567 F.2d 64 | D.C. Cir. | 1977
Lead Opinion
Opinion for the Court filed by District Judge GESELL.
Dissenting Opinion filed by Circuit Judge WRIGHT.
In a special rulemaking proceeding, the Interstate Commerce Commission has determined that there exists a national shortage of epoxy-lined (“XF”) boxcars and has required railroads using another line’s XF cars to make incentive per diem (“IPD”) payments to their owners.
The Commission’s finding of a shortage was based on evidence that 750,000 carloads of processed food are shipped annually, requiring a nation-wide fleet of 40,000-50,000 suitable cars. Since it has determined that only XF cars are suitable, and evidence indicated that only about 3,000 such cars exist, the Commission found a clear national shortage. IPD was thus imposed with the expectation that this would encourage the acquisition of XF boxcars.
Petitioner contends that there is no evidence of an XF boxcar shortage because there was no evidence that any processed food shipper had requested an XF car and not received one. It also claims that the Commission did not meet its own previously established criteria for the imposition of IPD.
Conrail assumes that there can be no finding of boxcar shortage under the statute unless there is a record of shipper complaints. However, in determining the existence of a shortage the Commission may certainly consider the public interest as well as the interests of shippers. IPD may be imposed to “encourage the acquisition and maintenance of a car supply adequate to meet the needs of commerce . . . .” 49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a). We cannot define the needs of commerce so narrowly as to exclude the need of consumers for uncontaminated, infestation-free food.
It is clear that, as petitioner asserts, the Commission did not compile as elaborate a statistical record in the XF boxcar proceeding as it did in prior proceedings.
The dissent, however, after an exhaustive examination of the legislative history of this statute, concludes that IPD can be imposed only where boxcar shortages are caused by the tendency of some railroads to hold cars owned by other lines. It says, in essence, that this section of the statute was aimed only at inefficient car utilization practices. However, the statutory delegation of power goes far beyond this limited field:
It is the intent of Congress to encourage the purchase, acquisition and efficient*67 utilization of freight cars. * * * In determining the rates of compensation to be paid for each type of freight car, the Commission shall give consideration to the transportation use of each type of freight car, to the national level of ownership of each such type of freight car, and to other factors affecting the adequacy of the national freight car supply. * * * Such compensation may be increased by any incentive element which will . . . provide just and reasonable compensation to freight car owners, contribute to sound car service practices (including efficient utilization and distribution of cars), and encourage the acquisition and maintenance of a car supply adequate to meet the needs of commerce . . . . 49 U.S.C. §. l(14)(a).7
We do not think the Court should rewrite this broad delegation by reference to the legislative history. It is too clear from the statute on its face that inefficient car utilization and distribution is but one of the permissible grounds for the imposition of incentive payments.
The Commission here has acted within its grant of statutory authority, and with substantial evidence to support its actions. The Commission is affirmed.
. Incentive Per Diem Charges-1968 (XF Cars), 350 ICC 11 (1975).
. We find on the record substantial evidence to support the Commission’s findings and do not reach the issue whether a lesser evidentiary showing would suffice. See Judge Wright’s opinion at p.--of 185 U.S.App.D.C., p. 68 of 567 F.2d, n.3 infra.
. We also note that the Commission may establish car service rules, after hearings, on its own initiative as well as after a complaint. 49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a).
. That the result may also be achieved, as the dissent suggests, by alterations in other car service rules is beside the point. Those determinations are left to the Commission.
. See Incentive Per Diem Charges-Gondolas, 40 Fed.Reg. 44851 (1975); Incentive Per Diem Charges-1968, 349 ICC 303 (1975).
. P. - of 185 U.S.App.D.C., p. 73 of 567 F.2d n.26 (12 infra.
. The statute currently reads as quoted, having been amended by § 212(a) of the Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform Act of 1976 (P.L. 94-210, Feb. 5, 1976). See Judge Wright’s opinion p.-of 185 U.S.App.D.C., p. 68 of 567 F.2d n.6 for the text at the time the ICC decision in this case was made.
Dissenting Opinion
dissenting:
This case has been argued by the Interstate Commerce Commission and the Justice Department as though the health of the American public would be gravely affected by its outcome. Were this true, I would find it difficult to lodge a dissent. But in fact the health of the nation is not at stake here because no matter how this case is decided the Commission will have ample power to create a fleet of sanitary freight cars, if indeed such a fleet is needed.
While the Commission’s action might be affirmed on a proper record, I do not agree with the majority that the record we have been presented in this case is satisfactory.
I. BACKGROUND
In order to understand the incentive per diem scheme authorized by Section l(14)(a) of the Interstate Commerce Act,
The tariff paid by a shipper for a multi-line haul is divided among the carriers who participate in a car’s movement. The expense associated with use of the freight car is similarly allocated among the participants through the mechanism of “per diem” payments made by each non-owning partici-
pant to the owning line.
Once unloaded, further movement of a car in interchange service is controlled by a series of car service rules, which have traditionally been promulgated by the Association of American Railroads but some of which are now established by the Commission.
As a result of the interchange, per diem, and car service rules, freight cars have in effect been put into a national pool upon which any road is free to draw (and, indeed, may be obligated to draw)
The Commission concluded that one of the principal factors causing [the] inadequate supply of freight cars was the operation of the national car-pool system. In practice this system resulted in freight cars being on lines other than those of the owning road for long periods of time, since the rules providing for the return of unloaded freight cars in the direction of the lines of the owning road were observed more often than not in the breach. Since the owning road was deprived of the use of its own freight cars for extended periods of time, the Commission found, there was very little incentive for it to acquire new freight cars. In addition, since a road which owned a supply of freight cars inadequate to serve its own on-line shippers could generally, by hook or by crook, arrange to utilize cars owned by other roads, the national car-pool system significantly reduced the normal incentive for a railroad to acquire sufficient equipment to serve its customers.
United States v. Allegheny-Ludlum Steel Corp., 406 U.S. 742, 745, 92 S.Ct. 1941, 1945, 32 L.Ed.2d 453 (1972); see Increased Per Diem Charge on Freight Cars, 268 ICC 659, 670 (1947).
