11 Mich. 542 | Mich. | 1863
When this cause was formerly before us (Chandler v. Allison, 10 Mich. 460), one of the questions involved was, whether Allison, the plaintiff, was rightfully in possession of the store at the time the trespass was committed, or whether his right of possession was dependent upon Chandler’s election to rebuild, and ceased when that election was made: and one of the grounds upon which the judgment in that case was reversed, was, the rejection of evidence tending to show that Allison’s right of possession was thus qualified. But as the case now appears before us upon exceptions taken on the new trial, the finding of the jury, whether right or wrong — no exception having been taken to the evidence or the charge upon this point— requires us to treat this question, so far as we are now to consider the case, as settled in favor of the plaintiff; and the defendant must be considered as a trespasser, entering upon the premises and tearing down the store while in the rightful possession of the plaintiff, under a lease for a term which would not expire till the first day of May following.
, The only question presented by the present bill of exceptions, and not already disposed of by our former decision, is the question of damages; and in this action of trespass (as parties are under no necessity of protecting themselves by contract against trespasses), the question of damages is to be treated in all respects as it would have been, had the trespass been committed by a party between whom and the plaintiff the relation of landlord and tenant did not exist; except so far as the good faith of the defendant, and the absence of malice on his part, might preclude the plaintiff from the recovery of damages of a punitory and exemplary character, beyond the amount which would compensate the actual loss. Upon this point (the question of exemplary damages) we think the Court
While in many cases the rule of damages is plain and easy of application, there are many others in which, from the nature of the subject matter, and the peculiar circumstances, it is very difficult — and in some cases impossible —to lay down any definite, fixed rule of law by which the damages actually sustained can be estimated with a reasonable degree of accuracy, or even a probable approximation to justice; and the injury must be left wholly, or in great part, unredressed, or the question must be left to the good sense of the jury upon all the facts and circumstances of the case, aided by siich advice and instructions from the court as the peculiar facts and circumstances of the case may seem to require. But the strong inclination of the courts to administer legal redress upon fixed and certain rules has sometimes led to the adoption of such rules in cases to which they could not be consistently or justly applied. Hence there is, perhaps, no branch of the law upon which there is a greater conflict of judicial decisions, and none in which so many merely arbitrary rules have been adopted. We have carefully examined all the cases cited in the very elaborate briefs of the respective counsel, and the most approved elementary treatises upon the subject; and, without attempting here to compare and analyze them (which would require
The principle of compensation for the loss or injury sustained, is, we think, that which lies at the basis of the whole question of damages in most actions at common law, whether of contract or tort. We do not here speak of those actions in which punitory or exemplary damages may be given, nor of those whose principal object is the establishment of a right, where merely nominal damages are proper. But, with these exceptions, the only just theory of an action for damages, and its primary object, would seem to be, that the damages to be recovered should compensate the loss or injury sustained. We concur entirely with the Court of Appeals in New York in Griffin v. Colver, 10 N. Y. 492, in repudiating the doctrine adopted by Mr. Sedgwick, from Domat (Sedgw. on Dams., 3, 37, 38, &c.), that “ the law aims not at the satisfaction, but the division, of the loss.” Such, it is true, is often the result of an action, but never the object of the law. The law may, and often does, fail of doing complete justice, from the imperfection of its means of ascertaining truth, and tracing and apportioning effects to their various causes; but it is not liable to the reproach of doing positive injustice by design. Such a doctrine would tend not only to make the law itself odious, but to corrupt its administration, by fostering a disregard of the just rights of parties. In actions upon contract, especially, 'and those nominally in tort, but substantially upon contract, courts have thought it generally safer, upon the whole, to adopt certain definite rules for the government of the jury by which the damages could be
But whatever plausibility there may be in the theory of Mr. Sedgwick when applied to actions upon contract — a plausibility which arises from mistaking the result for the object — the injustice of such a principle, when applied to cases of actual, positive tort, like that here in question, would be so gross as to shock all sense of justice.
