264 F. 453 | W.D.N.Y. | 1920
Indictments have been returned at this term of court against the above-named complainants, alleging violations of section 2 of the Lever Act as amended October 22, 1919 (41 Stat. 297, c. 80), and separate suits in equity were thereafter brought by certain of the defendants to enjoin the United States attorney from proceeding in the criminal actions pending final hearing. A rule to show cause was granted, which has now been heard; the government appearing and contending for a dismissal of the bill and opposing any stay.
In United States v. Reliable Credit Clothing Company, Incorporated, the defendant has demurred to the indictment. These four cases, involving substantially the same questions as to the validity of the indictment, have been heard together, and a single opinion covering them will suffice. .
Section 2 of the Lever Act, which is an amendment of section 4 of the original Act of August 10, 1917, makes it unlawful for “any person willfully * * * to make any unjust or unreasonable rate or charge in handling or dealing in or with any necessaries,” and the contention of the defendants, who are dealers in wearing apparel, is in the main that this provision of the act is unconstitutional; that it takes property for public use without just compensation, in violation of the Fifth Amendment of the Constitution of the United States; that the indictment is vague and indefinite, and accordingly repugnant to the Sixth Amendment; and, finally, that the President has not fixed a standard of prices to be charged for the articles. These objections are of vital importance.
Defendants earnestly contend that the states cannot regulate prices of necessaries, under the Fourteenth Amendment, in times of peace or in times of war or public peril, and indeed there are decisions, Milligan, Ex parte, 4 Wall. 2, 18 L. Ed. 281, and U. S. v. Freight Association, 166 U. S. 319, 17 Sup. Ct. 540, 41 L. Ed. 1007, for example wherein language is used apparently upholding this view. But, conceding that Congress is “subject to applicable constitutional limitations,” it has nevertheless been decided by the Supreme Court, in Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113, 24 L. Ed. 77, that a state has power to regulate the conduct of its citizens toward each other, and, whenever necessary for the public welfare, it may determine how property in which the public has an interest may be used. It is true the Supreme Court dealt, in the Munn Case, with a warehouse used for storing grain, regarding which the General Assembly of Illinois had enacted a statute providing, among other things, for elevating rates and charges. It was asserted that the statute was void under the Fourteenth Amendment of the national Constitution, but the Supreme Court affirmed the constitutionality of the act passed by the state assembly, and it was firmly held that, whenever the owner of property devotes the same to a use in which the public is interested, he practically grants to the public an interest in such use, and to the extent of that interest he must submit to be controlled by the public for the common good, as long as he maintains the use. The learned court pointed out that it has always been customary—
“to regulate terries, common carriers, hackmen, bakers, millers, wharfingers, innkeepers, etc., and in so doing to fix a maximum of charge to be made for services rendered, accommodations furnished, and articles sold.”
In Budd v. N. Y., 143 U. S. 550, 12 Sup. Ct. 468, 36 L. Ed. 247, the Supreme Court strictly adhered to the doctrine enunciated in the Munn Case, and warehousing was regarded as devoting private property to a public use in the same sense, the learned court said, as did a common carrier, miller, ferryman, innkeeper, wharfinger, baker, cartman, or hackney coachman. In Dueber Watch-Case Manufacturing Co. v. E. Howard Watch & Clock Co., 66 Fed. 637, 14 C. C. A. 14, Judge Eacombe referred to the Munn Case, saying:
*456 “An individual manufacturer or trader may surely buy from or sell to whom be pleases, and may equally refuse to buy from or sell to any one with whom he thinks it will promote his business interests to refuse to trade. That is entirely a matter of his private concern, with which governmental paternalism has not as yet sought to interfere, except when the property he owns is ‘devoted to a use in which the public has an interest’; and such public interest in the use has as yet been found to exist only in staple commodities of prime necessity.”