The Commission first attempted to use an increased per diem charge as a regulatory tool to correct the car shortage problem in 1947. See generally Increased Per Diem Charge on Freight Cars, supra. At, that time, the Commission found that connecting lines were holding cars unloaded after interchange service for what were in its view unjustifiably long periods of time.
Having struggled for almost 20 years to gain authority to impose IPD, the Commission in 1967 reversed course and refused to promulgate IPD regulations because it found no evidence that any freight cars were in short supply. Incentive Per Diem Charges, 332 ICC 11 (1967). After a dressing down by the Senate Subcommittee on Surface Transportation,
II. THE DECISION TO IMPOSE IPD ON XF BOXCARS
The Commission decision reviewed here originated in response to a petition filed by General Mills, Inc. (GMI) in one phase of the continuing XM boxcar proceeding. GMI alleged that owners of boxcars designated XP and XF were reclassifying these cars as XM boxcars in order to take advantage of the increased returns made possible by IPD on the XM cars.
The XF car designation was introduced in 1973. It indicates that a boxcar is equipped with a white epoxy inner coating and it can only be used by shippers of non-contaminating food products. See XF Report, supra, 350 ICC at 13. The XF designation was intended to replace the XP designation, which had been applied to plain, unequipped
According to the Commission, only the XF car can adequately protect the sanitation of processed package foods. XF Report, supra, 350 ICC at 18-19. It appears that the epoxy inner lining of the XF car prevents any rodents or insects which might be nesting between the outer and inner walls of the boxcar from gaining access to the food inside the car. As a result in-transit contamination of food shipped in containers which rodents or insects might otherwise penetrate is reduced or eliminated altogether. By contrast, the “class A” XM car traditionally used for carriage of processed packaged foods has clear disadvantages. See id. at 18. This car is no more than a regular XM boxcar to which the “class A” designation is attached once it has been cleaned and inspected to eliminate unsanitary conditions. In practice, the visual inspection upon which class A status is based is said to be inadequate because such an inspection will not detect infestation between the walls of an XM car and because .the quality of visual inspections varies widely from inspector to inspector. In addition, because XM cars are free-running, i. e., they may be used by any shipper regardless of the type of freight it proposes to load, it is possible that contaminants will be introduced which are not detectable by visual inspection but which can nonetheless taint subsequent loads of processed foods.
Given its conclusion that only XF boxcars are suitable for transportation of processed food products, the Commission takes the further position that the existence of a shortage of XF cars “is amply demonstrated by the prevalent use of the so-called class ‘A’ boxcars in transporting shipments of food products.” Id.
It is this further conclusion that is challenged by Conrail, primarily because the Commission has not cited even one instance where a food shipper has asked for, but has not received, an XF car, and because there is no such instance reported in the comments in this proceeding. Conrail also challenges what it perceives to be an inconsistency between the standard of proof of shortages required by the Commission in other incentive per diem cases and the sparse record in this proceeding. The majority has rejected both of these contentions, as do I.
III. THE ADEQUACY OF THE COMMISSION’S SHORTAGE FINDING
The Commission’s position can be summarized as follows: -(1) there are approximately 750,000 carloads of processed food shipped yearly;
Initially, it is interesting to note that William K. Smith, GMI’s vice-president for transportation and the moving party in these proceedings, stated, contrary to the Commission’s conclusion, that GMI uses successfully DF, DFB, and XM cars.
The record further suggests that there is nothing inherently unsanitary about the XM car. The problem with these cars arises only after rodents and insects infest their inner walls. All parties agree that such infestation is not present in the car at the beginning of its life, but is caused by introduction of bulk feeds, grains, and similar loose, life-supporting products into the XM car. See XF Report, supra, 350 ICC at 13; ICC Environmental Threshold Assessment Survey, JA 156, 162; comments of GMI, Exhibit 16, at 10, JA 54 (testimony of Mr. Smith). See also br. for the United States at 8. Indeed, it appears that the XP boxcar, which unlike the XF did not initially have an epoxy coating and was therefore substantially identical to an XM car, was successfully used by processed food shippers in assigned service for a number of years prior to creation of the XF designation. See XF Report, supra, 350 ICC at 13; comments of GMI, Exhibit 17, at 4, JA 63; comments of General Foods Corp., JA 146. The success of the XP car as a sanitary vehicle is apparently due not to its intrinsic design, therefore, but only to the fact that its restriction to assigned service prevents introduction, or repeated reintroduction, of contaminating cargoes into the car.
The record in this proceeding thus strongly indicates that the scarcity of sanitary cars is due to the absence of a classification for food-quality boxcars of whatever design which would allow their assignment and control in a manner like that established for XF cars by Association of American Railroads Car Service Directive 155.
There can be no doubt that the Commission recognized the crucial interplay between sanitation and car service rules, for it reversed its initial proposal to put XF cars in general service
Given this state of facts, I think the Commission has failed to give adequate consideration to all relevant factors and has further stopped short of giving the record the hard look essential to an exercise of informed discretion. Accordingly, I would vacate the rules imposing IPD on XF cars. By this, I do not mean to imply that the Commission must modify car service rules before it can apply IPD. The Commission plainly enjoys discretion to proceed by promulgation of rules, imposition of IPD, or a combination of approaches. It may not, however, impose IPD because a scarcity of a particular type of car has been generated primarily by the very car service rules which the Commission is empowered to change until it has at least considered whether a seemingly simple car service rule modification would alleviate the shortage.
IV. STATUTORY AUTHORITY TO IMPOSE IPD
As indicated above, the commission has in my judgment failed to make out a case for
Section l(14)(a) as amended in 1966 allows IPD to be imposed only if the Commission finds both that a shortage of a particular type of car exists and that incentive elements are necessary to “provide just and reasonable compensation to freight ear owners, contribute to sound car service practices * * *, and encourage the acquisition and maintenance of a car supply adequate to meet the needs of commerce * * *
Given the definition of basic per diem in Section l(14)(a) to include a fair return on value, it also becomes clear that the “just and reasonable compensation to freight car owners” for which IPD can be instituted must be something other than “fair return” on money invested. . That something else, according to the Commission, is a return to compensate “for the earning power or the value of the use of the vehicle which is lost by the owner when [a car is] used or appropriated by other carriers.” ICC, Seventy-First Annual Report, supra, at 137.
