665 F.3d 882 | 7th Cir. | 2011
Before E ASTERBROOK , Chief Judge , and P OSNER and
W OOD , Circuit Judges . P OSNER , Circuit Judge . ATA filed this diversity suit for breach of contract against Federal Express (which the parties call “FedEx,” as shall we, even though it’s actually a subsidiary of FedEx Corporation), and obtained a jury verdict in the exact amount it had asked for: $65,998,411. FedEx has appealed. ATA has filed a cross-appeal that is conditional on our reversing the judgment; the cross- appeal challenges the district court’s refusal to let ATA present evidence that it incurred $27,842,748 in unrecov- erable costs in reliance on a promise by FedEx in the alleged contract, and that it is entitled to recover these costs as reliance damages, either as an alternative to the expectation damages awarded by the jury or pursuant to the doctrine of promissory estoppel. The parties agree that the substantive issues are governed by the law of Tennessee, FedEx’s principal place of business, except that FedEx defends the district court’s ruling that ATA’s promissory estoppel claim is preempted by the federal Airline Deregulation Act. See American Airlines, Inc. v. Wolens , 513 U.S. 219 (1995); Morales v. Trans World Airlines, Inc. , 504 U.S. 374 (1992).
We begin there, and can be brief: the ruling was incor- rect. Although the Act forbids a state to “enact or enforce a law, regulation, or other provision having the force and effect of law related to a price, route, or service of an air carrier,” 49 U.S.C. § 41713(b)(1), it does not “afford[] relief to a party who claims and proves that an airline dishonored a term the airline itself stipulated. This dis- tinction between what the State dictates and what the airline itself undertakes confines courts, in breach-of- contract actions, to the parties’ bargain, with no enlarge- ment or enhancement based on state laws or policies external to the agreement.” American Airlines, Inc. v. Wolens , supra , 513 U.S. at 232-33.
Promissory estoppel, as the word “promissory” implies, furnishes a ground for enforcing a promise made by a private party, rather than for implementing a state’s regulatory policies. A garden-variety claim of promissory estoppel — one that differs from a conventional breach of contract claim only in basing the enforceability of the defendant’s promise on reliance rather than on consider- ation, In re Fort Wayne Telsat, Inc ., No. 11-2112, 2011 WL 5924446, at *2 (7th Cir. Nov. 23, 2011); Garwood Packaging, Inc. v. Allen & Co. , 378 F.3d 698, 701-02 (7th Cir. 2004) — is therefore not preempted. “We do not read the [Act’s] preemption clause . . . to shelter airlines from suits alleging no violation of state-imposed obligations, but seeking recovery solely for the airline’s alleged breach of its own, self-imposed undertakings . . . . A remedy confined to a contract’s terms” is not preempted. American Airlines, Inc. v. Wolens , supra , 513 U.S. at 228-29. Not so tort claims that override contract claims, see United Airlines, Inc. v. Mesa Airlines, Inc. , 219 F.3d 605 (7th Cir. 2000), rather than just seeking a remedy “confined to a contract’s terms.” But ATA is not alleging a tort; it is trying to hold FedEx to a promise that it contends FedEx made to it. We’ll see later that ATA’s promissory claim fails, but not because of preemption.
We turn to the conventional contract issues, on which ATA prevailed in the district court. In the event of a national emergency, the Department of Defense can use commercial aircraft drawn from what’s called the “Civil Reserve Air Fleet” to augment the Department’s own airlift capabilities. See Air Mobility Command, “Factsheets: Civil Reserve Air Fleet,” www. amc.af.mil/library.factsheets.factsheet.asp?id=234 (visited Dec. 21, 2011). Composed of aircraft owned by commercial air carriers but committed voluntarily to the Department for use during emergencies, the Fleet is divided into separate “teams” of airlines, each with a “team leader.” The teams pledge portions of their fleets for use by the Department during an emergency; the leader assembles the team and submits the team’s bid to par- ticipate in the Civil Reserve Air Fleet.
