275 F. 861 | S.D. Ohio | 1921
The President of the United States, acting by the Secretary of the Navy, requisitioned of the plaintiff, under section 10 of the National Defense (Eever) Act of August 10, 1917 (U. 5. Comp. Stat. 1918, Comp. St. Ann. Supp. 1919, § 3115%ii), as necessary to the maintenance of the navy, on June 30, 1920, 48.75 gross tons; on July 17, 1920, 3,984 gross tons; on August 20, 1920, 3,003 gross tons; and on September 18, 1920, 1,613 gross tons—of New River run of mine Tunker coal, fixing a price of $4 per gross ton, f. o. b. mines, for the same, which the plaintiff declined to accept. Plaintiff was paid $3 per ton by the government on account, and, in accordance with the provisions of the act, brings this suit to recover “such further sum as, added to said seventy-five per centum, will make up such amount as will be just compensation,” which, it avers, is not less than $5.60 per gross ton, f. o. b. mines. The government answers that just compensation is not $5.60 per ton, but the sum allowed. The action is submitted on the evidence, without the intervention of a jury.
It is not disputed by the government that coal of the grade in question was freely sold in the open market throughout the period covered by the requisitions at prices as high or higher than claimed by the plaintiff. It is the government’s contention, however, that on account of abnormal conditions, resulting from the war and other causes, there was no true or fair market, and no such thing as fair market value; that market value, in and of itself, is not the end to be sought in the present investigation, but that the goal of this proceeding is just compensation ; that where there is no fair market there can be no fair market value; that therefore some other standard must be sought; and that the true measure of just compensation, under the circumstances of this case, is the cost of production, including the expense of operation, maintenance, depreciation, and depletion, plus a just and reasonable profit.
The United States Fuel Administration had relinquished control of prices April 1, 1920. It is true that the market was extremely irregular, and that the price was frequently dictated largely by the buyers’ necessities. Many large dealers, including plaintiff, limited themselves, however, so far as their domestic business was concerned, to prices much below what could have been asked, for the purpose of retaining the good will of their customers for future business, and in view of the provisions of the fourth section of the I,ever Act, 1he unconstitutiouality of which was then not decided, restricting dealers to reasonable prices. Certain so-called priority orders of the Interstate Commerce Commission, by which freight cars were ordered to certain portions of the United States for the purpose of relieving local coal shortages, undoubtedly had a tendency to raise prices at some places and reduce them elsewhere. The demand was abnormal as the immediate aftermath of the war, and the supply was curtailed by labor troubles and car shortages. But, when all has been considered, the fact remains that the total coal output of the country,, some 600,000,000 tons, including about. 35,000.000 tons of the character of that in question, was sold and bought, for the most part, by voluntary transactions, and by persons under no restrictions or necessities, except the restraints of law and the needs that ordinarily impel consumers to buy fuel.
The fact that laws and governmental regulations affect the sale of commodities does not abrogate the settled rule that, market value is just compensation. All transactions in the commercial world are more or less affected by such conditions. Tariffs, transportation regulations, and various legal restraints and restrictions are in constant operation. Neither does the fact that unusual conditions affect the market mean that there is no market or market price. Drouths, floods, commercial panics, crop failures, labor difficulties, and other causes frequently affect markets seriously, but not so as to warrant a court, when assessing compensation consequent upon the exercise of the right of eminent domain, in saying that there is no market. The effects of war may differ in degree, but, so long as a market—that is, a general buying and selling of the commodity—exists, the rule persists.