The legislative history of the 1966 amendment to Section l(14)(a) confirms that the “fit” of the amendment to the regulatory problem described in Part I is no coincidence and that the statutory inadequacy of
[t]he shortage [which the amendment was intended to correct] results from the fact that many western roads build sufficient ears, but the trouble is that when the cars are on eastern roads, in the course of delivering goods to eastern markets, there is a reluctance on the part of some railroads in the East to return the cars * * * * * *
at * * * *
Some railroads find it more desirable to keep the boxcars and pay the $3 or $4 rental — at one time it was less than $2— than to buy boxcars. It is less costly to rent cars than to build them.
111 Cong.Rec. 15375 (1965). See also S.Rep. No.386, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 3 (1965); S.Rep.No.452, 86th Cong., 1st Sess. 4-5 (1959). A similar understanding of the problem was echoed in the House. See, e. g., 112 Cong.Rec. 10437 (1966) (remarks of Rep. Mize) (“when the per diem charge is low, as it is now, it is cheaper to rent a car than it is to buy or build one”); id. at 10438-10439 (remarks of Rep. Adams) (“[o]bviously it has been cheaper for many railroads to simply take the new cars produced by other railroads and hold them on their lines and pay a minimal rental rather than produce new cars”). See also Hearings on HR. 2230, HR. 7165, and S. 1098 Before the House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 20, 30, 32-33, 39 (1965) (remarks of sponsors of legislation to amend § l(14)(a)).
Notwithstanding the focus of the 1966 amendment, the Commission has chosen here to apply IPD to a type of freight car which has never been part of the national pool of free-running boxcars. Instead, use and return of XF cars had been governed until the order in this proceeding by Association of American Railroads Car Service Directive 155
The modification of Directive 155 required by the order here under review, see XF Report, supra, 350 ICC at 19, does not change the foregoing conclusions materially. The XF Report prohibits assignment of cars to a single shipper, but continues to allow assignment to a single location— which can presumably be a location on the owning railroad’s line — for use in originating shipments on the owner’s line. See id. Thus, for example, Grand Trunk Western Railroad now assigns all its cars to Battle Creek, Michigan, a location convenient to a number of its major food shippers,
The record before us does not, therefore, support the conclusion that the disincentives to car ownership associated with the national boxcar pool have affected the supply of XF cars. This raises the question whether the broad language of the 1966 amendment nonetheless allows imposition of IPD on XF cars even though the existence of the core problem to which Congress addressed the 1966 amendment has not been established. I think it does not, although this conclusion is not free from difficulty given the blunderbuss nature of IPD
Initially, it is important to note that there is no evidence that XF cars are being “appropriated” by non-owning lines for their own use or are being allowed to stand idle, and consequently IPD on XF cars is in essence a tax on the function of terminating through hauls. Although Congress clearly appreciated that IPD would accrue while this function was performed, the legislative history of the 1966 amendment to Section l(14)(a) indicates that no assessment of IPD was to be made on the termination function except where this was incidental to the mechanics of imposing IPD on improper uses of foreign cars.
The Commission chairman testified before Congress that it was not the Commission’s position that net per diem debtors should be taxed as such because at least some debtors would be short lines, or terminating or bridge roads, which ought proper
Under the Senate version of the bill, the ICC was specifically empowered to exempt from the incentive, or penalty, element of the freight car charges any or all of the groups [expressly enumerated in the Senate bill].
The aim of these provisions of the Senate bill, which I had a part in suggesting, was to assure reasonable and fair consideration of the special problems arising in the industry, including the problem of the terminating railroads, whose per diem charges are not related to the number of boxcars they may own.
In the bill before us today, as it has come back from the House of Representatives, the four types of circumstances spelled out in the Senate bill are not directly listed. It is clear, however, that all the factors listed in the Senate bill still have to be considered by the * * Commission, and the Commission would have the power, and the duty, not to apply the incentive element to any group of carriers, and even a single carrier, where those‘four circumstances, or any other circumstances, made it in the national interest to do so.
112 Cong.Rec. 10756 (1966) (emphasis added). Senator Cotton’s understanding of the effect of the House amendment seems clearly correct since the same view was taken by Representative Staggers, House floor manager for the bill:
[T]he committee amendment provides that the Commission would be empowered in its discretion to exempt from the incentive element provisions any group of carriers where the Commission finds such exemption to be in the national interest. This provision enables the Commission to make exemptions from paying an incentive element by class of carrier, and permits the Commission to consider the several factors specifically authorized in the Senate bill.
112 Cong.Rec. 10435 (1966).
The conclusion that IPD was not to be applied except where there was some evidence that the breakdown of the national car-pool system had contributed to car shortages is further buttressed by a consideration of the meaning of the phrase “just and reasonable compensation” used in the 1966 amendment to describe IPD payments. The reason the Commission adopted IPD rather than a simple penalty to be paid to the United States appears to be that car owners were losing revenue in times of shortage because their cars were being “appropriated” by non-owners and because no foreign cars were available on the owners’ lines to take the place of cars lost to non-owners.
Inexplicably, Representative Staggers stated that the House amendment to the Senate bill rejected this concept of use value since it was “essentially * * * an approach to the problem through penalties rather than through incentives.” 112 Cong; Ree. 10435 (1966). This statement notwithstanding, there is nothing in the legislative history of the House amendment which gives any other credible reason for compensating freight car owners for the use of their cars in time of shortage. This is especially so today when the Commission has set basic per diem rates in accord with the standards set out in Section l(14)(a) so that the criticism often voiced in the House debate — that the basic per diem did not give a sufficient return on value to the owners of freight cars — can no longer be validly made.
Finally, the history of the 1976 amendment to Section l(14)(a) also supports the view that IPD is proper only where railroads are using foreign boxcars in times of shortage. That amendment added a preamble to Section l(14)(a) which reads: “It is the intent of Congress to encourage the purchase, acquisition, and efficient utilization of freight cars.” Pub.L.No.94-210, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. § 212, 90 Stat. 46-47 (1976). While this language would support a very broad reading of the Commission’s authority to impose IPD, the legislative history of this preamble discloses that the concern of Congress was to authorize and encourage a remedy for improper use of foreign freight cars: “The first change [the preamble] provides that the intent of Congress is to encourage ownership of cars and discourage the use of cars not owned.” H.R.Rep.No.725, 94th Cong., 1st Sess. 73 (1975) (emphasis added).