The team members are not compensated directly for their commitment, but are compensated indirectly because in exchange for a team member’s commitment the Department awards the member “mobilization value points” in proportion to the scale of the commitment. The more points a member has, the more non-emergency air transportation for the Department the member can bid on. The points are transferrable within teams. Smaller carriers value providing non-emergency service to the Department (for which of course they are compensated) more than the bigger ones (such as FedEx) do. So they want the larger carriers’ points and are willing to pay for them, and as a result end up doing most of the non- emergency flying. The team leader — invariably a large carrier that therefore has a large number of mobilization value points because of its commitment to provide copious emergency service if needed — transfers points to the members of its team in exchange for a com- mission on their non-emergency military flights. The commission rate is the price term in the contractual arrangements between the team leader and each of the team’s smaller carriers. (This case concerns the con- tractual relations among the members of one team rather than the contracts between the teams and the Department.)
FedEx is the leader of one of the teams, which before the alleged breach of contract included ATA and Omni Air International — small passenger and charter airlines that split between them the team’s allotment of non-emergency military passenger service (as distinct from cargo ser- vice). The FedEx team’s annual revenues from the provi- sion of non-emergency services to the Department amount to about $600 million.
Relations among members of FedEx’s team are defined in three separate contracts, each with a one-year term. One contract fixes both the allocation of military business among the team members and the commission rate for the team leader. This contract is negotiated sepa- rately between the leader and each team member (so actually it’s more than one contract, but we can ignore that detail). A second contract identifies the team members and the aircraft they will commit to the military if the team’s bid is accepted. A third defines the liability and insurance obligations of the team mem- bers. There are additional provisions in these contracts, but we can disregard them. We’ll call the three con- tracts as a group the “tripartite contract.”
The tripartite contract has as we said only a one-year term. (The year is the federal fiscal year, which runs from October 1 of the previous calendar year to Septem- ber 30, so that the 2002 fiscal year, for example, began in October 2001. All our year references are to fiscal years.) But it was the team’s practice to enter into a sepa- rate three-year agreement concerning the distribution of business among the team’s members. Implementation of the agreement depended on the Defense Depart- ment’s accepting the team’s bid; otherwise there would be no business to divide among the team’s members. And if the Department decided it wanted more or less service from the team than had been bid, this might affect the division of business, since a particular team member might have insufficient capacity to provide its allotted share of service if the service requirement increased, or alternatively might be badly hurt by a reduction in that requirement if its share were unchanged — there might for example be limited demand for or profit in a par- ticipant’s nonmilitary business. The agreement also assumed that the parties would all end up on the FedEx team, though there was no contractual stipulation to that effect.
With so many contingencies, especially ones dependent on decisions entirely within the power and rights of each party, the agreement was a planning document rather than an enforceable contract. We have pointed out that “if any sign of agreement on any issue exposed the parties to a risk that a judge would deem the first-resolved items to be stand-alone contracts, the process of negotia- tion would be more cumbersome (the parties would have to hedge every sentence with cautionary legalese), and these extra negotiating expenses would raise the effective price.” PFT Roberson, Inc. v. Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. , 420 F.3d 728, 731 (7th Cir. 2005). Contract law “permits parties to conserve these costs by reaching agreement in stages without taking the risk that courts will enforce a partial bargain that one side or the other would have rejected as incomplete.” Id .; see EnGenius Entertainment, Inc. v. Herenton , 971 S.W.2d 12, 17-18 (Tenn. App. 1997); Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 27, comments b, c (1981).
ATA’s suit is based on one of these three-year “con- tracts,” signed in 2006, in which ATA and (maybe) Omni agreed with FedEx that during the following three years (2007 through 2009) the team’s passenger business would be divided equally between those two carriers. The “contract” is in the form of a letter from FedEx to them that reads as follows:
The letter will serve as the agreement for the distribu- tion between ATA and Omni of both fixed and expan- sion for both wide and narrow body passenger busi- ness in the AMC Long Range International Contract for FY07-FY09. It is agreed that the distribution for the above passen- ger segments will be fifty-fifty (50%-50%) respectively for both wide and narrow body and for both fixed and expansion. Please indicate your concurrence by signing as indi- cated below and returning to the undersigned. We look forward to a continued successful relation- ship over this period.
There is a space below the writer’s signature for signa- tures by representatives of ATA and Omni. Although only ATA’s representative signed, the evidence indicates that Omni concurred, and if so the omission of a signa- ture by a representative of Omni is immaterial.