It has been frequently said that the rule of damages, where there is no fraud, willful negligence, malice, oppression, &o., is the same in actions of tort as in those upon contract. But, though the remark is doubtless true in its application to those cases of tort where, from the nature of the case, elements of certainty exist, by which substantial compensation may be readily estimated, and other cases which are but nominally in tort, we do not think it can be accepted as a principle of universal application; nor, in our opinion, can it be justly applied to any case of actual, aggressive .tort, where, from the nature and circumstances of the case itself, no such elements of certainty are found to exist, or none which will apply substantially to the whole case: nor to any case where the rule applicable to breaches of contract would exclude a material portion of the damages the injured
There are some important considerations which tend to limit damages in an action upon contract, which have no application to those purely of tort. Contracts are made only by the mutual consent of the respective parties: and each party, for a consideration, thereby consents that the other shall have certain rights as against him, which he would not otherwise possess. In entering into the contract the parties are supposed to understand its legal effect, and, consequently, the limitations which the law, for the sake of certainty, has fixed for the recovery of damages for its breach. If not satisfied with the risk which these rules impose, the parties may decline to enter into the contract, or may fix their own rule of damages when, in their nature, the amount must be uncertain. Hence, when suit is brought upon such contract, and it is found that the entire damages actually sustained can not be recovered without a violation of such rules, the deficiency is a loss, the risk of which the party voluntarily assumed on entering into the contract, for the chance of benefit or advantage which the contract would have given him in case of performance. His position is one in which he has voluntarily contributed to place himself, and in which, but for his own consent, he could not have been placed by the wrongful act of the opposite party alone.
Again, in the majority of cases upon contract, there is little difficulty from the nature of the subject, in finding a rule by which substantial compensation may be readily estimated; and it is only in those cases where this can not be done, and where, from the nature of the stipulations, or the subject matter, the actual damages resulting from a breach, are more or less uncertain in their nature, or difficult to be shown with accuracy by the evidence, under any definite rule, that there can be any great failure of justice by adhering to such rule as will most
Again, in analogy to the rule that contracts should be construed as understood and assented to by the parties —if not as a part of that rule — damages which are the natural, and, under the circumstances, the direct and necessary result of the breach, are often very properly rejected, because they cannot fairly be considered as having been within the contemplation of the respective parties at the time of entering into the contract.
None of these several considerations have any bearing in an action purely of tort. The injured party has consented to enter into no relation with the wrong doer by which any hazard of loss should be incurred; nor has he received any consideration, or chance of benefit or advantage, for the assumption of such hazard; nor has the wrong doer given any consideration, nor assumed any risk, in consequence of any act or consent of his. The injured party has had no opportunity to protect himself by contract against any uncertainty in the estimate of damages: •no act of his has contributed to the injury: he has yielded nothing by consent: and, least of all, has he consented that the wrong doer might take or injure his property or deprive him of his rights, for such sum as, by the strict rules which the law has established for the measurement of damages in actions upon contract, he may be able to show, with certainty, he has sustained by such taking or injury. Especially would it be unjust to presume such consent, and to hold him to the recovery of such damages
Since, from the nature of the case, the damages cannot be estimated with certainty, and there is a risk of giving by one course of trial less, and by the other more than a fair' compensation — to say nothing of justice — does not sound policy require that the risk should be thrown upon the wrong doer instead of the injured party? However this question may be answered, we can not resist the conclusion that it is better to run a slight risk of giving-somewhat more than actual compensation, than to adopt a rule which, under the circumstances of the case, will, in all reasonable probability, preclude the injured party from the recovery of a large proportion of the damages he has actually sustained from the injury, though .the amount thus excluded can not be. estimated with accuracy by a fixed and certain rule. Certainty is doubtless very desirable in estimating damages in all cases : and where, from the nature
The law does not require impossibilities; and can not therefore require a higher degree of certainty than the nature of the case admits. And we can see no good reason for requiring any higher degree of certainty in respect to the amount of damages, than in respect to any other branch ■of the cause. Juries are allowed to act upon probable and inferential, as well as direct and positive proof. And when, from the nature of the case, the amount of the damages can not be estimated with certainty, or only a part of them can be so estimated, we can see no objection to placing before the jury all the facts and circumstances of the case, having any tendency to show damages, or their probable amount; so as to enable them to make the most intelligible
In the adoption of this course it will seldom happen that the Court, hearing the evidence, will not thereby possess the means of forming a satisfactory judgment whether the damages are unreasonable, or exorbitant; and, if satisfied they are so, the Court have always the power to set aside the verdict and grant a new trial.