Further evidence that IPD cannot be imposed except as a corrective for disincentives to freight car ownership associated with the national car-pool system can be found in the Commission’s interpretation of the shortage requirement in all other IPD proceedings.
In the first IPD report to discuss in detail the evidence needed to justify imposition of IPD, Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968, 349 ICC 303 (1975), issued only months before the XF car rules, the Commission declined to extend IPD to covered hopper cars, stating that the record did not meet the evidentiary standards for imposing IPD which it defined as follows:
* * * [W]e are amenable to an expansion of the incentive per diem program to cars other than general service*83 boxcars if (1) a record is made showing the car to be in short supply, (2) a record is made showing a reluctance to expeditiously release the car by the terminating or delivering railroad * * *.
Id. at 311 (emphasis added). This position was reiterated a few months after promulgation of the XF ear rules in the Commission’s notice of proposed rulemaking in Incentive Per Diem Charges — Gondolas, 40 Fed.Reg. 44851 (1975). There the Commission stated:
The record should be developed to describe current utilization and distribution practices in order to examine the impact of these practices on gondola car supply. * * *
Id. at 44851.
In summary, with the conclusion of the XF proceeding the Commission has come completely about in its understanding of the uses to which IPD should be put. In 1947 IPD was envisioned as a short-term tool which was presented to the Palmer court as a device whose purpose was “wholly independent” of any notion of compensation for car owners.
V. CONCLUSION
Nobody wants rats or insects in their breakfast cereal, and if the choice here were between rats or financial hardship on Conrail, I would take a stand with the majority. But this is not the choice. For all that is shown on the record of this rulemaking, sanitation could be costlessly achieved simply by Commission promulgation of rules allowing clean XM cars to be retained in an assigned service free from the continual loading of contaminants. Yet the Commission seems oblivious to this possibility, even though its availability is strongly indicated by the record. Equally important, the Commission has not demonstrated that it has the authority to impose IPD on XF cars, although I believe it does have the authority to create an XF car fleet under other parts of the Interstate Commerce Act. Because of this, I would not -allow the Commission to create a broad taxing power where it is clear that none was intended by Congress. Since the majority opinion does not require the Commission to take a hard look at the record and because the majority concurs in what is in my view an unsound reading of the incentive per diem amendments, I respectfully dissent.
. Imposition of incentive per diem is by no means the only regulatory approach open to the Commission. It can order railroads which serve food shippers to provide the necessary XF cars. See Illinois Terminal R. Co. v. United States, 541 F.2d 201, 206 & n.7 (8th Cir. 1976). In some circumstances, it can condition tariff increases on earmarking of additional revenues for purchase of sanitary equipment. See United States v. Chesapeake & Ohio R. Co., 426 U.S. 500, 96 S.Ct. 2318, 49 L.Ed.2d 14 (1976). Finally, it can change car service rules to prevent loading of contaminants into cars otherwise suitable for food transportation. See 49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a) (1970), as amended by Pub.L. No.94-210, § 212(a), 90 Stat. 46-47 (1976). The only course which it may not adopt is to act without authority and without a proper record, no matter how indisputably beneficial its goals may be. See Hampton v. Mow Sun Wong, 426 U.S. 88, 96 S.Ct. 1895, 48 L.Ed.2d 495 (1976).
. The majority’s characterization of the incentive per diem statute as a “broad delegation,” majority op. at 5, 567 F.2d at 66, is misplaced. While the language of the incentive per diem provisions may be broad, its sweep must surely be tempered by the rather narrow office of the car service provisions in the overall scheme of the Interstate Commerce Act. Moreover, there is no evidence in the legislative history of the incentive per diem provisions which would indicate that Congress intended to grant a sweeping authority. Indeed, the House Report accompanying the bill which became the amending legislation specifically states that there was no evidence that the incentive per diem scheme would even work. See H.R.Rep.No.1183, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 2-3 (1965), U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1966, p. 2227, See also H.R.Rep.No.1384, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. 20 (1972) (“incentive per diem as presently structured is not working. It is neither an effective incentive to return cars nor to buy new ones.”).
. The proper standard of review of the record in a proceeding such as this is a matter of some dispute. In United States v. Allegheny-Ludlum Steel Corp., 406 U.S. 742, 92 S.Ct. 1941, 32 L.Ed.2d 453 (1972), the Supreme Court appeared to require substantial evidence on the record as a whole. See 406 U.S. at 753, 92 S.Ct. 1941. One year later, however, the Court ruled in United States v. Florida East Coast R. Co., 410 U.S. 224, 93 S.Ct. 810, 35 L.Ed.2d 223 (1973) , that the “hearing” requirement was not the full hearing envisioned for adjudications under the Administrative Procedure Act, but could generally be satisfied by procedures required for rulemaking. Since the substantial evidence test does not, under the Administrative Procedure Act, apply to the latter procedures, see 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(E) (1970), it is unclear where the matter stands today. On remand in Florida East Coast, the three-judge District Court concluded that substantial evidence was still required. See Florida East Coast R. Co. v. United States, 368 F.Supp. 1009, 1014-1015 (M.D. Fla. 1973) (three-judge court), affd, 417 U.S. 901, 94 S.Ct. 2595, 41 L.Ed.2d 207 (1974). A contrary view was apparently taken by another three-judge District Court in Ann Arbor R. Co. v. United States, 368 F.Supp. 101, 112 (E.D. Pa. 1973), aff’d per cu-riam, 419 U.S. 807, 95 S.Ct. 23, 42 L.Ed.2d 36 (1974) . Both District Court cases have been affirmed by the Supreme Court. Because I find either that the record is devoid of any evidence to support the Commission or that the evidence adduced indicates that the Commission has abused its discretion, I do not reach the scope of review issue.
. “The Commission shall not make any incentive element applicable to any type of freight car the supply of which the Commission finds to be adequate * * *.” 49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a) (1970).
