226 F. 455 | S.D.N.Y. | 1915
The first question is of the established or reasonable royalty; the second, of treble damages. The first question breaks into three parts: The amount, if any, of the proper royalty; the scope of the accounting, whether for whole tires or the rubber stock alone; the Kokomo transaction. I shall take these up in order, and conclude with the question of treble damages.
The first question, therefore, is of the amount of an established, or of a reasonable, royalty. I do not see how any one can dispute that there is adequate proof of an established royalty of 10 or 20 cents-up to 1890. In 1899 the plaintiffs began themselves to manufacture the component parts, and they abandoned a license agreement, charging instead a flat rate for the rubber stock, which varied only with the cost of crude rubber, a practice they continued down to May, 1902, when the Circuit Court of Appeals of the Sixth Circuit declared the patent, void. In these contracts it was, nevertheless, specifically agreed that the flat price should include the rent of a brazing or welding machine and the royalty for the patent in suit, together with a design patent. The “rent and royalty” so fixed was originally 20 cents like the immediately preceding licenses, but competition cut this down first to 10 cents and subsequently to 5 cents.
The defendant’s theory is that this figure cannot be regarded as wholly royalty, since both sides did not so understand it, since the plaintiffs sold freely in the market to others at the same prices, and since the flat price necessarily included the profits of the business, which on the average are estimated at 6.24 cents per pound from 1903 to 1908, during \\ hich time the patent had little or no protection. The licenses distinctly provide that the sum shall be “rent and royalty,” of which the rent is a trilling matter, and I think the parties must be said to have so understood it; but f do not think that the matter is necessarily settled by what the parties called it. As to the second objection, it seems to me of no consequence that the plaintiffs sold to outsiders, except in so fat as it shows that the royalty, so called, included the plaintiff’s profits, aud was not all royalty.
This brings up the third point. I agree that a license gives only the right to practice the invention, and that its value, and hence the reasonable royalty for it, must leave room for the usual profit in the business, logether with the cost of production. Whether the resulting price will be greater than what the market will bear only experience can test, which means that what the market will bear determines the license value or royalty. Even though the parties agree to call a sum a royalty, it should not be taken as such if it include the manufacturers’ profits in cases where, as here, he does not give the mere right, but makes the
In this posture of affairs came the decision inyalidáting the patent on May 6, 1902, making impossible any true established royalty thereafter. All the subsequent period until the patent was finally declared valid in April, 1911, seems to me irrelevant to any just estimate of the patentee’s damages. Even if, crippled as the patent was by the adverse ruling, an apparent established royalty during that period had been shown, I should not regard it as a true established royalty, because that phrase should not be used of the value of a patent monopoly which is suspected with good reason of being no patent at all. What we seek is the sum above cost and profits which the patentee could exact of the market through his monopoly. The sum he exacted while he ■was ■ unable to enforce it, and while every one supposed he had no monopoly at all, or at least suspected he might not have any, is. surely no index of the actual value of his right. Hence I think that during the period there was no established royalty for the right, and that we must seek a reasonable royalty, to which I now turn. Although the evidence of the mingled elements of profit and royalty and rent substantially ceased in 1902; and although the infringement did not begin till 1905, yet, had the patent continuously enjoyed the recognition to which it is now conceded to be entitled, it would in 1905 have been- possible to charge and to get the same sum for the same elements, and to continue to get it till the patent expired.
To begin with, the plaintiffs swear they continued to charge the sum of 20 cents till they were forced to a reduction first to 10 and in some cases to 5 cents by the competition of infringers. Again, we have the right to assume that a royalty established as this was over a period of years would continue, unless some change is shown in the market conditions. The only change shown is the presence of infringers, who wrongfully cut under the prices established by the patentee. It is an inference that the plaintiff could have continued its profits of 20 cents, and that the market would have borne it, had it not been for this new factor, which arose after 1902. I shall proceed upon the assumption, therefore, that the joint sum of rent, reasonable profit, and reasonable royalty have been proved to amount to the sum of 20 cents, the amount amply proved to^ be obtainable up to May, 1902.
