103 Va. 243 | Va. | 1904
delivered the opinion of the court.
This controversy involves the construction of a clause in a written contract of settlement, entered into March 2, 1892, between appellants — J. W. E. Allemong, J. T. Shiekel, J). B. Strouse and James Bonsack — of the one part, and appellees— Jed. Hotchkiss, H. M. Bell and R. H. Catlett — of the other part. ■
It appears that appellants and appellees sold the Mt. Vernon Iron property, of which they were equal owners, to the- Grot
“Now the parties hereto agree that the Mt. Vernon property lying east of the S. V. B. B., free of all claims of the Grottoes Company, shall be held for the benefit of the parties hereto in the name of Jed. Hotchkiss, trustee, and shall be sold by the parties of the first part (appellees) whenever the same can be sold for $100,000 or more, or by consent of all parties for less, and that the proceeds shall be divided among the parties thereto, as follows: First, there shall be paid to the parties of the first part the amount released by them on the Grottoes of
The sale authorized by' this agreement was never effected, and Hotchkiss having assigned his interest in the $21,000 to the Augusta National Bank, that institution filed a bill in equity against appellants and other parties in interest, asserting priority of claim for the $21,000 in the proceeds of sale of the Mt. Vernon Iron property lying east of the Shenandoah railroad, and praying for a sale of the property and distribution of the avails.
The appellants, by their answer, denied the interpretation placed upon the contract by the bank, and insisted that unless the property could be sold for $100,000 or more, “according to the terms of said agreement the fund would have to be distributed ratably, giving to the parties of the first part 60 1-2 per cent., and to the parties of the second part 39 1-2 per. cent."
The matter was referred to a commissioner in chancery, who sustained the contention of appellees, and the court, by the decree appealed from, confirmed the report of the commissioner and ordered a sale of the property.
Hpon the foregoing facts, independently of express compact, it would have been incumbent upon appellants to reimburse their associates to the extent of one-half the value of the asset surrendered by them for the common good, or else to have provided for their indemnity in the ultimate division of the proceeds of sale of the joint property. A careful examination of the contract shows that the object of the parties, in adjusting their rights among themselves, was to secure an equal division of the social assets. To that end appellees, as remarked, made negotiable notes payable to appellants for the amount received by them in excess of their half of the cash payment on the
It could not have been in contemplation of the parties that a sale of the property at the price fixed was a condition precedent to recompensing appellees for the expenditure made by them with their individual means. Indeed, the answer concedes that such is not the proper construction of the contract, but insists that if a sale should be made for less than $100,000, the fund ought to be distributed in the proportion of 60 1-2 per cent, to the appellees, and 39 1-2 per cent, to appellants. It is quite clear, however, that such a ratio of distribution is not justified, either by the contract or the principles of law applicable to the conceded facts.
Nor can it be fairly presumed that if from any cause a sale in pais could not be made for the price named, the parties intended to relinquish their legal right to resort to a court of equity to compel a sale; or only to invoke the aid of that tribunal on the terms of surrendering a priority to which they were entitled by the law and facts of the case.
Where a contract admits of two constructions, the general rule is that the court ought to adopt that which is most equitable and which will not give an unconscionable advantage to one party over the other.
The fundamental error in the contention of appellants consists in construing the limited power of sale given appellees in the contract and the scheme of distribution of the proceeds of sale as dependent covenants, whereas, in light of the context and according to a just interpretation of the agreement they are separate from and independent of each other, the former providing that the property “shall be sold by the parties of the first part whenever the same can be sold for $100,000 or more, or by consent of all parties for less”; and the latter declaring “that the proceeds shall be paid to the parties thereto as follows : First, there shall be paid to the parties of the first part the amount released by them on the Grottoes of the Shenandoah property, to-wit: Twenty-one thousand dollars ($21,000), without interest; and second, the balance shall be distributed one-half to the parties of the first part, and the other half to the parties of the second part.”
This court has said: “Perhaps there is no other branch of the law in which is to be found a larger number of decisions or-a greater apparent conflict of authorities than that in which the effort has been made to define the dependence and independence of covenants, and to designate the class to which any given case in dispute is to be referred. The great effort, however, in the more recent decisions has been to discard, as far as possible, all ^ules of construction founded on nice and artificial reasoning, and to make the meaning and intention of the parties, coT
“Courts construe agreements so as to prevent a failure of justice, and hold dependent covenants to be independent when the necessity of the case and the ends of justice require it, notwithstanding the form.” Todd v. Summers, 2 Gratt. 167; Brockenbrough v. Word, 4 Rand. 352; Bream v. Marsh, 4 Leigh, 21; Ayres v. Robins, 30 Gratt. 105; see note to Todd v. Summers (title “Dependent Covenants”), Va. R. Anno. 322.
Applying the foregoing principles to the case in judgment, there is no error in the' decree appealed from, and it must he affirmed.
Affirmed.