. If anything is plain, it is the error of the Commission’s interpretation of its authority under § l(14)(a) of the Interstate Commerce Act, 49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a). Even the Commission’s counsel in brief in this very case appears to agree that § l(14)(a) is intended to deal with the ills of the national car-pool system. See br. of ICC at 1-6.- To be sure, Commission counsel has not carried the logic of this position through to its end: that this purpose requires a record which shows the ills of the national car-pool system to be an aggravating factor in shortages of cars upon which IPD is imposed. However, in other proceedings, which bracket the rulemaking reviewed here, the Commission has itself recognized that evidence of such aggravating factors is required before IPD can properly be imposed. See text at notes 62 to 63 infra. I argue for no more.
. At the time of the Commission’s decision in this case, this section read as follows:
(a) The Commission may, after hearing, on a complaint or upon its own initiative without complaint, establish reasonable rules, regulations, and practices with respect to car service by common carriers by railroad subject to this chapter, including the compensation to be paid and other terms of any contract, agreement, or arrangement for the use of any locomotive, car, or other vehicle not*69 owned by the carrier using it (and whether or not owned by another carrier), and the penalties or other sanctions for nonobservance of such rules, regulations, or practices. In fixing such compensation to be paid for the use of any type of freight car, the Commission shall give consideration to the national level of ownership of such type of freight car and to other factors affecting the adequacy of the national freight car supply, and shall, on the basis of such consideration, determine whether compensation should be computed solely on the basis of elements of ownership expense involved in owning and maintaining such type of freight car, including a fair return on value, or whether such compensation should be increased by such incentive element or elements of compensation as in the Commission’s judgment will provide just and reasonable compensation to freight car owners, contribute to sound car service practices (including efficient utilization and distribution of cars), and encourage the acquisition and maintenance of a car supply adequate to meet the needs of commerce and the national defense. The Commission shall not make any incentive element applicable to any type of freight car the supply of which the Commission finds to be adequate and may exempt from the compensation to be paid by any group of carriers such incentive element or elements if the Commission finds it to be in the national interest.
49 U.S.C. § l(14)(a) (1970). This section was amended in 1976, Rail Reorganization Act Amendments of 1976, Pub.L.No.94-210, § 212(a), 90 Stat. 46-47 (1976). The present text of this section is set out in the majority opinion at page 5, 567 F.2d at 66. Except as noted in Part IV infra, the 1976 amendment has no bearing on this case.
. See generally Chicago, B. & Q. R. Co. v. New York, S. & W. R.R., 332 ICC 176, 183-185 (1968) (hereinafter Per Diem Report), aff’d, sub nom. Union Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 300 F.Supp. 318 (D.Neb.) (three-judge court), aff’d, sub nom. Boston & Maine R.R. v. United States, 396 U.S. 27, 90 S.Ct. 196, 24 L.Ed.2d 142 (1969).
. Per diem payments are made to the owning line even if it does not participate in a car’s interline movement.
. See Per Diem Report, supra note 7, 332 ICC at 186.
. Section l(14)(a) gives the Commission authority to establish reasonable rules affecting car service. See note 6 supra. This authority has recently been exercised to promulgate rules governing the return of cars. See 49 C.F.R. §§ 1033.0-1033.19 (1976); United States v. Allegheny-Ludlum Steel Corp., supra note 3.
. See Hearings on S. 179 and S. 1098 Before the Freight Car Storage Subcommittee, Committee on Commerce, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 12 (1965) (statement of Charles A. Webb, ICC Chairman).
. See note 17 infra.
. See text at note 11 supra.
. See Hearings, supra note 11, at 33 (statement of ICC Chairman Webb).
. Increased Per Diem Charge on Freight Cars, 268 ICC 659, 662-663 (1947), vacated, Palmer v. United States, 75 F.Supp. 63 (D.D.C.1947) (three-judge court).
. See id. at 661, 674.
. The legislative history of the 1966 amendment to § 1(14) (a) reveals that the difficulties with the use of incentive per diem as a tool to enhance car utilization and ownership still re
[T]he per diem charge applies every day a foreign car is on a railroad. It applies whether the car is moving as expeditiously as possible, or is standing still; whether it is in the hands of a consignee for unloading, of a shipper for loading, or is under control of the railroad; whether it is awaiting bottoms for export or is being held by the railroad for expected freight. * * *
* * * [P]er diem * * * has no relation to avoidable delay or to inefficiency. It is payable for every day a foreign car is on the line. * * * The per diem charge, in so far as it penalizes, penalizes use and non-use, efficient and inefficient use, unavoidable and avoidable delays, alike. It would be deemed arbitrary as a regulatory measure under the established rules of law.
But the decisive consideration is the essential nature of the thing which is proposed to be done here. The car situation involves conflicting economic interests of considerable moment. There is the conflict between the great trunk lines, which are organized and able to own large numbers of cars, and the smaller and shortline roads, unable or unequipped to own .many cars. * * * There is also the conflict between a car owner’s interests in restricting its cars to its own lines for its own purposes, and the general interest of the nation in through traffic, with its necessary free interchange of cars. There is the conflict between the economic waste of moving large numbers of empty cars from the unloading areas back to the proprietary lines at certain periods of the year, and the economic efficiency of using unloaded foreign cars for the immediate movement of freight awaiting shipment at the points of unloading. The Commission has insisted that the extensive movement of empty cars is an economic waste to be avoided.
The Commission does not propose by the pending order to solve these problems by regulations directly addressed to them, but actually the order cuts across all these complex difficulties. If the order results in the prompt return of emptied foreign cars to the owners, regardless of available freight in that direction, it will decide the economic balance between movement of empties and the movement of freight in favor of the former. If the order does not cause hiring roads to release the cars, it will merely transfer tremendous sums of money from non-owners to owners, making the economic status of many non-owners difficult, if not unbearable. * * *
Palmer v. United States, supra note 15, 75 F.Supp. at 67, 68-69.
. See ICC, Sixty-Fourth Annual Report 128 (1950). The Commission’s legislative recommendation was repeated in every Annual Report through 1966.
. 49 U.S.C. § 1(15) (1970).
