56 N.Y.S. 588 | N.Y. App. Div. | 1899
The contract which is the subject of this action was reviewed by the appellate division in the First department upon a demurrer interposed to the plaintiff’s complaint; and the court held, in affirmance of the court at special term, that it did not appear upon the face of the contract that it was illegal as being in
“The obtaining by dealers of a fair and reasonable price for what they sell does not seem to contravene public policy, or to work an injury to individuals. On the contrary, the general interests are promoted by activity in trade, which cannot permanently exist without reasonable encouragement to those engaged in it. Producers, consumers, and laborers are alike benefited by healthful conditions of business.”
The distinction between the two classes of contracts is admirably stated by Judge Gray in Leslie v. Lorillard, 110 N. Y. 519, 533, 18 N. E. 366, where the learned judge says:
“When, therefore, the provisions of agreements in restraint of competition tend beyond measures for selfrproteetion, and threaten the public good in a distinctly appreciable manner, they should not be sustained. The apprehension of danger to the public interests, however, should rest on evident grounds, and courts should refrain from the exercise of their equitable powers in interfering with and restraining the conduct of the affairs of individuals or of corporations, unless their conduct, in some tangible form, threatens the welfare of the public.”
We have already seen that the contract, upon its face, does not merit condemnation. Has the testimony in the case aided to that end? It appeared upon the trial (at least, for all purposes essential to support the verdict of the jury) that the business in which the plaintiff was engaged had fallen to a low ebb. To use the language of one of the witnesses for the defendants:
“Tlie competition in the wholesale trate was very close and severe. Goods were being sold in New York by Eastern manufacturers less than could be produced by New York manufacturers. Goods were sold in Philadelphia and in other places less than they could be produced and make a profit by the local manufacturers.”
And he further stated that the trade was in such a demoralized condition that it was a question of bankruptcy or combination with many of them; that goods were selling below tvliat it cost to produce them, and that the formation of the Standard Envelope Company was necessary as a measure of protection against ruinous competition; that the purpose of the agreement was to give the people engaged in the business a living profit, and was not to strangle competition, or enhance prices beyond a point where a fair manufacturer’s profit could be obtained; that at this time there were plenty of people engaged in this business who were not related to the Standard Envelope Company, either by contract or otherwise, but were in competition with it, and could keep the price within the range of fair dealing. In this connection it appeared that there were 19 other concerns doing business in various parts of the country that were more or less in competition with the parties to this contract. It is true that some of the witnesses for the defendants stated that the contracting parties did not regard these people as competitors, but it is equally true that the character of the business carried on by them showed that they were all more or less competitors, and some of them were shown to be substantial. There was substantive testimony, therefore, to show that the purpose of the contract was not to stifle competition or to unduly increase prices, and the conditions were such that the operation of the contract could not produce, in an appreciable degree, injury to the public. At least, the jury were authorized so to find.
It is insisted that the clause of the contract whereby the plaintiff was to furnish 250,000 envelopes daily was not a sale, and was not intended to be, and, as the proof shows that no envelopes were delivered under it, it is conclusive of such fact. It is apparent that the
The argument of the learned counsel for the defendants proceeds upon the theory that the contract is void upon its face. We do not
It was stated upon the argument that the plaintiff was required by the defendants to enter into this contract as a measure of protection for his own business against the further ruinous competition which would have been waged against him by the defendants. If this be so, the defendants cannot call upon the courts to strain rules for their protection when they are sought to be held accountable for what they have produced. In such cases it may be that the parties do not stand in pari delicto. The borrower at usury was never regarded as occupying that relation to the lender. And so, where there is oppression upon one side and necessary submission upon the other, such relation does not exist. “When one holds the rod, and the other bows to it,” the holder cannot be heard to say that the contract thus forced is illegal. Broom, Leg. Max. (8th Ed.) 724. The record, however, does not clearly establish such relation, and we are therefore not called upon to say what the rule would be in such a case.
If our views be correct, it follows that the judgment should be affirmed.
Judgment and order affirmed, with costs. All concur.