The tripartite contracts for 2007 and 2008 incorporated the 50/50 division — but with a change in the 2008 contract: ATA’s allotment was reduced by 10 flights per month to enable them to be allotted instead to Northwest Air- lines, a much bigger carrier, which wanted to start flying for the Civil Reserve Air Fleet. Northwest was already a participant in the FedEx team, but like FedEx (though without FedEx’s responsibilities as team leader) had heretofore been a guarantor of emergency service to the military and thus a seller of points to the smaller airlines; 2008 would be the first time it would be a flying member of the team.
The change turned out to be pregnant with menace for ATA. For later that year FedEx decided to drop ATA from the team and, beginning in 2009, give the mobiliza- tion value points that would have gone to ATA to Delta, which had acquired Northwest shortly after the signing of the 2008 tripartite contract. FedEx’s decision to replace ATA in 2009 caused ATA to withdraw from the team prematurely, in the middle of 2008 (we’re not sure why). The withdrawal precipitated it into bankruptcy because it had very little nonmilitary business to fall back on.
ATA’s breach of contract claim should never have been permitted to go to trial. Courts interpret and enforce contracts; they don’t make contracts. A contract is unenforceable if it is “indefinite” in the sense of missing vital terms, such as price, that can’t be readily supplied by a court, for example by reference to a price formula agreed on by the parties. Doe v. HCA Health Services of Tennessee, Inc. , 46 S.W.3d 191, 196-97 (Tenn. 2001); Four Eights, LLC v. Salem , 194 S.W.3d 484, 486-87 (Tenn. App. 2005); Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 33 (1981); 1 E. Allan Farnsworth, Farnsworth on Contracts § 3.27, pp. 417-20 (3d ed. 2004). If the price or other vital missing term can’t be reconstructed in that way, the “contract” shouldn’t be called a contract at all, but an attempted contract; its indefiniteness renders it unenforceable.
We’ve already seen that a great deal was missing from the so-called contract to allocate the FedEx team’s passen- ger business for 2007-2009 between ATA and Omni. True, “the fact that a contract is incomplete, presents interpre- tive questions, bristles with unresolved contingencies, and in short has as many holes as a Swiss cheese does not make it unenforceable for indefiniteness. Otherwise there would be few enforceable contracts. Complete con- tingent contracts are impossible. The future, over which contractual performance evolves, is too uncertain.” Haslund v. Simon Property Group, Inc. , 378 F.3d 653, 655 (7th Cir. 2004). But “a contract is rightly deemed unenforceable for indefiniteness when it leaves out (1) a crucial term that (2) a court cannot reasonably be asked to supply in the name of interpretation.” Id .
The proper division of responsibility between the contracting parties, on the one hand, and a court asked to enforce a purported contract, on the other, requires the parties to decide on the key terms of the contract (or at least on a methodology that generates the key terms more or less mechanically), such as price, and leaves the court to resolve only issues that, being unlikely to arise, the parties should not be required to have foreseen and provided for. To require parties to negotiate every contingency that might arise during performance would be impossible, because as we said not every contingency can feasibly be foreseen and provided for — the future is too uncertain. Contract law supplies a set of standard terms that the parties can change if they wish but that if they don’t change supply a substitute for negotiation. But there is no standard price term, and no agreed-upon formula for calculating the price, for the service provided by the leader of a team of the Civil Reserve Air Fleet.
The doctrine of indefiniteness that makes a contract unenforceable when it omits a crucial term that cannot be supplied by interpretation has particular force when the contract is one between sophisticated commercial entities and involves a great deal of money. PFT Roberson, Inc. v. Volvo Trucks North America, Inc. , supra , 420 F.3d at 730; Skycom Corp. v. Telstar Corp. , 813 F.2d 810, 815 (7th Cir. 1987); Farnsworth, supra , § 3.8, pp. 224-26. That describes the letter agreement; ATA’s share of the revenues that the tripartite contract generated each year was, at its peak, $406 million, and in 2007 its profits from the contract exceeded $90 million. Even if we as- sumed — unrealistically — that all the other holes that we mentioned in the team structure for 2007-2009 could be filled by a court from industry standards, course of dealing, trade usage, or some other objective source of guidance that enables judicial completion of an incom- plete contract, the price term — FedEx’s compensation for providing team leadership and transferring mobiliza- tion value points to team members — could not be supplied from any such source. That compensation was the result of ad hoc negotiations and thus was deter- mined by the parties’ circumstances each year at the time of contracting. It had usually been 7 percent but one year had plunged to 4.5 percent.