. S. 1789, 86th Cong., 1st Sess., printed in S.Rep.No.452, 86th Cong., 1st Sess. 11 (1959).
. The Senate took the position that the measures proposed under § 1(15) were too punitive, and it therefore rejected that approach in favor of the incentive approach. See S.Rep.No.452, supra note 20, at 6-7. In the first ICC Annual Report following this Senate action, the legislative recommendation to amend § 1(15) was dropped without comment. See ICC, Seventy-Fourth Annual Report 183-184 (1960).
. Pub.L.No.89-430, 89th Cong., 2d Sess. § 1, 80 Stat. 168 (1966).
. See United States v. Florida East Coast R. Co., supra note 3, 410 U.S. at 232-233, 93 S.Ct. 810.
. See Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968, 350 ICC 464 (1975).
. The record does not support GMI’s allegation, however. Although other participants before the Commission made allegations similar to that of GMI, no proponent of this view supplied any data to support its position. The only data in the record shows that XF car stocks increased throughout the period when IPD was applied to XM cars. See comments of Erie Lackawanna Railroad, JA 20-21 (317 cars upgraded to XF status during this period); comments of Union Pacific Railroad, JA 104 (96 cars upgraded to XF status during this period).
. I agree with the majority that, were we to hold today that IPD could not be imposed except on a record of shipper complaints, important interests such as that in sanitary food would be put at risk since there is no reason to suppose that the interests of shippers and of the public will necessary coincide. However, I find it at least troubling, as the majority apparently does not, that the record here is completely devoid of evidence of shipper complaints since the moving parties in this proceeding have been GMI and the Grocery Manufacturers’ Association, both groups which would be in a position to know of shipper complaints.
'I agree with Conrail that the Commission has departed from contemporaneously announced standards of proof with respect to statistical evidence of car shortages. See, e. g., Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968, 349 ICC 303, 311 (1975); Incentive Per Diem Charges — Gondolas, 40 Fed.Reg. 44851, 44851-44852 (1975). This departure is not unexplained, however. The Commission has stated that creation of the XF car classification only one year before its inquiry into imposition of IPD prevented creation of an elaborate statistical record of shortages. Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968 (XF Cars), 350 ICC 11, 17 (1975) (hereinafter XF Report). Conrail does not appear to challenge this statement and has cited no authority which would require the Commission to defer action on IPD until adequate statistics can be generated. Therefore, it appears that the Commission was acting within its permitted discretion when it chose to examine the shortage question on the basis of whatever record could be generated given the relative newness of the XF classification.
. Comments of GMI, Exhibit 17, at 9, JA 68 (verified statement of Daniel G. McPherson, GMI vice-president).
. Id, Exhibit 16, at 9, JA 53 (verified statement of William K. Smith, GMI vice-president for transportation).
. XP cars were used for food transportation prior to creation of the XF designation. See p. 13 supra, 567 F.2d at 72. At the time of the Commission’s report there were 2,495 XF cars and 29,075 XP cars. XF Report, supra note 26, 350 ICC at 17.
. Conrail has not challenged the figures in text; however, it has challenged the inference which should be drawn from them, noting particularly that William K. Smith, GMI’s vice-president for transportation and apparently the person whose testimony launched the XF proceeding, did not conclude from these figures that IPD was needed on XF cars except to prevent reclassification of XF cars to XM. Were such reclassifications prevented, GMI would apparently have been satisfied and would not have pressed for IPD simply to increase the size of the XF car fleet. See Comments of GMI, JA 35. As has already been noted, see note 25 supra, there is no evidence that GMI’s fears of losing its XF fleet were well founded. To the contrary, the record so far as it shows anything indicates that railroads serving food shippers were ready and able to supply the needed cars. See Comments of Grand Trunk Western, JA 6 (“The Grand Trunk Western Railroad Company plans to expand the use of ‘XF’ box cars for use by the cereal industries over our lines.”); Comments of Erie Lackawan-na, JA 20-21 (“This company knows of no facts which would lead us to the conclusion that there is a national shortage of XF cars. * * * Erie Lackawanna has upgraded some 317 box cars between December 1973 and August 1974 at great expense to create.the status of an XF car * * *.”); Comments of Union Pacific, JA 104 (“Union Pacific, when approached by food processing companies, has satisfied all specific requests for the provision of [XF] cars.”); Comments of Florida East Coast, JA 127 (“[A] survey during the month of July 1974 shows that FEC had a surplus of XF cars on line.”).
. Comments of GMI, Exhibit 16, at 7, JA 51. The Commission reported that GMI also used XL cars. Environmental Threshold Assessment Survey, JA 155.
. In assigned service, cars are restricted as to the use terminating roads may make of them. Assigned service is discussed at length below. See text at notes 41-52 infra.
. See note 41 infra.
. See Notice of Proposed Rulemaking and Order, JA 2.
. See, e. g., United States v. Allegheny-Lud-lum Steel Corp., supra note 3.
. See note 6 supra. The language quoted in text was not changed by the 1976 amendments to § l(14)(a). See Pub.L.No. 94-210, § 212(a), 90 Stat. 47 (1976).
. At some point, however, more rapid return of cars could be achieved only by returning an excessive number of empty cars, which would be extremely inefficient. See Hearings, supra note 11, at 33 (statement of ICC Chairman Webb); note 17 supra.
. See Per Diem Report, supra note 7, 332 ICC at 186. The 1976 amendment to § l(14)(a) states the standard for setting basic per diem slightly differently, viz. “fair return on the cost of such type of freight car (giving due consideration to current costs of capital, repairs, materials, parts, and labor).” Pub.L.No. 94-210, § 212(a), 90 Stat. 47 (1976). This, standard does not appear to differ in practical effect from the earlier standard as applied in the Per Diem Report, supra. In any case, at the present time, basic per diem rates continue at levels established with reference to the language of § l(14)(a) adopted in 1966.
. See note 56 infra.
. Hearings on H.R. 2230, H.R. 7165, and. S. 1098 Before the House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 91 (1965) (testimony of general counsel for Burlington Lines).
