 19).
But it is claimed by the respondents that, admitting the mortgage bonds and trust deeds to be equally void, still, the holders have an equitable lien upon the property assigned by the deeds, for the money advanced; and they base theii claim upon the ground that they advanced their money upon the faith of and relying upon these securities. The
I omit the examination of various questions and of several minor branches of the case, which it would have become necessary to consider had the principles here advanced been adopted by the court, and shall content myself with the general conclusion that the trusts are void, and that the receiver is entitled to the entire fund, to be distributed ratably among all the creditors of the company. The judgment of the supreme court ought, I think, to be reversed.
having been of counsel, did not sit in the case.
The court adopted the following propositions unanimously, except as otherwise noted:
1. The million and half million trusts mentioned in the pleadings and proofs are not void under the eighth section
2. The said trusts are not void under the ninth section of said statute; it being the opinion of the court that they were not made with intent to give a preference to particular creditors over other creditors. (Judge Selden not voting.)
3. The trusts are not void under the statute (2 R. S., 135, § 1), on the ground that they were made for the use of the North American Trust and Banking Company; it being the opinion of the court that the statute applies only to conveyances, &c., primarily for the use of the grantor, and not to instruments for other and active purposes, where the reservations to the grantor are incidental and partial, (Judge Selden not voting.)
4. The said trusts were not made with intent to hinder, delay or defraud creditors, and therefore they are not void on that ground. (Judge Selden not voting.)
5. The North American Trust and Banking Company had power to borrow money, and prior to the 3d day of June, 1840, banking associations could lawfully issue time paper to secure a debt for moneys loaned, with or without the corporate seal, provided such paper was not intended or calculated to circulate as money, and the trust bonds in the two trusts were not of a description falling within this proviso. (Judge Selden dissenting, but not on the ground that the said bonds were calculated or intended for circulation.)
6. Prior to the said 3d of June, 1840, the said trust bonds were issued and pledged to Palmer, Mackillop, Dent & Co.,, in London,' to secure their debt and future advances, with power to sell the same, according to the original design of the trust. Such pledge was valid, and it entitles the Palmers, &c., still holding three hundred and seventy-seven of the million and one hundred and eighty of the half million bonds under the same, to the benefit of the two
7. The said bonds, when so issued and pledged, and when portions of the same were sold, were English contracts, and the loans or advances procured on the sale of four hundred and ninety-nine of them belonging to the million trust were not usurious by the then existing laws of England, being exempted from the usury laws of that country by the statute of 2d and 3d Victoria, ch. 37. (Judge Selden not voting.)
8. Even if said loans upon the four hundred and ninety-nine bonds were usurious, the appellant, as receiver, representing, as he does, the corporation, is prohibited by the statute of this state, passed in 1850, ch. 172, from setting up the usury in these cases in any stage thereof.
9. The holders of the said four hundred and ninety-nine bonds are therefore entitled to share in the benefit of the million trust. (Judge Selden not voting.)
10. The loan, nominally, of $250,000, procured from the Philadelphia banks, was a Pennsylvania contract; and although it may have been usurious, nevertheless, by the laws of that state, the contract was inoperative only for the excess of interest over six per cent, the lawful interest.
11. The pledge of the two hundred and seventy half million bonds to said banks was valid, although the twelve certificates of deposit, amounting to $250,000, issued by said company, were prohibited by the statute of May 14, 1840, which took effect June 3, 1840; it being the opinion of the court that the intention and legal effect of the pledge were to secure the payment of the money loaned, and it being also the opinion of the court that the alleged voidness of the certificates of deposit, issued for the repayment of such loan, does not affect anything else in the contract. (Judge Shankland dissenting, on the ground that the pledge is void upon the authority of Leavitt v. Palmer, 3 Comst. 19.)
13. The Messrs. Holfords & Co. have a right to share in the million trust, as pledgees and holders of twenty-four of the bonds in that trust. (Judge Shankland dissenting as above, and Judge Selden not voting.)
14. The general account of Palmers, Mackillop, Dent & Co. against the North American Trust and Banking Company, including the advances made by them to take up the Davis bills, so-called, constitutes a legal and valid debt, to be reduced, however, by computing interest at five per cent only, instead of seven per cent, and by striking out the commissions on the sale of so many of the million bonds as they themselves purchased.
Decree modified accordingly.