And so the letter agreement was not an enforceable contract. But it did contain a promise to divide the military passenger service to be provided by FedEx’s team equally between ATA and Omni. The doctrine of promissory estoppel makes a promise enforceable even though it is not supported by consideration or other- wise enforceable under conventional principles of con- tract law, provided that the promisee reasonably incurred a cost in reliance on the promisor’s fulfilling the promise and that the promisor should reasonably have anticipated that the promisee would rely in that way and might therefore be hurt if the promisor reneged. Calabro v. Calabro , 15 S.W.3d 873, 878-79 (Tenn. App. 1999); Amacher v. Brown-Forman Corp. , 826 S.W.2d 480, 482 (Tenn. App. 1991); Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 90 (1981); Farnsworth, supra , § 2.19, pp. 176-78.
One function of the doctrine of promissory estoppel, as we noted at the outset of this opinion, is to allow reason- able reliance to be substituted for consideration. The underlying idea is that a reasonable promisee wouldn’t incur an unrecoverable cost in reliance on the promise’s being fulfilled unless there really had been a promise, and so reasonable reliance is as good a basis for inferring the existence of a promise as consideration is. Garwood Packaging, Inc. v. Allen & Co. , supra , 378 F.3d at 702. In this case, however, there is no question that there was a promise — the promise to share business 50/50 between ATA and Omni is in writing, in the letter agreement. The question is whether the promise was (or could reasonably have been understood to be) intended to induce, and could reasonably induce, reliance to the tune of $28 million.
If someone tells you “I promise you X, but don’t hold me to it,” the promisor is making clear that he is not inviting reliance and the promisee cannot, by ignoring the warning and relying on the promise to his detriment, make the promise enforceable. Such a “promise” may create an expectation but does not create a commitment, and so the promisee relies at his risk. Risk taking is ubiqui- tous in business and is perfectly reasonable because the expected benefits of a risky undertaking will often exceed the expected costs. It may have been reasonable for ATA to reckon that it had a good enough chance of getting half the passenger business of the FedEx team in the 2007-2009 period to justify its going ahead and ac- quiring the aircraft it would need to provide the service because its existing fleet was inadequate; it is the $28 million in allegedly unrecoverable expenses relating to that acquisition that ATA seeks to recoup by invoking promis- sory estoppel. But ATA could not reasonably have believed that FedEx intended to commit itself to split the passenger business equally between ATA and Omni during that period when so much was left to be agreed upon, and so FedEx cannot have been expected to antici- pate that ATA would rely on the promise. ATA’s lawyer acknowledged at the oral argument that his client may have been “imprudent” in failing to recognize the possi- bility that Northwest would want more of the team’s business; and Northwest was (and Delta, which swallowed Northwest, even more so, is) to ATA as the Dreamliner is to the DC-3. Acting on a hope is not reasonable reliance. Classic Cheesecake Co. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A. , 546 F.3d 839, 845-46 (7th Cir. 2008); Garwood Packaging, Inc. v. Allen & Co. , supra , 378 F.3d at 703-04; Wood v. Mid-Valley Inc. , 942 F.2d 425, 428 (7th Cir. 1991).
So ATA loses. But we do not want to ignore the jury’s award of damages, which presents important questions that have been fully briefed and are bound to arise in future cases.
The award was based entirely on a regression analysis presented by an expert witness, a forensic accountant named Lawrence D. Morriss. FedEx objected to the ad- missibility of the analysis, citing Rule 702(2), (3) of the Federal Rules of Evidence, which when this case was tried conditioned the admissibility of expert evidence on the expert’s having applied “reliable principles and methods . . . reliably to the facts of the case.” The rule has been reworded slightly, effective December 1 of this year, but the Committee Notes state correctly that the changes are purely stylistic.
There were, as we’re about to see, grave questions concerning the reliability of Morriss’s application of regression analysis to the facts. Yet in deciding that the analysis was admissible, all the district judge said was that FedEx’s objections “that there is no objective test performed, and that [Morriss] used a subjective test, and [gave] no explanation why he didn’t consider objective criteria,” presented issues to be explored on cross-examination at trial, and that “regression analysis is accepted, so this is not ‘junk science.’ [Morriss] ap- pears to have applied it. Although defendants disagree, he has applied it and come up with a result, which ap- parently is acceptable in some areas under some mod- els. Simple regression analysis is an accepted model.”
