Campbell v. Macomb

4 Johns. Ch. 534 | New York Court of Chancery | 1820

The Chancellor.

The sale of the whole of the mortgaged premises was indispensable in this case, because they were not capable of being sold in parcels, or of being divided, without manifest injury to all the parties concerned. When the whole premises are thus necessarily sold, it is the direction of the statute, (1 N. R. L. 490.) that the Court apply the proceeds of the sale not only in payment of the interest, instalment, or portion due, but towards payment of the whole, or residue of the demand, which hath not become due, or payable, provided the same bears interest. But this provision is made for the necessity of the case, and more than is due is not to be' raised out of the mortgaged premises, when that necessity does not exist. If the mortgagor; or the party holding the equity of redemption, comes before the sale, and brings in the amount due, with costs, there is • no justice or equity in suffering the sale to proceed. It has been the practice of the Court, since I have sat here, to stay the sale in such cases, and to let the decree of foreclosure remain good to enforce payment of the future interest and instalments, as they may respectively become due. When such an application was made, before answer, in Lansing v. Capron, (1 Johns. Ch. Rep. 617.) I required, as a condition of the rule, a decree of foreclosure to be entered by way of security, and to save the trouble and expense of a new suit; but this is the utmost length to which any proceeding in the cause has been carried, after payment of the amount due, with the costs.

Though there be a regular decree of sale in this casé, there can be no doubt of an adequate power in the Court, in its discretion, to regulate the process of execution under ' the decree. To sell, after satisfaction of the decree, would *537be gross abuse; and the whole inducement to the sale is to obtain satisfaction of the sum actually due. The object of v v the decree was not to raise any part of the debt not due; , . . /> , *ii i yet, the raising oi the entire debt may become an unavoidable consequence of the sale, because, the Court, in order to raise what is due, is obliged to sell the whole of the mortgaged premises, as they happen to consist of one entire subject, incapable of being conveniently, or safely divided. If this necessity can be avoided, before the sale, by the voluntary payment of what is due, the present object of the decree is satisfied, and all that the party can, in conscience, require, is, that it may remain as a security, for subsequent defaults, and afford him an easy and prompt remedy, when they occur.

A Court of law, after judgment and execution for the entire debt, will relieve the defendant, on paying the instalment due, but will retain the judgment as a security for the future instalments. (Judd v. Evans, 6 Term, Rep. 399.) This is an equitable construction of the statute of 4 Anne ; and surely this Court will not turn a deaf ear to the equity of the case, and adopt a more than common law rigour.

But the petition states, that the petitioner is not only a mortgagee in trust, but a surety for the mortgagor, and that the mortgaged premises are in a state of injury and decay, from the action of storms, and have thereby become a precarious security. I do not perceive that this circumstance gives him any right or title, in equity, to have the premises sold for a debt not due. The security was taken with knowledge of the situation and character of the property, and of the risks to which it was exposed. It does not belong to the Court to give a party better security than he elected to take, where there has been no fraud or mistake, nor any abuse or waste of the subject. I am not informed that there exists any precedent of a bill quia timet,- adapted to such a case.

*538All the cases in the English law, in which even a surety may file a bill quia timet, are those in which the debt ivas due from the principal debtor; and I do not know of any principle of equity that will justify us in giving aid to the surety, before the debt is due, when the parties have not provided, in their contract, for such a case.