. Car Service Directive 155 provides in relevant part:
NOTICE:
This Directive is issued under provisions of paragraph (g), Car Hire Rule 19. Each violation of Section A.2., or Section B.2. of this Directive is subject to an assessment of one hundred dollars ($100.00).
APPLICATION:
To box cars AAR mechanical designation XF, carrying railroad reporting marks.
ORDER:
SECTION A. Cars Assigned to Shipper or Pool Points.
1. Waybills accompanying assigned cars under load must be endorsed “Assigned Car For Processed Packaged Food Loading CSD No. 155.”
2. After unloading, such cars must be returned empty to assigned loading point via reverse of loaded movement.
3. Such empty return must be on standard form waybills without charges which shall be endorsed “Assigned Car For Processed Packaged Food Loading CSD No. 155.”
SECTION B. Unassigned Cars.
1. Waybills accompanying unassigned cars under load must be endorsed “Unassigned Car For Processed Packaged Food Loading CSD No. 155.”
2. After unloading, cars subject to this Directive must be handled either per owner’s instructions or returned empty to the owner or loaded to or via the owner, the holding road to exercise the option.
SECTION C.
XF cars are restricted to processed packaged food loading only except, with the approval of owner, such cars may be used for loading other non-contaminating products enclosed in clean packaging. Cars must not be used for the loading of bulk commodities. If cars are used for loading which results in contamination or damage to linings or floors, and it becomes necessary to renew floors, lining or sheathing (including any associated parts), or portions thereof, in order to restore cars to previous loading classification, the cost of*78 repairs shall be assumed by the road (either switching or road haul) placing cars for loading.
NOTE: Carriers may exempt their cars from the provisions of Section A.2. or B.2. • to allow use by other specified lines for loading as prescribed in Section C. Such exemptions must be confirmed in writing to the Car Service Division in advance.
. The record does not indicate how many XF cars have been placed in assigned service and how many in unassigned service. The comments of many parties indicating that assignment was critical to the effectiveness of the XF car as a food carrier would indicate that few if any XF cars ever operated in unassigned service. See XF Report, supra note 26, 350 ICC at 15. The Commission also states that XF cars are operated in assigned service and does not even mention the possibility that they might be free-running. Id. at 13.
. Even if XF cars have been operated in unassigned service, Directive 155, § B(2), allows the owner of aij XF car to specify how it will be moved after unloading. See note 41 supra. The only evidence in the record suggests that an owner’s directions for further movement have generally been followed and that carriers and shippers have been cooperating to ensure proper car use. See comments of GMI, Exhibit 16, at 9, JA 53.
. See Directive 155, § A(2), supra note 41. The “NOTE” to Directive 155 allows carriers to direct that their cars be loaded on foreign lines. See note 41 supra. Some roads have apparently made use of this provision to allow shipper-assignees to make loaded return movements. See comments of General Foods Corp., JA 146-147.
. See note 41 supra.
. Although Congress required the Commission to find that cars were in inadequate supply before IPD could be imposed, the finding of a car shortage does not itself indicate anything about the reasons for the shortage. And, while it is clear that Congress was legislating against an assumed state of facts in which car shortages could in some cases be ascribed to disincentives to car ownership caused by abuse of car service rules, the legislative history is quite plain that no one thought that car shortages necessarily implied an abuse of car service rules or that such an abuse was the sole cause of car shortages. The House report summarized the situation as follows:
There have been all sorts of conflicting statements made as to the reasons for the shortages as to whether they arise from lack of adequate ownership, or from improper distribution of the existing car fleet, or from overdetention by the shippers in unloading, or from the prevailing 5-day as against the 6-day week * * *.
******
The record of the hearings which have been had on this bill is similar to the records which have been had on previous bills and is not conclusive as to whether “incentive” per diem will be successful in achieving the goal which we are seeking, namely, the alleviation of these chronic shortages.
Therefore, inasmuch as some railroads feel that this might be of great help to the situation and inasmuch as the Interstate Commerce Commission is of the belief that with this authorization it can do something in the matter and inasmuch as no alternative has been brought to the attention of the committee, the committee is recommending that this bill be enacted.
H.R.Rep.No.1183, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 2-3 (1965), U.S.Code Cong. & Admin.News 1966, p. 2228. The Commission has also required proof of the existence of disincentives to car ownership arising from car service practices. See text at notes 59-60 infra.
. See comments of GMI, Exhibit 16, at 9, JA 53.
. XF Report, supra note 26, 350 ICC at 18.
. Inadequacies in XF car supply may be attributable to low tariffs on processed food products. See comments on behalf of the Trustees of Penn Central Transportation Co., JA 92:
. See comments of GMI, Exhibit 16, at 9, JA 53; comments of General Foods Corp., JA 146.
. Comments of Grand Trunk Western Railroad, JA 6.
. “[The amendments of Directive 155] will preserve to the railroads full control of their cars.” XF Report, supra note 26, 350 ICC at 19.
. See note 17 supra.
. This could occur in either of two ways. First, the earmarking requirements set out in 49 C.F.R. § 1036.3 (1976) will require any net IPD balances on XF cars to be used for new car construction, although not necessarily for construction of XF cars, see id § 1036.4. Second, under § 1036.4, funds which are earmarked can be used to construct any of the types of cars to which IPD applies. Thus it is conceivable that funds arising from XM car use could be applied to XF car construction (and vice versa). This use of funds raises problems, however. In Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968, supra note 26, the Commission stated:
[T]he main benefit from investing incentive per diem funds in an expanded covered hopper fleet would accrue to the grain shippers. This is contrary to the broader basis specified in section l(14)(a) of the act for imposition of incentive per diem, namely consideration of “factors affecting the adequacy of the national freight car supply”. Therefore, we believe that incentive funds should only be used for purchase of plain boxcars, in order to benefit shippers generally and not a particular segment of the shipping public.
349 ICC at 311 (emphasis added). How XF cars — which are restricted to food shippers, a class undoubtedly no larger than grain shippers — would “benefit shippers generally” if covered hoppers do not is by no means apparent.
. See Hearings, supra note 11, at 12, 14, 35.