However, it is urged that the licenses to jobbers -and manufacturers were no tests of the proper licenses to rubber makers, and in support of ibis the Firestone Case is instanced. That case was a compromise made of a past license when the patent had only two more years to win, and the license was coupled with an adjusted balance for past infringement of $80,000. It may be dismissed, I think, from consideration as a test. As to the objection that these licenses were all tO' jobbers and the like, I think it makes no difference. In estimating lost sales it is, of course, necessary to show that the patentee would have made the sales. Not so with licenses. Every wheel made up with Diamond rubber was a wheel upon which the plaintiffs lost a license, whether they would have manufactured it or not. In contributing to that eventual infringement which occurred when the rubber was so
The defendants will suggest' this difficulty with the foregoing treatment: That it ignores the effect of the three suits which gave immunity to the Goodyear Company, the Kokomo Company, and the Victor Company. This immunity extended to selling the rubber stock, and we may assume that it also extended to selling complete tires. So far as concerns complete tires, they would be immune in the hands of the customers of all three companies; but, so far as concerns the rubber stock, no one who bought could possibly have used it, either to make up tires himself (Rubber Tire Co. v. Goodyear Co., 232 U. S. 413, 34 Sup. Ct. 403, 58 L. Ed. 663), or to sell the component elements to another to make up tires (Woodward Co. v. Hurd, 232 U. S. 428, 34 Sup. Ct. 409, 58 L. Ed. 670), or, in my judgment, to -sell the rubber stock alone, with intent that it should go to make up a Grant tire, as I shall show later. This being true, the three companies did not have it in their power to affect what would have been the royalty for the invention during the period in question for the following reasons:
Their effective right to sell only complete tires made impossible to them any effective competition, unless they went into the tire business themselves, making up and selling the invention as a whole. Otherwise, the plaintiffs could have stopped their customers from any practical use of what they had bought, a condition which would at once have stopped their sales. On the other hand, each of these companies was a rubber company, selling this stock to jobbers in tires, to carriage manufacturers and the like, and doing a large outside business. It is the.merest speculation to assume that they would have gone into corrr-petition with their former customers iti the tire business in order to avail themselves of the only rights secured by their decrees. What they needed to compete with the plaintiff was the right to sell rubber stock of proper size and conformation, with or without the channels and wires, and that they really never got by the decrees, though the trade did generally suppose so, until the Supreme Court decided the question. They never did go into the manufacture of complete tires upon a scale large enough to. affect the plaintiff’s market, and if speculation is proper I see no reason to suppose they ever would have.
All sorts of considerations might have influenced them against such an undertaking; if they competed directly with carriage manufacturers and with jobbers, they might have lost in good will more than they could have possibly made in the sale of tires; the reorganization of their business to include this might have wholly thrown out of gear their methods and their prospects. We must, I think, take this record as it stands, showing them competitors in the sale of rubber stock and in that alone. We may not assume that, had they learned early enough that their customers were all infringers, they would have sold the complete tires. Therefore the plaintiffs were all along the only ones
The defendants’ only answer is that, although the tires were sold with that expectation aud intent, they might have been used either with siraighr-sided channels or with cement. Their theory is that they were not fitted only for an infringing tire, under the doctrine of Crown Cork & Seal Co. v. Brooklyn Bottle Stopper Co. (C. C.) 172 Fed. 225, and similar cases. This rubber stock was, however, not fitted for any other use. I do not mean to say that it could not have been used in straight channels, though these had substantially disappeared by 1905; but, if they had been so used, it would have been a perversion from its obvious purpose. Having made them for that use, it would be most unfair to ask the plaintiffs to show that they had not been misused. The same thing is true of the possible cementing of the tires into the channels. The holes for wiring are there, and if they were in addition cemented, that should be shown. There is undoubtedly proof of a certain amount of cementing, which the plaintiffs insist had been discontinued before 1905. I have not found any very definite evidence upon that question, but I think it immaterial. If an infringer had wired down the rubber in the channels, I do not think that he would be less an infringer if he also cemented it. This is not inconsistent with the fact that the merit of the invention lay in the free tipping feature. The invention itself lay in the claims, and the claims may be infringed, though the merits be lost. There is nothing in the decisions to show that to fasten by wires and cement is not to infringe. The holes in the rubber indicate that the defendant’s intention was to have wires used. If any of the rubber was not so used, that should have been shown by the defendants.