The question on this subject, so often raised in the civil law, assumed the fact, that the principal debtor was in default ; Si diu in solutione reus cessavit; and when it is added, aut eerie bona sua dissipavit, the reference was still to the case in which the debtor had failed to pay, and was, also, wasting his goods. I apprehend, this must be the true con-, stvuction; for the only question raised by Marcellus, in the text referred to, (Dig. 17. 1. 38. 1.) was, whether the surety could seek indemnity before he had himself paid, fide jussor an et prius, quam solvat, agere possit, ut liberetur ? It was a very equitable provision in the civil law, to afford a remedy to the surety when the debtor neglected to pay, though the creditor had not required payment, and though the surety had not actually ádvanced the debt; but it would not have been very just to have 'given the surety an action for indemnity against the debtor, before the latter was in default, and when such a previous claim made no part of the original contract. The debtor, as the civil law truly observes, in another place, (Dig. lib. 17. 1. 22. 1.) has an interest not to be compelled to pay before the day ; and yet, I perceive, that several writers on the civil law (Domat. part 1. b. 3. tit. 4. sec. 3. n. 3. Wood’s Institutes of the Civil Law, p.227. Brown’s Lectures on the Civil Law, vol. L 362.) (a) refer to this very text to prove, that if the surety be *539in peril, he may sue before the time of payment, to be indemnified or discharged. It may be so, but these writers refer to no other text but that already cited, and that certainly does not, by any necessary interpretation, warrant the doctrine. Indeed, it seems to preclude it, because the remedy was intended, or provided, (and so it is expressed,) especially for the case of a surety who could not conveniently discharge the debt himself, and have his regular recourse over, at once, by the action of mandatum. It was a benevolent provision, in that view, and just in no other. In other *540parts of the Pandects, (Dig. 17. 1. 22. 1. and 46. 1. 31.) Paul and Ulpian lay down a rule, in respect to sureties, in perfect accordance with the construction I have ventured to adopt, for they say, that if the surety pays before the day, he cannot have recourse over to the debtor until the day of payment has arrived. A number of civilians who have very fully discussed the rights and remedies of sureties under the civil law, and always with this text of Marcellus in view, give us no intimation of such a doctrine. The general rule of the civil law was, that the action by the surety against his principal, depended upon his having paid the creditor, (Inst. 3. 21. 6. and Ferriere’s Inst. h. t.j and the cases in which he might have recourse over, before payment, were all special cases, as where judgment had already passed against the surety, or the debtor was in failing circumstances, or such a recourse over was part of the original contract, or the debtor had neglected a long time, as from three to ten years, to pay, or the creditor to demand. In all these excepted cases, the surety might sue the debtor for his indemnity or discharge; but when might he sue him ? Not before the debt was due and payable to the creditor, but before the surety had paid the creditor. The authorities to which I now refer, (Hub. Prœlec. lib. 3. tit. 21. De Fide Jussoribus, 11. Voet ad Pand. lib. 46. tit. 1. 34. Pothier, Trait, des Oblig. n. 441. Ersk. Inst. b. 3. c. 65.) all consider these exceptions as only providing for the relief of the surety, ante solutionem. He may sue the principal debt- or before he has actually paid the debt, and the exceptions were to relieve him from that burden, for without one of these special causes, says the Code, there would be no foundation, before payment, for the action of mandatum. (Nulla juris ratione, antequam satis creditori pro ea feceris, eum ad solutionem urgeri cerium est. Code 4. 35.10.) This plain and equitable principle, that until the debtor is in default, either in his contract with the creditor, or in his contract *541with the surety, he is not bound to pay or indemnify, seems to pervade equally every part of the civil law.

Pothier says, (ubi sup. n. 442.) that if the obligation to which the surety has acceded, must, from its nature, exist a long time, as if he was surety for the due execution of a trust, he cannot, within the time, sue the principal debtor or trustee for his discharge, for Tie knew, or ought to have known, the nature of the obligation he contracted. Though where he is surety, indefinitely, as for payment of an annuity, he may, after a long time, as, say ten years, demand that the principal debtor liberate him, by redeeming the annuity.

