141 F.2d 692 | Emer. Ct. App. | 1944
Complainant as the owner and operator of two parking lots in Columbus, Ohio, became subject to the provisions of Maximum Price Regulation No. 165, issued June 23, 1942, and effective July 1, 1942.
Third and Broad Streets
Present Schedule Proposed Schedule
1 hour 170 1 hour 10 minutes 200
2 hours 280 2 hours 10 minutes 300
3 hours 390 3 hours 10 minutes 400
4-12 hours 440 13 hours 450
12-24 hours Theatre } 660 plus 50 each additional hour 25 hours Theatre 700 300 if hours over 2 10 minutes
State and Front Streets
Present Schedule Proposed Schedule
1 hour 170 1 hour 10 minutes 200
2 hours 280 2 hours 10 minutes 300
3 hours 390 3 hours 10 minutes 400
Theatre 250 13 hours 450
25 hours 650
Theatre 300 if hours over 2 10 minutes
The proposed schedules provided for discontinuance of the one hour parking rate of 170 and for substitution in its place of a one hour and ten minute rate of 200. This represents a 17.6% increase in the minimum price and an almost identical percentage increase in the length of time made available to short-time parkers. The proposed schedules would be more expensive to some long-time parkers (for example, 2 hours and 20 minutes would cost 400 under the new schedules and 390 under the old), and less expensive to others (2 hours and 5 minutes would cost 300 under the proposed schedules and 390 under the old). There is no dispute between the parties of the fact that a person desiring to park for one hour or less would have to pay 30 more under the proposed schedules than he pays under the present schedules. Complainant takes the position, however, that there is no actual increase in price embodied in its proposal for the reason that additional time is offered in proportion to the increase in price, the per minute charge remaining the same. Complainant also points to the lower prices which some customers would pay under the proposed schedules.
Since the installation of the proposed schedules would result in higher charges to some parkers, we are of opinion that the Administrator had the right to prevent it. It is immaterial that all parkers at complainant’s lots would not be affected. Small increases of charges in times of threatened inflation have been held to be inconsistent with the purposes of the Act because of their effect when combined with others of the same kind.
Complainant argues that the Administrator’s ruling is inconsistent with a prior interpretation issued by him, in which approval was given to the increasing of prices of commodities up to 20%, so long as there was a proportionate increase in size. The interpretation to which reference is made was rendered in an explanation of the General Maximum Price Regulation. It appeared in question and answer form, as follows:
“Do contents of the same kind, quality and brand or tradename, sold as units of sale in different sizes of containers or packages, constitute the same or different commodities under GMPR? % ijc jji
“Independently of the method of pricing, different sizes put out by the same manufacturer are the same commodity, only more or less of it, in all cases except those in which the new size serves a distinctly different merchandising function * * *. A new size—whether smaller or larger— which is added to a selling line may be priced as a different commodity so long as purchasers have a free choice between it and the previous larger or smaller size, respectively. Where the new size replaces the old in the selling line, the problem is more difficult. In the case of mareases m size the Office of Price Administration, as
(Italics indicate portion relied upon by complainant.)
We find that this interpretation was made largely because of War Production Board restrictions on the use of certain materials. The use of larger size containers in packaging tangible commodities was being encouraged. By permitting proportionate increases in charges, the Office of Price Administration assisted in the material-saving program and at the same time provided an automatic method of setting new prices without going through the routine -of establishing a price for a new commodity. This purpose, which is corroborated by the language of the interpretation itself, obviously has no application to a commodity such as parking services. But complainant contends in effect that unless the interpretation is made applicable to its services, the Regulation is unreasonable and discriminatory; that since services and tangible products are included within the definition of the term “commodity” as used in the Emergency Price Control Act,
From what has been stated, it is clear that unless complainant has established that there is no substantial difference between the pricing practices relating to parking services and those involved in the sale of tangible products, its claim of discrimination must fail. Complainant submits that it has successfully established there is no such difference. It urges that its commodity (parking services) may be broken into different sizes, based on the length of time purchased; one hour of parking time is urged to be a size of a commodity fairly comparable to a gallon of a tangible article such as paint; two hours of parking time is said to be comparable to two gallons of paint; and so on. But this comparison does not take into account substantial differences. The purchaser of a tangible product receives all for which he pays. He has complete control over it to do with as he likes; he may use it at a later time, he may give it away or dispose of it for profit. The short-time parker does not have the same choice. He takes the full parking time at the time of purchase, or he leaves it; his control, unlike that of the purchaser of a tangible product, is limited. This important difference is enough to distinguish the pricing practices in connection with parking services from those prevailing in connection with tangible products and to justify different treatment by the Administrator of the two types of commodities.
Another attack by complainant is based upon Section 4(d) of the Act which
Having reached the conclusion that the proposed schedules would result in price increases inconsistent with the purposes of the Act and the complainant having failed to show any reason compelling the allowance of such increases, we have no doubt as to the legal right of the Administrator to prohibit them. A regulation interpreted so as to prevent such increases is a valid exercise of the. Administrator’s authority. Sec. 2(a), Emergency Price Control Act of 1942. In this view, complainant’s case must fail, and it is not necessary to consider the right of the Administrator, in the absence of a showing of fraud or subterfuge, to prohibit the introduction of the proposed schedules as a manipulative practice under Section 2(d) of the Act or as a circumvention or evasion of price control which may be prevented under Section 2(g).
The complaint is dismissed.
7 F.R. 4734.
Lincoln Sav. Bank of Brooklyn v. Brown, Em.App., 137 F.2d 228.
Pike & Fiseher OPA Service 11:-1026.
See. 302(c) “The term ‘commodity’ means commodities, articles, products, and materials * * * and it also includes services rendered otherwise than as an employee in connection with the processing, distribution, storage * * * of a commodity, or in connection with the operation of any service establishment for the servicing of a commodity: * * *y>