There is merit in this contention by the government. In Waters-Pierce Oil Co. v. Texas, 212 U. S. 86, 29 Sup. Ct. 220, 53 L. Ed. 417, the Supreme Court had before it the anti-trust statute of Texas, which included the words “reasonably calculated to fix and regulate prices,” and tlie court said the phrase “reasonably calculated” merely implied the commission of an act which tended to accomplish the prohibited thing. -It was there urged that the statute was void for uncertainty, but the court was of opinion that the broad power was not given by the statute to a jury “to determine the criminal character of the act in accordance with their belief as to whether it is reasonable or unreasonable.” The decision, true enough, left it doubtful as to the right of a jury in a criminal case to determine the reasonableness of a charge or rate; but in Nash v. U. S., 229 U. S. 373, 33 Sup. Ct. 780, 57 L. Ed. 1232, which was a criminal case, this doubt was seemingly quieted. It was urged in that case that the statute was vague and indefinite, but Mr. Justice Holmes said:
*457 “But apart from the common law as to restraint of trade thus taken Tip by the statute the law is full of instances, where a man’s fate depends on his estimating rightly, that is, as the jury subsequently estimates it, some matter of degree. * * * ‘A criterion in such cases is to examine whether common social duty would, under the circumstances, have suggested a more circumspect conduct.’ 1 East, P. C. 262.”
Defendants contend, however, that this decision was based on the authority of the Waters-Pierce Oil Co. Case, and that it has no application to a determination by a jury as to the unreasonableness of a rate or charge for a commodity since the provision under consideration has no standard or guide for a merchant making a charge or rate, and his criminality ought not to depend upon a mere belief of the jury. It is pointed out that in the Standard Oil Case, 221 U. S. 1, 31 Sup. Ct. 502, 55 L. Ed. 619, 34 L. R. A. (N. S.) 834, Ann. Cas. 1912D, 734, and the Tobacco Case, 221 U. S. 106, 31 Sup. Ct. 632, 55 L. Ed. 663, the Supreme Court held that there must be a standard involved in the law to determine violations of the Anti-Trust Act (Comp. St. §§ 8820-8823, 8827-8830), and that in such cases the rule of reason fixed by the common law was applied as a standard. In the Nash Case, however, consideration was given to this question, as the excerpt quoted above would seem to show. In International Harvester Co. v. Kentucky, 234 U. S. 216, 34 Sup. Ct. 853, 58 L. Ed. 1284, the Supreme Court reversed the state court, because the state statute offered no standard of conduct by which it was possible to understand in advance whether the price restriction in that case was violated or not. This decision was deemed consistent with the Nash Case, because, as stated in the opinion, the court dealt “with the actual, not with an imaginary, condition other than the facts.”
It is certainly a pertinent inquiry as to whether the case at bar falls within the category of the Nash or International Harvester Cases. I think the weight of authority justified me in holding that it comes within the former, for the reason that in a later case (Miller v. Strahl, 239 U. S. 426, 36 Sup. Ct. 147, 60 L. Ed. 364) the Supreme Court-expressed the view that rules of conduct must necessarily be expressed in general terms, and depend upon varying circumstances. The case concerned a police statute, in which keepers of hotels were required tq give notice to guests in case of fire, and it was held that such a statute was not void for uncertainty in not describing rules of conduct. See, also, Fox v. Washington, 236 U. S. 277, 35 Sup. Ct. 383, 59 L. Ed. 573, Omaechevarria v. Idaho, 246 U. S. 349, 38 Sup. Ct. 323, 62 L. Ed. 763, and Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 258 Fed. 307, 169 C. C. A. 323, as bearing upon the asserted indefiniteness of the act. Candor compels the admission that the objection of uncertainty is not altogether free from doubt, and I am in agreement with Judge Rudkin in U. S. v. Spokane Dry Goods Co. et al., 264 Fed. 209, wherein, in overruling a demurrer to a similar indictment, he said:
“The situation confronting Congress was a difficult one at best. * * * To fix profits definitely and arbitrarily, without reference to place or circum*458 stance, would prove unjust and oppressive in the extreme, for it is matter of common knowledge that what would be deemed just and reasonable in one place or as to one commodity would be unjust and unreasonable in another place or as to a different commodity. Congress was therefore compelled to choose between the course pursued and some other course equally difficult, and the wisdom of its choice cannot be made the subject of judicial inquiry.”
It is therefore held that the indictments are not invalid for uncertainty.
Orders may accordingly be entered in conformity with the views expressed -herein.