This cursory, and none too clear, response to FedEx’s objections to Morriss’s regression analysis did not dis- charge the duty of a district judge to evaluate in advance of trial a challenge to the admissibility of an expert’s proposed testimony. The evaluation of such a challenge may not be easy; the “principles and methods” used by expert witnesses will often be difficult for a judge to understand. But difficult is not impossible. The judge can require the lawyer who wants to offer the expert’s testi- mony to explain to the judge in plain English what the basis and logic of the proposed testimony are, and the judge can likewise require the opposing counsel to explain his objections in plain English.
This might not have worked in the present case; neither party’s lawyers, judging from the trial transcript and the transcript of the Rule 702 hearing and the briefs and oral argument in this court, understand regression analysis; or if they do understand it they are unable to communicate their understanding in plain English. But a judge can always appoint his own expert to assist him in understanding and evaluating the proposed testi- mony of a party’s expert. Fed. R. Evid. 706; General Electric Co. v. Joiner , 522 U.S. 136, 149-50 (1997) (concurring opin- ion). If he worries that the expert he appoints may not be truly neutral, he can ask the parties’ experts to agree on a neutral expert for him to appoint, as we suggested in DeKoven v. Plaza Associates , 599 F.3d 578, 583 (7th Cir. 2010), and In re High Fructose Corn Syrup Antitrust Litigation , 295 F.3d 651, 665 (7th Cir. 2002); see also Daniel L. Rubinfeld, “Econometrics in the Courtroom,” 85 Colum. L. Rev. 1048, 1096 (1985). Also, the Federal Judicial Center has published a nontechnical “Reference Guide on Multiple Regression” written by Professor Rubinfeld, published in Reference Manual on Scientific Evidence 303 (3d ed. 2011). Had the district judge read the relevant portions of Rubinfeld’s guide, he would have realized that Morriss’s regression analysis was fatally flawed. Another good introduction to the use of statistical analysis in litigation is David Cope, Fundamentals of Statistical Analysis (2005).
The judge would have discovered in these or other sources that he might have consulted that a linear regres- sion is an equation for the straight line that provides the best fit for the data being analyzed. The “best fit” is the line that minimizes the sum of the squares of the vertical distance between each data point and the line. (Why the squares rather than the simple distances is difficult to explain, and the jury can be asked to take it on faith.) A simple linear regression (that is, one in- volving only two variables — one the dependent vari- able, the variable to be explained, and the other the inde- pendent variable, the variable believed to explain the dependent variable) is easily visualized by plotting the data points on a graph. The regression line is a straight line that minimizes the aggregate of the squared vertical distances from the points to the line. The equation that generates that line can be written as Y = a + bX + u, where Y is the dependent variable, a the intercept (explained below), X the independent variable, b the coefficient of the independent variable (that is, the number that indicates how changes in the independent variable pro- duce changes in the dependent variable), and u the regres- sion residual — the part of the dependent variable that is not explained or predicted by the independent variable and the intercept, or in other words is “left over,” like the change you receive after paying for a 99-cent item with a $1 bill.
To illustrate below we graph a regression of salary (the dependent variable, on the vertical axis) on job experience (the independent variable, on the horizontal axis) for a hypothetical company. Each dot represents the salary and job experience of a particular employee. The intercept is the point at which the regression line crosses the vertical axis on the left side of the graph; it is thus the salary received by an employee who has no job experience at all. (Because a is 26.9, the model predicts that the starting wage of a new hire with no experience would be $26,900.) The slope of the regression line is the coefficient of the independent variable: it is a positive number because the more job experience a worker has, the higher his salary is likely to be. For example, b equals 2.2 in the graph, so the regression model predicts that a 1-year increase in job experience generates a $2200 increase in salary.
The relation between salary and job experience, although positive, varies from employee to employee. That is why not all the data points lie on the regression line, the straight line that fits the data best; the best fit is rarely a perfect fit. The variation in salary that the regression line does not explain is the regression residual, u in our equation.
Regression analysis is used to test hypotheses, in our example the hypothesis that more experienced workers get paid more (and how much more) depending on the amount of their experience. But it is also used to pre- dict — for example that when a new employee accrues 10 years of experience he will be paid $22,000 more than his starting wage.