The final question concerns the Kokomo contract, and the defendants’ device to avoid infringement after the Supreme Court had finally declared the patent valid. Judge Day has already passed upon this, and his opinon leaves nothing more to say. It has been decided that, though the Kokomo' Company might sell the rubber, it was an invasion of the patent for any customer to sell it with the other parts to another for the purpose of making up a tire. Woodward Co. v. Hurd, 232 U. S. 428, 34 Sup. Ct. 409, 58 L. Ed. 670. If it was an infringement for the Woodward Company to sell the rubber and channels and wires, it must be an infringement for the defendant to sell to the Woodward Company with that intent, unless the whole basis of contributory infringement is different froth what I have stated.
The effect of the clause introduced into the decree in this suit is not touched upon in any of the opinions in 232 U. S. 428, 34 Sup. Ct. 409, 58 L. Ed. 670, because the defendants were not parties; but in the appeal reported in 220 U. S. 428, 445, 31 Sup. Ct. 444, 55 L. Ed. 527, the Supreme Court concurred with the remarks of Judge Coxe and these clearly show that the Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit had no intention of construing that language as a decision upon this question. They simply meant to leave the defendants in the same position respecting rubber bought of the Kokomo Company and the other licensed infringers as though the decree had not passed; the question being left open for future consideration. Now the time has come to consider the question, which turns out to be controlled by Woodward v. Hurd, supra. I therefore overrule the defendants’ exceptions.
As to the defendants’ first exception to the report, I shall overrule it. The theory that their profits should be taken as a reasonable royalty certainly has no basis in fact or in law. There is undoubtedly a good deal to be said for the position that a reasonable royalty could be figured at a higher figure than 5 cents, as I have tried to show; but-ilo one in the case seems to have considered it from that point of view.' The onfy reasonable royalty actually fixed was 5 cents, and it would be rather absurd to fix such a royalty at the sum of 6.24 cents; the very idea being something of an approximation. Moreover, there is a more substantial reason for caution, which arises from the in
After April, 1911, there is certainly much less to say in excuse for the continued infringement. Had the decisions in Seim v. Hurd, supra, and Woodward Co. v. Hurd, supra, been then made there could have been no excuse, or shadow of excuse, for continuing the business. The provision for treble damages would mean nothing, if it did not apply to such a case. But the case of Kessler v. Eldred, 206 U. S. 285, 27 Sup. Ct. 611, 51 L. Ed. 1065, had not then been overruled or limited, and the scope of that case in my judgment put the matter in doubt. Kessler v. Eldred, supra, held that, if Kessler was protected in selling the lighters, his customers were also protected. All that the Kokomo- Company needed was the same immunity for its customers in selling a constituent part of the combination. If the customers had such a right when the seller sold the whole invention, it was certainly not clear that the customers, had not the right to resell to others a single constituent’element, just as it was, which the seller had the right to sell to them. Indeed, the defendants still argue on this very accounting that the Supreme Court did not mean to' include the resalé of a single constituent element. Therefore, had the defendants merely bought from the Kokomo Company after the decision of the Supreme Court, I should not have thought that they were doing what they necessarily knew they hád no right to do. I could not say that their infringement had in their own minds no color of excuse.
In fact, they did not do this. The Kokomo Company was not then making any rubber stock, and' what it sold the defendants under the contract of 1911 was made out of rubber compound furnished by the defendants, through the use of the old molds, with which up to that time the defendants had made the infringing tires. While it was not quite the equivalent of buying a license from the Kokomo Company, since the latter did actually mold the rubber, a process which cost them about 2 cents of the 5 they received, it missed being a license only by that margin. Certainly, if the defendants had attempted merely to buy a license of the Kokomo’ Company, it would be too much to ask that such an attempt be taken in good faith. What they actually did was no doubt a middle ground between buying from the Kokomo Company in the honest belief that they could resell and taking a mere •
Furthermore, the defendant’s whole conduct has shown that it sought by every device to infringe this patent with impunity. The organization of the Diamond Company of New York, its dissolution at the very expiration of the patent, the assuring that it should by no change have any profits to reach, the efforts to resist the disclosure of the Ohio Company’s books, the deviousness throughout of its persistent effort to suck the value from the invention and not pay the price, all these do not help its cause. I shall therefore increase so much of the award as is earned after the decision of the Supreme Court, not by trebling it, as I might do, but.by adding the sum of $50,000, which should be. enough to pay the costs of the litigation and give the plaintiffs smart money, in addition to the actual award as damages.
Eet a decree pass for poundage at 5 cents per pound, with interest, as stated, together with $50,000, and costs.