Of the cases cited by the government that most nearly sustaining its contention is Kountz v. Kirkpatrick & Lyons, 72 Pa. 376, 13 Am. Rep. 687, an action for damages for failure to deliver' oil pursuant to an assigned contract. By the day fixed for delivery an unlawful combination of dealers, including the original purchasing party, but not his assignee, had gained control of the market, and had forced the price up temporarily to a greatly inflated figure. A few days later the price dropped to the' normal. The real plaintiff, for whose benefit the suit was prosecuted, was innocent of this inflation. It was held that-“value” and “market price” are not always convertible terms; that there could be no difference in justice or law between an unnatural depression and an unnatural exaltation in the market price; that neither is the true and only measure of value; that, when the market price is unnaturally inflated by unlawful and fraudulent practices, it cannot be the true means of ascertaining what is unjust compensation. It was concluded (two of the five justices dissenting) that it was a fair question for the juiy to determine whether the price which was demanded for the oil on the delivery day was not a fictitious, unnatural, inflated, and temporary price, the result of a combination to “bull” the market, as it was termed, and to compel sellers to pay a false and swollen price in order to fulfill their contracts.
“If so,” the court said, “then such price was not a fair test of the value of the oil, and the jury would be at liberty to determine, from the prices before and after the day, and from other sources of information, the actual market value of the oil on the 31st of December 1869” (delivery day). “Any other cause [course] would be unjust and injurious to fair dealers, and would enable gamblers in the article to avail themselves of their own wrong, and to wrest from honest dealers the fruits of their business. * * * Men are not to be stripped of their estates by such cruel and wrongful practices, and courts of justice cannot so wholly ignore justice as to assume such a false standard of compensation.”
It is to be noted that even there the court did not abandon the rule of market value, but, for the ascertainment of it, merely justified a departure in evidence from the exact date set for delivery. The plaintiff here does not seek to base its claim upon unusual sales at the precise
In the case of Lovejoy v. Michels, 88 Mich. 15, 49 N. W. 901, 13 L. R. A. 770, cited by the government, the court refused to allow the market value, because prices of the commodity there under consideration were dictated by an association of manufacturers, of which plaintiff was one, and it was held that the price arbitrarily fixed by such a combination was no more evidence of value than a price arbitrarily staled by any vendor for his wares, and not a market value, and therefore the court had recourse to the rule of cost of production plus a reasonable profit. There was, in effect, hut one vendor, dictating the price and attempting to make it the measure of damages in an action at law for the reasonable worth of the goods. No such situation is before the court here.
The subject of market value artificially enhanced is treated by Sedg.wick on Damages, vol. 1, § 249, as a question still undecided, and the author concludes:
“Where, however, the market price of property has been enhanced by such an operation, it will be regarded as the value of the property, at least when the question arises between parties neither of whom has been concerned in the raising of the price. And since value is really measured by the opinion of the public, and that opinion, when expressed in a free market, is the market value, it would seem that, if even for a short time buyers and sellers, unconstrained to act, are willing to pay and to receive a certain price for the commodity, this price is its value, but what one when oonstramed to buy must pay is not necessarily the value.”
The author and the causes cited deal with instances where prices have been artificially advanced by manipulators for the purpose of increasing profit. The evidence discloses no such fact in the instant case. Scarcity of supply and increased demand, resulting from war and labor conditions, cannot be said to constitute artificial enhancement. The effect of the Lever Act was not to increase, but to reduce, prices. There is a distinction between a market controlled by unlawful combination and manipulation, and one that is high and irregular, due to disturbed conditions at home and abroad: The former is the result of activities which were unlawful, and no doubt the same public policy which condemns the conspiracy to control the price rejects the result as a rule of evidence, when offered on behalf of a member of the combination. The latter is the result of circumstances not within control of either purchasers or sellers.
The government calls attention to the language in the opinion of the court in New York v. Sage, 239 U. S. 57, 61, 36 Sup. Ct. 25, 60 L. Ed. 143, where it is stated that—-
*866 “What the owner is entitled to is the value of the property taken, and that ’ means what it may fairly be believed that a purchaser in fair market conditions would have given for it in fact—not what a tribunal at a later date may think a purchaser would have been wise to give, nor a proportion of the advance due to its union with other lots.”