There is much more to regression analysis, even in the simple case in which there is only one independent variable; but we’ve now explained (and the judge could readily have understood from the FJC guide) enough to enable us to show why Morriss’s regression analysis should never have been allowed to be put before a jury.
He used regression analysis to predict what ATA’s military profits would have been had it not been dropped from FedEx’s team. In a graph that he prepared which we reproduce below, the dependent variable is ATA’s annual costs of participating in the Civil Reserve Air Fleet as a member of the FedEx team and the independent variable is ATA’s total annual revenues from that partici- pation. There are 10 data points, each representing ATA’s costs and revenues for one year from 1998 through 2007. As in our illustrative graph, the regression line in Morriss’s graph slopes upward — when revenues rise, costs rise. Notice that the data points are closer to the regression line than the data points in our illustrative graph. This means that the regression line in his graph fits his data better than the regression line in our illustra- tive graph fits the data in that graph.
To calculate ATA’s damages, Morriss needed to estimate its military revenues and costs for the second half of 2008 (after ATA withdrew from the team), and all of 2009, on the counterfactual assumption that the airline would have continued to belong to FedEx’s team for the entirety of those two years rather than for just the first six months of the period. Morriss estimated that ATA’s revenues for 2008 would have been $286.5 million, a figure he arrived at by multiplying the FedEx team’s 2008 military passenger revenue of roughly $600 million by ATA’s historical share of the team’s annual passenger revenue. Plugging his revenue estimate into his linear regression (which, remember, treats costs as a function of revenues), Morriss came up with a cost figure of $253.8 million; and subtracting that from the estimated revenues yielded an estimated net profit for ATA in 2008 of $32.7 million.
Since FedEx was willing to keep ATA on the team throughout 2008, it is doubtful that the loss of profits that ATA experienced in the last half of 2008 by reason of its premature withdrawal can be blamed on FedEx. Yet Morriss believed that his inflated estimate of ATA’s lost profits underestimated the loss in 2008 because the figure for costs that he used (and profits are revenue minus costs, so the higher the costs the lower the profits) included interest, taxes, depreciation, and amorti- zation costs that he estimated amounted to $11.4 million in 2008. He thought these costs would not have been affected by the company’s flying as part of the Civil Reserve Air Fleet that year, and so should not be deducted from revenues. There is some truth to this. Some of those costs may have been fixed, and if so were properly subtracted from the cost figure used to compute ATA’s lost profits. Imagine that a firm has a fixed rental expense of $1 million a year, and unexpectedly lands a very profitable con- tract. Because the rental would have to be paid even if the firm had failed to obtain the contract, the rental expense would not be a cost allocable to the contract and so should not be subtracted in calculating the contract’s profitability. Yet we’ll see that elsewhere in his analysis he treated capital expenditures as current expenses, a treatment that fails to match costs and revenues, just as subtracting a fixed cost from the revenue generated by the contract in our example would fail to match costs and revenues.
Expunging the $11.4 million figure from Morriss’s cost estimate increased his annual estimate of ATA’s lost profits to $44 million for all of 2008. Last he assumed that ATA’s profits would be identical in 2009, so he multiplied $44 million by 1.5 (to calculate lost profits for the period encompassing the latter half of 2008 and all of 2009) to yield a total lost profits estimate of $66 million. As we said, the estimate was excessive because it included ATA’s profits in second half of 2008 — the consequence of what appears to have been a self-inflicted wound.
But these were the least of Morriss’s errors. His most glaring error was to use costs as his dependent variable and revenues as his independent variable. The dependent variable as we know is a number sought to be explained by the independent variable, as in any equation. In the equation Y = bX, the effect of X on Y is quantified by its coefficient, b; so, for example, if b is 3, then Y is three times larger than X.
But revenue does not influence cost directly; nor is it clear that it is closely correlated with unmeasured variables that do influence costs. An increase in revenue may be correlated with an increase in cost — and indeed is likely to be if the increased revenue is the result of increased sales, but not if it is the result of selling the same output at a higher price. Increases in total costs are driven by increases in component costs — labor, materials, and so forth — not by revenues. What is true is that if revenues plummet, the firm will try to cut its costs in order to minimize the losses caused by the drop in reve- nues. But to the extent that those costs are fixed, it may not be able to cut them in time to avoid bankruptcy — which is what happened to ATA in 2008.