. The Commission’s theory is nowhere spelled out with detail or clarity. In its Seventy-First Annual Report, in which promulgation of a rule under § l(14)(a) was first endorsed, the Commission stated:
The two principal causes of shortages are inadequate car ownership and the failure of some carriers to utilize existing equipment efficiently. One way of correcting this unsatisfactory situation is the imposition of a penalty per diem charge [under § 1(15)] which would furnish a pecuniary spur to deficit railroads to acquire enough cars to meet their own loading obligations. Another approach to the problem * * * is the requirement that the earning power or the value of the use of the vehicle which is lost by the owner when used or appropriated by*81 other carriers, be included as a factor by the Commission in determining the per diem charge. This would eliminate the owner’s loss, the user’s gain, and provide an incentive for increased car ownership.
ICC, Seventy-First Annual Report 137 (1957). The language of the bill proposed by the Commission closely parallels this explanation, see S.Rep.No.386, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. 2 (1965), and ICC Chairman Webb appeared to endorse this explanation of the phrase “just and reasonable compensation” when he testified:
[T]he bill [would] raise the per diem charge so as to return some profit to the owner of the car and thereby encourage an increase in car supply.
Hearings, supra note 11, at 35 (emphasis added). The “use value” or the profit to be “returned” would apparently be a value proportional to the net revenue which the non-owning user had gained through “appropriation” of a foreign car. An extended explanation of the function of per diem given by the general counsel of Burlington Lines, the major proponent of IPD, corroborates this view. See generally Hearings, supra note 11, at 140-142; Hearings, supra note 40, at 91. Presumably any level of per diem above basic per diem would provide incentives to chronic borrower roads to buy cars since, with ownership costs approximately equal to basic per diem, more net revenue would be returned if an owned car was used wherever possible. The opposite side of this proposition is that creditor roads would have financial incentives to invest more heavily in cars if the debtors did not increase their fleets since the total return to car ownership would be increased. In the XF proceeding, however, while owners of XF cars would undoubtedly enjoy increased returns, there is no evidence that XF debtors are making any revenue through appropriation of XF cars unless the word “appropriation” is tortured to apply to the period in which XF debtors are fulfilling their statutory obligation to terminate XF shipments. Thus the “use value” of which XF owners are deprived is zero, and the incentive per diem should similarly be zero.
. House members were fond of repeating variants of the phrase “under present per diem rules, it is cheaper to rent a car than to own one.” See, e.g., pp. 22-23 supra, 567 F.2d at 76. This apparently referred to a belief that per diem rates were “barebones” rates which did not really cover the costs associated with freight car ownership. While this may or may not have been the case, it seems clear that no amendment to § l(14)(a) was needed to authorize the Commission to establish reasonable, compensatory per diem rates. Palmer v. United States, supra note 15, is not to the contrary since that case treated the issue as whether the Commission had
power to fix compensation for the use of cars as a regulatory measure, solely for the purpose of increasing efficiency in the use of cars and at an amount wholly independent of the costs of car ownership, expenses of maintenance and operation, and a reasonable profit.
75 F.Supp. at 66 (emphasis added). The issue of whether the increase was justifiable as compensation was not before the court. Id. at 76. Moreover, Rep. Staggers, in explaining the House amendment, which expressly defined basic per diem to include “a fair return on value,” stated that this language was merely a restatement “in clear language of what the courts have held to be the limitations of the law as it is now written.” 112 Cong.Rec. 10435 (1966). See also Hearings, supra note 40, at 52 (testimony of ICC Chairman Webb) (“Oh, we have that authority [to fix a compensatory per diem rate] at the present time, and we have always had it.”). If the only purpose of the amendment was to force the Commission to set per diems to include a fair return on value, then the Commission has already done this, see Per Diem Report, supra note 7, at 211-214, and any additional increment of compensation for XF car owners would appear a fortiori to be excessive.
. I. e., such roads, by virtue of being net per diem debtors, would routinely be using other roads’ cars, thereby depriving them of revenue. If the purpose of IPD was simply to increase the return on car owners’ investment, then no such exemption would be required and, indeed, such an exemption would be counterproductive.
. “The construction of a statute by those charged with its execution” is an important factor to be considered in divining the meaning of a statute. Red Lion Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 395 U.S. 367, 381, 89 S.Ct. 1794, 1802, 23 L.Ed.2d 371 (1969). This is especially so here, where the legislation was proposed by the agency charged with its execution and where the legislative history indicates that Congress had no strong views on the efficacy of the approach suggested, but merely wanted to ensure that the Palmer case presented no barrier to Commission experimentation. See H.R.Rep. No.1183, supra note 46, at 2-3.
. The Commission’s initial proposal to amend § (15) also indicates that the Commission conceived of IPD as an adjunct to emergency powers intended to get cars moving more quickly in times of short-term emergency.
. Incentive Per Diem Charges, 332 ICC 11 (1967); Incentive Per Diem Charges — 1968, 337 ICC 183 (1969) (interim report); id., 337 ICC 217 (1970) (further report).
. The findings of this report were affirmed in ' United States v. Allegheny-Ludlum Steel Corp., supra note 3.
. See Palmer v. United States, supra note 15, 75 F.Supp. at 66.
. See notes 17 & 27 supra.
. Commission counsel apparently does not disagree with the legislative history adumbrated above, since he explains that § l(14)(a) is a response to shortages “largely attributable to the national car-pool system.” ICC br. at 3. Nonetheless, counsel does not point to any evidence in the administrative record which would indicate that the disincentives to ownership present in the car-pool system have affected the supply of XF cars.
. In my judgment, the procedures adopted by the Commission in this proceeding are seriously deficient and contrary to both the hearing requirement of § l(14)(a) of the Interstate Commerce Act and the common law of this circuit. The Commission’s notice of proposed rulemaking failed to disclose the data upon which it was based and, when this material
I am not sure whether the procedural errors I perceive in this proceeding require reversal in the special circumstances of this case, since the parties have expressly waived all’ procedural objections and consequently have not focused on the actual harm which may have resulted from these deficiencies. However, I think the Commission should be aware that procedures in rulemaking are for the benefit of the public as well as the parties and accordingly cannot be shielded from appellate review by waiver. Therefore, should a proceeding marred with similar errors come before this court in the future, I would not be hesitant to reverse the Commission.