I cannot make it a condition of the order, staying the sale, that the defendant should repair the dam. This would be a very extraordinary and dangerous interference with the exeicise of the rights of a mortgagor, and is, in practice, unknown. Suppose, the most valuable part of the mortgaged premises should consist of buildings, and they should accidentally be destroyed by fire, can the mortgagor be compelled immediately to rebuild ? Is it not rather incumbent on the mortgagee, or the surety, to provide for such a case in the contract, or by insurance ? It would bring distress and ruin on a mortgagor, to charge him with burdens and duties, not within the contemplation of his contract, and, therefore, not within his provident foresight. How far the Court could, or ought to interfere, in a case of negligent, or permissive waste, rapidly impairing the security, is a question which need not now be discussed; for the relief, if any, would not be by directing the mortgaged premises to be sold for a debt not due, or, under a decree of sale, te. give an order to repair, or a reference to assess damages, The necessity of any interference, of any kind, in cases of mortgages, is exceedingly diminished by the consideration, that the mortgagee can, if he pleases, relieve himself, by obtaining possession of the land, and make, at his own expense, the requisite repairs, for which he would be allow*542ed, in account, when the mortgagor came to redeem. It is, also, stated, in this case, that the present owner of the equi- ^ re(lemption is in the act of repairing the dam ; and it is so evidently his interest to do it, and his payment of the interest due on the mortgage, together with the costs, is such decisive evidence, that the property is considered to be worth more than the debt charged thereon, that I should infer there was little or no foundation for the alarm discovered, in the petition.

Motion denied, with costs.

There must be some misapprehension of the meaning of the text, or the part of these writers, or the opinion of Marcellus, (Dig. lib. 17. tit. 1. 38.) to which they refer, is irreconcilable with principles laid down in. other parts of the Digest. In the case stated in the text, Tiiius was part owner of a house, which, by his consent, was mortgaged to the creditor of his natural son Mavius. Mavius died, and the question which *539arose between Titius and the guardians of the orphan child of Mamitis,. was, whether the part of the house so pledged, could be exonerated; there being, as it would seem, no time fixed, by the agreement of the parties, for that purpose. “ It is not unlike,” says Marcellus, “ the question so frequently agitated, whether a surety, even before he has paid the debt, can demand to be discharged ? He is not obliged,” he answers, to wait until he has paid the debt, or a judgment is given against him, if the debtor has delayed payment a long time, or is wasting his estate ; especially, if the surety has not got the money, by the payment of which, to the creditor, he would be entitled to his action, ex mandato, against the principal.” [JVon absimilis ilia quce frcquentissime agitan solet, fidejussor an et prius, quam solvat, agere possit, ut liberetur ? Nee lamen semper ex-spectandum est, ut solvat, aut judicio aecepto eondemnetur, si diu in solulione reus cessavit, aut eerie bona sua dissipavit: prassertim si domi pecuniam fidejus.sor non habebit, qua numerata creditori mandati aclione convenial.] Marcellus either refers to the case where no day of payment is fixed, and then it is an exception to the general rule, and left to the discretion of the Judge, to be decided according to the circumstances of the case, or to a case where the day of payment was passed; otherwise, the surety, by'paying the debt, could not have an action ex mandato, against his principal; for, until the surety has paid, and the principal is in default, the implied or quasi contract, ex mandato, could not arise between them. If the creditor cannot sue the debtor before the day of payment, the surety, whose obligation is accessary merely, can have no better right. Accordingly, Javolenus says, (Dig. 17.1. 51.) though the surety, by mistake, pays the money before the day, he can neither have an action to recover it back, nor an action ex mandato, against the debtor, before the day of payment arrives.” [Fidejussor, quamvisper errorem ante diem pecuniam solverit, pelero (repetere) lamen ab eo non potest: ac ne mandati quidem actionem ; antequam dies solvendi venial, cum reo habebit.]

the civil Zuro, a surety cannot sue the principal debt- or for his indemnity or discharge, before the term of payment fiven to the ebtor, by his contract with the creditor, has expired; though the suretymay, after the time of payment has elapsed, sue the debtor for his indemnity, in certain case», before he has himself paid the debt.