Morriss tried to justify his explaining cost by revenue, rather than by more plausible variables such as fuel, maintenance, and labor costs, on the ground that such information was unavailable. It is hard to believe this, because the information must have been recorded by ATA’s accountants — how else could they have prepared a balance sheet and income statement for the company? In any event a plaintiff’s failure to maintain adequate records is not a justification for an irrational damages theory.
Even if we assumed that Morriss’s model were built on a rational foundation, we would have to reject its results because the model was improperly implemented. In 2007, the last full year in which ATA participated in the Civil Reserve Air Fleet, its profits were a minuscule $2.1 million. If it would have had the same profits in 2008 and 2009 had it not been dropped from FedEx’s team, its total damages would have been only $3.15 million during the 18 months remaining in 2008 and 2009, rather than the $66 million that ATA asked for and the jury awarded (to the dollar). $2.1 million is only 6.4 percent of the $32.7 million profit that Morriss’s regression analysis predicted that ATA would have earned the following year (as well as the year after that) had ATA not been dropped from the team. (The $32.7 million is the profit before the adjustment for the so-called fixed costs of $11.4 million. The adjustment was not carried into the calculation of ATA’s 2007 profits, which is why we are expressing those profits as a percentage of the predicted profit for 2008 and 2009.)
The following graph, based on one prepared by Morriss and admitted into evidence, exhibits the fallacy of his prediction. (We are not clear why his graph was truncated at 2002, since ATA had joined the FedEx team earlier and the record provides sufficient data to extend the graph to 1998, as we have done.) The top line is ATA’s annual military revenues; the lower line is its annual costs; the vertical distance between the two lines measures the company’s profits from its military business. We see that revenues rose sharply from 2002 to 2005, then plum- meted in 2006 and 2007. Costs rose more gently, and fell more gently, over the 2002-2007 period, and in 2007, the last year for which there are data, the two lines almost intersect — it was because revenues were so close to costs that profits were so meager that year.
Morriss predicted that ATA’s military revenues would have risen in 2008 and 2009 while its costs would have continued to fall. The difference between his estimated revenues and his estimated costs is the $66 million in (imagined) lost profits. Remember that Morriss’s regres- sion model, which is based on historical data (2002- 2007), found a positive relation between revenues and costs: when revenues rise, costs rise, and when revenues fall, costs fall. Remember too that he used the model to predict that ATA’s costs would have continued to fall in 2008 and 2009 (the lower dashed line), even as revenues rose. It’s this divergence in directions that turns a modest predicted growth in revenues into a large growth in profits.
What produced this odd result — costs falling as revenues rise — is that ATA’s costs had increased much more slowly than its revenues between 2002 and 2005, resulting in big profit margins. To predict a comparable (though somewhat smaller) profit margin in 2008 and 2009 (and thus produce a big lost-profits estimate), when the uptick in revenues was expected to be much smaller than it had been between 2002 and 2005, Morriss had to make costs in those years fall. But for ATA’s costs to fall as its revenues rose would make no economic sense, as well as being inconsistent with Morriss’s underlying assumption that costs are a positive function of reve- nues — that if revenues rise costs rise and if revenues fall costs fall. That costs rise more slowly than revenues does not imply that costs drop when revenues increase slowly. No mechanism for such a reversal is suggested, and revenues and costs had never moved in opposite direc- tions during the preceding decade in which ATA had actually been operating.
Morriss tried to explain away the embarrassingly mi- nuscule profits that ATA earned on its military business in 2007 as a fluke: the carrier, he said, had experienced “nonrecurring” costs that year. The costs in question were the costs of acquiring new aircraft. They were indeed nonrecurring costs, but they were not 2007 costs; they were capital expenditures, which is to say expenditures expected to increase revenues or reduce costs over a period of more than a year, and thus beyond the year in which the expenditures were made. If a business buys a piece of equipment in year 1 for $1 million that will be usable for 10 years and will then be scrapped, to treat this as a $1 million cost in year 1 and a zero cost in each of the nine subsequent years would create a misleading picture of the firm’s profits through time. Costs should be matched with revenues to provide an accurate year-to- year picture of profitability. This is done by amortizing (spreading) a capital expenditure over its useful life. In the case of our hypothetical $1 million asset, this would require assigning costs of $100,000 per year to each year of the asset’s useful life. If that were done here, Morriss’s estimate of lost profits in 2008 and 2009 would have been lower than it was, because some of the nonrecurring costs incurred in 2007 would have been reallocated to those years.