The justice of the principles we have endeavored to explain will, we think, be sufficiently manifest in their application to the present case. The evidence strongly tended to show an ouster of the plaintiff for the balance of the term, by the defendant’s act. This term was the property of the plaintiff; and, as proprietor, he was entitled to all the benefits he could derive from it. He could not by law be compelled to sell it for such sum as it might be worth to others; and, when tortiously taken from him against his will, he can not justly be limited to such sum — or the difference between the rent he was paying and the fair rental value of the premises — if the premises were of much greater and peculiar value to. him, on account of the business he had established in the store, ■and the resort of customers to that particular place, or the good will of the place, in his trade or business. His right to the full enjoyment of the use of the premises, in any manner not forbidden by the lease, was as clear as that to sell or dispose of it, and was as much his property as the term itself, and entitled to the same protection from the laws. He had used the premises as a jewelry store, and place of business for the repairing of watches, making gold pens, &c. This business must be
The plaintiff in this case did hire another store, “the best he could obtain, but not nearly so good for his business” — “his costumers did not come to the new store, and there was not so much of a thoroughfare by it, not one quarter of the travel, and he relied much upon chance
Now if the plaintiff is to be allowed to recover for this injury to his business, it would seem to follow, as a necessary consequence, that the value of that business before the injury as well as after, not only might, but should be shown, as an indispensable means of showing the amount of loss from the injury. If the business were a losing one to the plaintiff before, his loss from its being broken up or diminished (if any thing) would certainly be less than if it were a profitable one. It is not the amount of business-done, but the gain or profit arising from it, which constitutes its value.
But it is insisted that loss of profits constitutes no. proper ground or element- of damages. If there be any such rule of law it is certainly not a universal, and can hardly be called a general rule. Decisions, it is true, may be found which seem to take it for granted that the ruléis universal. But there are numerous cases, even for breach of contract, in which profits have been properly held to constitute, not only an dement, but á measure (and sometimes the only measure) of damages: as in Masterton v. The Mayor, 7 Hill, 61; Phil. W. & B. R. R. Co. v. Howard, 13 How. 344. And in actions for breach of contract in not delivering goods (as wheat or other articles) having a marketable value, as well as in most-actions of-trespass or trover for the taking or conversion of such property — wherever the difference between the" contract price, or the market value at the time of taking or conversion, and the higher market value at any subsequent [period, is held to constitute the damages — in all such cases this difference of price is but another name for profits, and is yet very pro
But there are also cases for breach of contract where, though the profits were in their nature somewhat uncertain and contingent (and in most of them quite as much so as in the present case), they were yet held to constitute, not strictly a measure, but an element of damages proper for the consideration of a jury, to enable them to form a judgment or probable estimate of the damages; as in McNeill v. Reid, 9 Bing. 68; Bagley v. Smith, 10 N. Y. 489; Gale v. Leckie, 2 Stark. 107; Ward v. Smith, 11 Price, 19; Driggs v. Dwight, 17 Wend. 71; and see Passenger v. Thorburn, 36 Barb. 17. And in Waters v. Towers, 20 E. L. & E. 410 the jury were allowed to take into consideration the profits which might have been made upon a collateral contract (though void by the Statute of Frauds); and see McNeill v. Reid, supra; while, by the American authorities, profits of this description have been almost uniformly rejected.
But whatever may be the rule in actions upon contract, we think a more liberal rule in regard to damages for profits lost, should prevail in actions purely of tort (excepting perhaps the action of trover). Not that they should be allowed in all cases without distinction: for there are some cases where they might, in their nature, be too entirely remote, speculative or contingent, to form any reliable basis for a probable opinion. And perhaps the decisions which have excluded the anticipated profits of a voyage broken up by illegal capture, or collision, may be .properly justified upon this ground: upon this,
Accordingly such past profits have been allowed for this purpose, both in actions ex contractu and ex delicto, though
But it is. urged by the counsel for the defendant that damages for tlie loss of profits ought not to be allowed, because they could not have been within the contemplation of the defendant. Whether, as matter of fact, this is likely to have been true, we do not deem it important to inquire. It is wholly immaterial whether the defendant in committing the trespass actually contemplated this, or any other species of damage to the plaintiff. This is a consideration which is confined entirely to cases of contracts, where the question is, what was the extent of obligation, in this respect, which both parties understood to be created by the contract. But where a party commits a trespass he must be held to contemplate all the damages which may legitimately follow from his illegal act. And where a party, though acting in good faith, yet knowing his right to be disputed by a party in possession, instead of resorting to a judicial trial of his right, assumes to take the law into his own hands, and, by violence, to seize the property or right in dispute, he must be held thereby to assume, on the one hand, the risk of being able to show, when the other party brings him into Court, that the property or right was his or that his act was legal; or, on the other, of paying all the damages the injured party may have suffered from the injury; and if those damages are in their nature uncertain, then such as, from all the circumstances, or the best light the nature
We are therefore entirely satisfied that all the questions put to the witness, Allison, touching the nature, extent and profits of the business, before and after the trespass, were .competent, and improperly overruled; and that the charge of the Court, so far as it excluded all consideration of the good will of the place, its peculiar value to the plaintiff, and his probable profits, was erroneous.
■The judgment must be reversed, with costs to the plain-, tiff, and a new trial granted.