The question under consideration was whether the commissioners, in fixing compensation for property appropriated by the city for reservoir purposes, were justified in adding to the sum allowed for the land and building a further amount "for reservoir availability and adaptability.” No question as to the general condition of fhe real estate market was before the court. The court found that the commissioners had considered the value of the reservoir as a whole and allowed a fair proportion of the increase over and above the market value of the lot. It was held that adaptability for the purposes for which the land could most profitably be used might be considered, but only so far as the public would have considered it if the land had been offered for sale in the absence of the city’s exercise of the power of eminent domain ; also that the city was not to be made to pay for any part of what it had added to the land by uniting it with the lots, if that union would not have been practicable or have been attempted, except by the intervention of eminent domain. The fair market conditions there referred to seem to have been those conditions of availability of the land itself and the title thereto which would have affected its sale to one of the public, as distinguished from those conditions supplied by the city by the very exercise of the right of eminent domain. If, in the instant case, the plaintiff sought to trade upon the necessity of the navy for fuel, and so enhance the price, the case would be directly in point. But it is not so. The plaintiff asks the same price that it received from others in the general market, and not more, but less, than the prevailing market price. There is no evidence to show that the market was affected by the navy’s requirements. It took less than 1,500,000 out of some 35,000,000 of tons produced in the smokeless coal region during the year 1920.
The same consideration shows those cases to be not here pertinent which hold that value to the party taking is not the test, and that enhancement of the price by reason of the obligation of the government to take the property should not be considered in determining a fair price. U. S. v. Chandler-Dunbar Co., 229 U. S. 53-77, 33 Sup. Ct. 667, 57 L. Ed. 1063; McGovern v. New York, 229 U. S. 363, 33 Sup. Ct. 876, 57 L. Ed. 1228, 46 L. R. A. (N. S.) 391; United States v. Seufert Bros. Co. (C. C.) 78 Fed. 520; Sargent v. Merrimac, 196 Mass. 171, 81 N. E. 970, 11 L. R. A. (N. S.) 996, 124 Am. St. Rep. 528; Burger v. State Female Normal School, 114 Va. 491, 77 S. E. 489. It is said that the market was not a fair market. The term “fair market value” does not mean value in a fair market, in the sense of a market in which the supply about equals the demand, and in which conditions might be termed fairly normal, but means fair worth in view of existing market conditions.
Suppose this coal had been requisitioned, not from the producers or the producers’ selling representatives, but from those who had purchased the same upon the open market, as, for instance, retail dealers, operators of coal yards, or the like; would it be said that the measure of just compensation was the cost of production plus a reasonable profit? Or, on the other hand, cost to the dealer from whom it was taken plus a reasonable profit? Assuming part were requisitioned from the producer, and part from the retail dealer, would they he allowed, different rates of compensation? Is the compensation to be determined by who receives it? Just compensation is lor the property, not to the owner. Mr. Justice Brewer in Monongahela Navigation Co. v. United States, 148 U. S. 312, 326, 13 Sup. Ct. 622, 37 L. Ed. 463. It is obviously impossible to depart from the rule of market value with regard to marketable commodities. Value is compensation; money for money’s worth. Any other rule would lead to inequality and confusion.
In United States v. Russell, 13 Wall. 623, 20 L. Ed. 474, it was held that where the. government, in emergencies, takes private property into its use, a contract to reimburse the owner is implied, and that the gov-, ernment is bound to make “full compensation” to the owner. The meaning of the phrase “just compensation,” as used in the Eifth Amendment, is discussed by Mr. Justice Brewer in Monongahela Navigation Co. v. United States, supra:
“The noun ‘compensation,’ standing by itself, carries the idea of an equivalent. * And this is made emphatic by the adjective ‘just.’ There can, in view of the combination of those two words, be no doubt that the compensation must be a full and perfect equivalent for the property taken.”
The compensation must, of course, he just to the public as well as to the owner. Searl v. School District, 133 U. S. 553, 562, 10 Sup. Ct. 374, 33 L. Ed. 740; Bauman v. Ross, 167 U. S. 548, 17 Sup. Ct. 966, 42 L. Ed. 270.
It is therefore concluded that neither the then existing legal regulations, nor the unusual disparity between supply and demand, nor both together, produced a condition which the court is warranted in pronouncing “no market.” The price of $5.60 per gross ton which the plaintiff asks for the coal does not exceed its fair value, in contempla