Another mistake Morriss made was to model the relation between cost and revenue as a straight line, as if, for example, ATA’s costs were always exactly 75 percent of its revenue (producing the linear regression equation c = .75 r ), in which event the company would turn a 25 percent profit every year. Yet its actual profit margins, as shown in the next graph, fluctuated between 0 and 25 percent of total revenue.
Still another mistake was Morriss’s basing a prediction of what ATA’s costs would have been in 2008 and 2009 (had it remained a member of FedEx’s team) on a tiny sample — 10 observations, each consisting of ATA’s costs in one of the 10 years on which the regression analysis was based. Small samples are less representative of the population being sampled than large ones. The popula- tion here would be the entire cost experience of ATA and similar air carriers.
Confidence intervals (familiar as the “margins of error” reported in predictions of election outcomes) are statistical estimates of the range within which there can be reasonable confidence that a correlation or prediction is not the result of chance variability in the sample on which the correlation or prediction was based; 95 percent confidence is the standard criterion of reasonable confi- dence used by statisticians. Consider our hypothetical regression of wages on experience. A regression based on a sample of 10 workers would yield a less precise predic- tion of what the average relation of wages to experience was for the workers in a plant that had 1000 workers than a regression based on a sample of 50 or 100 of the workers.
The 95 percent confidence interval for Morriss’s predic- tion of ATA’s 2008 costs was correctly calculated in the report of FedEx’s expert to be $90 million. This means that Morriss’s estimate that ATA would have costs of $254 million was the midpoint of a range from $299 million at the top ($254 million + $90/2 million) to $209 million at the bottom ($254 million - $90/2 million) — and if its costs were at the top of the range the result would have been a $12.5 million annual net loss for ATA rather than Morriss’s predicted $32.7 million profit (before the ad- justment for fixed costs). All else aside, the confidence interval is so wide that there can be no reasonable confi- dence in the jury’s damages award.
All this is not to say that it would be a surprise if ATA had lost profits as a result of its expulsion from the FedEx team, although its nonmilitary business was col- lapsing and it is doubtful that it could have survived purely on its military business. But the only quantification of damages presented at the trial was based on Morriss’s regression, and as a result there was a failure of proof of damages. It is not enough to prove injury in a damages suit; the plaintiff must prove an amount of damages and ATA failed to do that.
This is not nitpicking. Morriss’s regression had as many bloody wounds as Julius Caesar when he was stabbed 23 times by the Roman Senators led by Brutus. We have gone on at such length about the deficiencies of the regression analysis in order to remind district judges that, painful as it may be, it is their responsibility to screen expert testimony, however technical; we have suggested aids to the discharge of that responsibility. The responsibility is especially great in a jury trial, since jurors on average have an even lower comfort level with technical evidence than judges. The examination and cross- examination of Morriss were perfunctory and must have struck most, maybe all, of the jurors as gibberish. It became apparent at the oral argument of the appeal that even ATA’s lawyer did not understand Morriss’s analysis; he could not answer our questions about it but could only refer us to Morriss’s testimony. And like ATA’s lawyer, FedEx’s lawyer, both at the trial and in his appellate briefs and at argument, could only parrot his expert. FedEx’s expert did not testify; as is common in damages cases, the defendant offered no alternative measure of damages, doubtless fearing that the jury would take that as a signal to split the difference — finding liability but awarding the plaintiff less than the plain- tiff asked for — rather than struggle to understand an incomprehensible case. Both because FedEx tendered no estimate of damages and because neither Morriss nor the lawyers nor the judge presented an intelligible damages analysis to the jury, it is no surprise that, having decided that ATA should win, the jury simply awarded the exact figure that ATA had asked for in damages.
If a party’s lawyer cannot understand the testimony of the party’s own expert, the testimony should be with- held from the jury. Evidence unintelligible to the trier or triers of fact has no place in a trial. See Fed. R. Evid. 403, 702.
The judgment is reversed with instructions to dismiss the suit with prejudice. R EVERSED . 12-27-11